Abstract

Governments in developing and emerging countries aim to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) to generate growth. Yet, empirical studies on the country level show no clear growth effect. We argue that FDI induces concentrated benefits on the local level—in close proximity to multinational corporations—which leads to economic development in that area but also amplifies inter-regional economic inequality. Both effects should be stronger in autocracies compared to democracies, because autocrats face fewer political constraints to create profitable investment environments. Empirically, we leverage geo-located data on FDI projects from 2003 to 2018, which we combine with nightlights using two approaches: concentric buffers around project locations and global 10 × 10 km grid cells. Our estimator compares the effect of FDI on growth and inequality between areas that have already received FDI and areas that have not yet received FDI. We find strong evidence for FDI-induced local growth and regional inequality. Both effects are more pronounced in autocracies than democracies.

Los Gobiernos de los países en desarrollo y emergentes tienen como objetivo atraer IED con el fin de generar crecimiento. Sin embargo, los estudios empíricos a nivel país no muestran que exista un efecto claro sobre el crecimiento. Argumentamos que la IED genera beneficios concentrados a nivel local, muy cerca de las empresas multinacionales. Esto favorece el desarrollo económico en esa área, pero también amplifica la desigualdad económica interregional. Ambos efectos deberían apreciarse con más fuerza en las autocracias, en comparación con las democracias, debido a que los autócratas se enfrentan a menos limitaciones políticas para poder crear entornos de inversión rentables. De manera empírica, aprovechamos los datos geolocalizados sobre proyectos de IED entre 2003 y 2018, y los combinamos con luces nocturnas utilizando dos enfoques: zonas de influencia concéntricas alrededor de las ubicaciones de los proyectos y celdas de cuadrícula globales de 10 × 10 km. Nuestro estimador compara el efecto de la IED con respecto al crecimiento y a la desigualdad entre las áreas que ya han recibido IED y las áreas que aún no han recibido IED. Encontramos pruebas contundentes del crecimiento local inducido por la IED y la desigualdad regional. Ambos efectos son más pronunciados en las autocracias que en las democracias.

Les gouvernements des pays en développement et pays émergents souhaitent attirer les IDE pour générer de la croissance. Pourtant, les études empiriques au niveau national ne montrent aucun effet clair sur la croissance. Nous affirmons que l'IDE induit des avantages concentrés au niveau local, à proximité des multinationales, ce qui engendre le développement économique de cette zone, mais aussi l'amplification des inégalités économiques entre les régions. Ces deux effets devraient être plus importants dans les autocraties que les démocraties, car les autocrates rencontrent moins de contraintes politiques pour créer des environnements d'investissement avantageux. Sur le plan empirique, nous exploitons des données géolocalisées sur les projets d'IDE entre 2003 et 2018, que nous combinons avec les lumières du ciel nocturne à l'aide de deux approches : des tampons concentriques autour de l'emplacement de projets et des cellules du réseau mondial de 10 × 10 km. Notre estimateur compare l'effet de l'IDE sur la croissance et les inégalités entre les zones qui ont déjà reçu des IDE et les zones qui n'en ont pas encore reçus. Nous trouvons des éléments qui viennent fortement étayer la présence d'une croissance locale et d'inégalités régionales découlant des IDE. Ces deux effets sont plus prononcés dans les autocraties que les démocraties.

Introduction

Even though governments around the globe, and especially in developing and emerging countries, strive to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) in order to generate economic growth (see, e.g., Jensen 2003, 2006; Pandya 2016), conclusive evidence on the growth-enhancing effect of FDI is “surprisingly hard to come by” (Nunnenkamp and Spatz 2004, 54). Notwithstanding and even in light of critical voices that hold FDI responsible for rising inequality and social conflicts (see, e.g., Paczynska 2016), the importance of this facet of economic globalization has been growing steadily in the past decades (OECD 2018). Many developing and emerging countries are heavily reliant on external sources of finance to bolster their economies, rendering them dependent on foreign investors’ decisions to implement projects (Pandya 2016). Because creating favorable investment conditions often comes with considerable costs, this begs the question: what exactly are the economic consequences of FDI for host countries and communities?

The notion that FDI is economically beneficial ranks among the more important, if not the most important, reasons for governments to attract FDI. In line with that goal, Ram and Zhang (2002) and Blonigan and Wang (2005) indeed identify a direct positive effect of FDI on growth, which more recent comparative studies at the national level confirm (Emako, Nuru, and Menza 2022; Iamsiraroj and Uluba¸sog˘lu 2015). More than that, some studies even find that the effect of FDI on growth is either self-reinforcing (Li and Liu 2005) or complements the positive effect of domestic investment (Tang, Selvanathan, and Selvanathan 2008). Yet, other studies find a direct negative effect (Dutt 1997), especially in environments that are not favorable for multinational companies (Nunnenkamp and Spatz 2004), or find neither a growth-enhancing, nor a growth-deterring effect (Adams 2009; Azman-Saini, Baharumshah, and Law 2010; Carkovic and Levine 2005). Recently, Bergougui and Murshed (2023) sought to explain such heterogeneous findings by examining whether there are sectoral differences, particularly in developing and emerging markets.

Further research underscores the growth potential of FDI but stresses that FDI promotes economic growth not necessarily on its own but only in conjunction with other factors. Borensztein, De Gregorio, and Lee (1998), for example, argue and find that FDI exhibits a growth effect only in countries with a highly educated workforce. Yet, the debate about what exactly these conditioning factors are is still ongoing, since others stress the role that a sufficient level of economic wealth (Blomström, Lipsey, and Zejan 1994), a functioning financial market (Alfaro et al. 2004; Hermes and Lensink 2003), openness to international trade (Balasubramanyam, Salisu, and Sapsford 1996), economic stability (Bengoa and Sanchez-Robles 2003), or a small technological development gap (De Mello 1999) have in facilitating growth induced by FDI. The growth effect of FDI is supposedly also contingent on domestic conditions and institutions in the host country (Forte and Moura 2013; Iamsiraroj 2016). Capitalizing on innovations in geo-coded data, recent research adds a spatial dimension to the growth effects of external investments, showing that positive impacts, such as additional investments (Bunte et al. 2018) and spillovers (Bluhm et al. 2025), occur mainly near the investment site, thus favoring the local economy (Benshaul-Tolonen et al. 2019).

In this article, we follow these state-of-the-art approaches that go away from national-level data and set out to provide a comprehensive account of the economic effects of FDI on the local level. Importantly, we focus not only on the effect of FDI on economic activity but also investigate whether FDI produces asymmetric changes between areas that receive FDI and areas that do not. We do this because prominent theoretical arguments that facilitate our understanding of the political effects of FDI often rely on assumptions about the economic effects of FDI. Through its growth effect, for instance, FDI supposedly affects regime trajectories (Bak and Moon 2016; Escribà-Folch 2017; Rommel 2018), electoral outcomes (Owen 2019), domestic policies (Blanton and Blanton 2012; Li 2006), and international openness (Elkins, Guzman, and Simmons 2006).1 A more nuanced picture of the economic consequences of FDI that uncovers within-country geographical heterogeneity could therefore lead to different expectations with regard to the political implications of cross-border investment by multinational corporations (MNCs).

We aim at making three contributions: For one, we argue that FDI induces growth, but that this effect is spatially concentrated around the location of FDI projects. FDI primarily promotes more economic activity in its direct environment by increasing the local capital stock as well as through concentrated spillovers, which manifest in close proximity to the multinational's investment location. This implies that FDI benefits businesses and the working-age population in the vicinity of projects, yet these growth-enhancing effects do not travel to areas farther away from the location of investment.

At the same time, investment by MNCs also affects the distribution of economic resources in the host economy. To assess FDI's impact on economic inequality, we combine insights from theories on agglomeration effects and firm-level theories of international openness. Highly productive multinational investors gain from openness through their superior productivity and, importantly, induce a local growth effect, predominantly through spatially concentrated backward linkages. As distance from the investment site increases, the positive direct and indirect effects on growth diminish, making foreign investors less influential in shaping growth trajectories in distant regions. However, the concentrated growth near the investment site exacerbates disparities, creating a widening divide in economic development between areas close to MNCs and those farther away, thereby increasing inter-regional inequality.

Lastly, we argue that political institutions determine the extent to which the economic consequences of FDI materialize. Autocratic leaders need foreign capital to bolster their output legitimacy and face fewer political obstacles to grant MNCs lucrative investment deals. Democracies are more constrained in offering, for instance, tax rebates or softer workplace regulations, because citizens can hold their government to account via elections and more equal access to the judiciary. MNC activity should thus lead to faster economic development on the local level as well as higher economic inequality in autocratic countries compared to democracies. Importantly, this implies that FDI produces more economic activity in autocracies only where MNCs actually invest, not necessarily country-wide.

Studies that rely on country-level aggregates discount FDI's geographically confined nature and neglect that some areas in host countries are much more likely to receive FDI. Consequently, our empirical strategy focuses on the local level. We leverage geo-located data on FDI projects to estimate the local economic effects of FDI between 2003 and 2018 in non-OECD countries and combine these with nightlight data using two different approaches: First, we create concentric buffers around each location that at some point in time will receive foreign investment. Second, we use global grid cells of 10 × 10 km size. For each unit, we calculate average light intensity (measuring economic prosperity) and the difference in light intensity between each unit and its neighboring units (measuring inter-regional inequality). To mitigate endogeneity problems, we rely on difference-in-differences and treatment matching estimators, where we compare the effect of FDI on growth and inequality between areas that have already received FDI in a given year and areas that have not yet received FDI, additionally controlling for lagged nightlights and population size. Using both approaches, we find that FDI has a spatially concentrated effect on economic growth, which in turn contributes to increased inter-regional inequality driven by foreign investment. Importantly, both the growth- and inequality-enhancing effects of FDI at the local level are more pronounced in authoritarian countries.

We proceed as follows: In the next section, we provide a detailed theoretical account of the relationship between FDI and economic activity on the local level and elaborate how political institutions condition these economic consequences. Section 3 presents our research design and discusses how we leverage light emissions at night and geo-coded data on FDI projects to arrive at a better understanding of its economic effects. Section 4 presents our findings on rising local growth and growing inter-regional inequality from FDI. Section 5 outlines the implications of this spatially confined growth effect for research and policymakers.

Theoretical Argument

In this section, we argue that FDI directly and indirectly generates more economic activity, but that this effect is spatially concentrated. In essence, the economic consequences of FDI are inherently local, which is important as investments are not evenly distributed within countries. Multinational companies invest in carefully selected locations for a very specific purpose: to increase their return on investment (Dunning 1993, 2001). Governments allow multinational companies to enter the domestic market because they count on economic gains in the form of economic growth and job creation (Owen 2019; Pandya 2014).2 But we also argue that the concentrated, localized benefits of FDI exacerbate regional disparities. Inter-regional inequality arises from FDI-receiving regions, which experience disproportionately high growth, while distant areas without FDI projects tend to grow little or at a slower rate. Lastly, we argue that both the growth- and inequality-enhancing effects of FDI depend on the regime type of the host country. Authoritarian regimes provide environments conducive to higher locally concentrated growth, which results in higher interregional inequality at the same time.

Local Economic Growth, But Interregional Inequality

The economic case for the relationship between foreign direct investment and economic growth is supposedly straightforward. Entry of multinational companies increases the capital stock, which—according to neoclassical growth models—directly contributes to economic growth (Romer 1986), especially in developing countries where capital is scarce. This effect should be even more pronounced for FDI compared to other types of capital flows, because FDI is rather immobile after investment and aims at generating long-term returns (Jensen 2006).

The direct growth effect of FDI is further amplified by indirect effects, which include public and private growth-enhancing activities that precede or accompany foreign investment. These measures often involve favorable investment regulations, subsidies aimed at attracting or retaining foreign investors, and infrastructure development (Khadaroo and Seetanah 2009). Such public goods might even be provided by MNCs themselves because governments mandate them as investment requirements (Bunte et al. 2018). At the same time, multinational companies and local suppliers increase labor demand, resulting in higher overall employment, and often offer wage premiums. This rise in employment and wages boosts purchasing power and consumption (Benshaul-Tolonen et al. 2019), thereby benefiting sectors beyond those directly exposed to international capital (Görg and Strobl 2002; Markusen and Venables 1999).

However, there are two important aspects of FDI that warrant taking the local level, as opposed to the country level, more seriously when thinking about the relationship between FDI and economic growth (for a similar plea, see Owen 2019). First, FDI is neither evenly nor randomly distributed within countries. To the contrary, the distribution of FDI within countries depends on a number of factors foreign investors carefully screen before selecting a specific site for their investment. These local characteristics determine which areas are more or less attractive to investors. FDI projects in the mining sector, for instance, can only be located in areas with extractable minerals, whereas successful FDI in the manufacturing industry often depends on the local infrastructure and supply of labor. This entails that some locations in countries are much more likely to host foreign investors, while others are not attractive for FDI projects. In addition to location-specific factors, local politics often plays a crucial role in fostering an environment conducive to foreign investment through public investment (Nielsen, Asmussen, and Weatherall 2017). When investors choose a location, the local conditions are likely to already support growth, as public investment, locally available subsidies, and infrastructure development in these areas make them attractive (Katitas and Pandya 2024; Khadaroo and Seetanah 2009) and create a foundation for further economic growth.

Second, when multinational enterprises invest in these specific locations, they increase the capital stock and produce spillover effects on the local level. Because multinational companies need complementary investment, the direct neighborhood of FDI projects should immediately start to develop as well. In areas attractive to investors with better public infrastructure, growth is amplified by backward linkages, as foreign investors rely on local goods and services to support their operations (Bunte et al. 2018; Speakman and Koivisto 2013). Yet even though these benefits favor domestic business and the working-age population in the vicinity of FDI projects, the growth-enhancing effects do not travel to areas farther away from the location of investment (Merlevede and Purice 2016; Caselli and Michaels 2013; Benshaul-Tolonen et al. 2019).

This argument resonates well with findings in the literature on spillovers that showcase the importance of backward linkages between the foreign multinational and domestic business (Aitken and Harrison 1999). Spillovers occur more frequently when they directly benefit multinational companies’ business model (Görg and Greenaway 2004; Godart and Görg 2013). The benefits of domestic business from the presence of foreign multinationals and the possibility to become part of their supply chains are, however, contingent on spatial proximity, which is in line with growing evidence on positive geographically concentrated backward linkages (Merlevede and Purice 2016; Krugman 1991).3 Thus, domestic firms close to the site of investment of foreign multinationals are far more likely to benefit from FDI, which exacerbates the local effect of FDI on economic development (Speakman and Koivisto 2013).

FDI should, therefore, promote local growth both directly by increasing the capital stock and indirectly through local backward linkages. Additionally, conducive local conditions that attract investors further enhance FDI's growth potential, creating a favorable environment for economic expansion. This implies that the growth-enhancing effect of FDI should be concentrated around the site of investment.

H1: The more FDI in a specific location, the higher the growth of economic activity in that area.

H2: The growth-inducing effect of FDI decreases in distance to the location of investment.

Through its spatially concentrated growth effect, FDI also affects the distribution of economic resources within the host economy. The exact shape and form of the distributional consequences of FDI are, however, highly contested (Palmtag, Rommel and Walter 2020). Starting from the argument about the strong spatial concentration of positive growth effects and contrasting this development with the overall distributive effects within countries (Lessmann 2013), we argue that FDI contributes to rising levels of interregional inequality.

Rising inter-regional inequality results from FDI's concentrated growth effects near project sites, while more distant regions are left out from this specific boost to the economy. Domestic firms farther from FDI locations are less likely to become suppliers for foreign multinationals, limiting new employment opportunities to areas close to the project (Gerschewski 2013b; Krugman 1991). Consequently, FDI creates new employment opportunities and higher wages mainly around the project site, with regard to the foreign multinational and its suppliers, but does not change the demand in more distant labor markets. Additionally, positive backward linkages to other domestic businesses decrease with distance, as those benefiting from FDI tend to spend their income locally (Merlevede and Purice 2016; Marchetti 1994). Since people often live near their workplace, increased household income from new jobs or better wages boosts demand for non-tradable services and local goods, driving economic activity and wage growth near the FDI site (Benshaul-Tolonen et al. 2019). This leads to more intense economic activity and higher wage levels in both the sector of investment as well as other sectors located closely around the foreign investment compared to regions farther away from investors.

Potential negative effects of FDI on growth, particularly with regard to market-seeking investments, can occur both near and far from investors. These effects may displace domestic competitors of foreign multinationals (Owen 2019). While this displacement does not necessarily hinder growth in other regions, negative horizontal linkages from FDI in areas farther away may not be offset or reversed by direct growth effects or positive vertical linkages (Gerschewski 2013b). Hence, we argue that the locally concentrated growth effects of FDI drive rising inter-regional inequality. MNCs both directly and indirectly generate so much economic activity that the majority of economic entities in the immediate vicinity are better off compared to areas in which foreign investors are not present. Because FDI-exposed areas benefit disproportionately, FDI contributes to a widening gap in economic development between these areas that gain from increased capital, accompanying public investment, positive spillover effects, and improved labor market conditions, and those that are too distant to share in these growth benefits.

H3: FDI increases differences in economic activity between directly exposed areas and areas distant from MNCs' investment sites, which produces regional inequality.

Differences Across Regime Types

In what follows, we argue, is that the effectiveness of FDI projects to generate economic activity differs between democracies and autocracies.4 More specifically, we argue that the presence of multinational investors induces higher local growth rates in autocratic countries for three inter-related reasons: (1) autocrats are more dependent on economic growth than leaders in democracies, (2) autocrats have to offer better investment conditions to attract international investors, and (3) autocrats are actually better able to do so because of fewer political constraints. Importantly, this line of reasoning is on the local level and does not necessarily travel to overall differences in economic growth between democracies and autocracies (Chandra and Rudra 2015; Knutsen 2021).

First, while no leader opposes higher economic growth, autocrats should be more dependent on economic prosperity compared to democratically elected fellow stateswomen. Because of the lack of input legitimacy, autocrats have to resort to other means to maintain their hold on power (Gerschewski 2013a). Choosing from a menu of options, political leaders in dictatorships often rely on economic growth and FDI to boost their own, and consequently the regime's, popularity (Rommel 2024; Treisman 2011; Wintrobe 1998). Autocratic leaders are thus interested in a mutually beneficial relationship between their own survival prospects, facilitated by the direct and indirect growth effects of FDI, and multinational investors’ return on investment.

Second, autocrats may not only be interested in giving special treatment to foreign multinationals, they may actually need to. This is due to the fact that foreign investors face a time-inconsistency problem. Policy flexibility is beneficial for multinational enterprises before investment takes place but poses serious political risks afterwards (Büthe and Milner 2008; Jensen 2003).5 In order to counter these perceived risks, autocrats are forced to pay a risk premium to foreign investors and offer even higher benefits. In line with this notion, research has shown that autocrats offer more tax incentives to foreign investors (Li 2006) or that autocracies have lower labor standards (Messerschmidt and Janz 2023). Hence, autocracies can only match the more secure investment environment that characterizes democratic regimes by creating an investment environment that increases the return on investment for MNCs.

Third, we argue that autocrats are less constrained in terms of their ability to make policy with regard to both vertical and horizontal constraints. This argument is in line with mounting evidence that regional favoritism in producing growth is higher in autocratic regimes (Hodler and Raschky 2014) and that autocrats can induce political budget cycles more easily (Shi and Svensson 2006; Shmuel 2020). Whereas merely being interested in mutual gains does not guarantee that leaders actually offer more beneficial investment deals, autocrats have more room to maneuver and thus the ability to actually act on their promises.

Taken together, these three interrelated dynamics lead to the conclusion that FDI should generate higher economic growth in autocracies compared to democracies on the local level where FDI projects are located. Because autocrats are dependent on economic prosperity and have the ability to provide private goods, they welcome foreign direct investment for its growth potential. In addition, more autocratic settings make domestic political favoritism easier, which also increases complementary investment in the vicinity of FDI projects. The combination between an autocrat's interest in offering a mutually beneficial investment environment and investors’ interest in taking advantage of such environments should thus bolster local economic activity more than it does in democratic regimes.

On the flip side, fewer constraints and more flexibility to tailor policies towards the narrow interests of regime insiders and multinational companies come at the cost of the interests of the larger public, thus elevating the risk of heightened economic inequality. In autocracies, the population has fewer means to challenge political favoritism by dictators. The public lacks the instrument of meaningfully challenging the incumbent via regularly held, free, and fair elections and is oftentimes subjected to repressive measures if its members resort to protest to challenge the political distribution of economic resources. In addition, the lower independence of and higher obstacles to access to the judicial system in autocratic regimes oftentimes work against the interests of the population and do not offer fair administration of justice in case of legal challenges to specific policies. Consequently, the institutional setup that is conducive to local economic growth in autocracies at the same time increases the asymmetric distribution of these economic gains within countries.

H4: The local effect of FDI on both economic growth and economic inequality is stronger in more authoritarian countries.

Empirical Strategy

Measuring Local Growth and Inequality

To assess the local economic consequences of foreign direct investment, we require disaggregated information on economic activity and inequality. Unfortunately, official national or sub-national data is neither sufficiently spatially disaggregated nor flexible enough to serve as a measure for our dependent variables of interest. Therefore, we focus on nighttime light emissions for several reasons:

First, nightlights have been frequently validated as a proxy for economic development and inequality (see, e.g., Kuhn and Weidmann 2015; Cederman, Weidmann, and Bormann 2015; Keola, Andersson, and Hall 2015; Perez-Sindin, Chen, and Prishchepov 2021). They are more reliable than national accounts of economic activity and correlate closely with countries’ aggregate economic output (Elvidge et al. 1997; Chen and Nordhaus 2011; Proville, Zavala-Araiza and Wagner 2017). Official GDP figures can contain serious measurement errors and often vary significantly due to differing methodologies and motivations for data collection (Jerven 2013).6 Second, nightlights offer high resolution, allowing us to measure economic activity across various environments on the local level. They have also proven useful for measuring spatially detailed economic activity, for example at the subnational (Lessmann and Seidel 2017; Henderson, Storeygard, and Weil 2011; Sutton, Elvidge, and Ghosh 2007) or neighborhood level (Weidmann and Schutte 2017).

Nightlight emissions are collected by the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA, National Geophysical Data Center 2018a,2018b) and are available as a raster with a resolution of 30 arc-seconds, which is approximately one square kilometer at the equator, on a global scale. The illumination of these rasters is measured as a “digital number” (DN), ranging from 0 to 63. A raster cell with the value of 0 DN is completely dark, which means no light was detected by satellites during nighttime, whereas 63 DN is a cell with maximum illumination. While NOAA provides the original data, we rely on a product by Li et al. (2020) that creates a harmonized and globally integrated measure of nightlights for the time period from 1998 to 2018 using NOAA's official data. Importantly, this data update resolves differences in average light intensity that might arise over time because of changes in the quality of satellites.

In what follows, we embed these light emissions at night in two different approaches that determine the units of analysis: a buffer approach and a grid cell approach. For each approach, we create two different dependent variables. First, as a measure for economic activity, we simply use the average nightlight illumination within the respective unit of analysis. Second, in order to measure cross-unit (i.e., regional) inequality, we calculate the difference between the nightlight intensity of one unit and the average nightlight intensity of its neighboring units (that also lie within the borders of the same country). For every measure, higher values imply more economic activity or higher inequality, respectively.

Analysis of Concentric Buffer Zones Around FDI Projects

To identify the activity of foreign multinational companies in host countries, we draw on geolocated FDI data from the “fdimarkets” database, which is provided by the Financial Times. This database is a unique source of information on FDI at the project level and records greenfield investments as well as expansions of existing projects on an ongoing basis since 2003 (The Financial Times Ltd. 2018). The Financial Times relies on multiple sources, news wires, various media sources, and information from industry organizations to collect this information. The database includes detailed project-related data, such as the date when the investment was announced, the estimated capital expenditure, and the estimated number of jobs created by the multinational company. Furthermore, it provides data on the home country of the investor, the investing company, and the sector of the respective project.

Most importantly, the FDI data includes information on the location of each project. Using this information, we can illustrate how growth and inequality change over time in locations that are attractive for foreign investors by creating buffer zones around each FDI project. To do so, we identify all unique investment locations in non-OECD countries where at least one project has been implemented between 2003 and 2018. Even though geo-located FDI data provides us with a unique opportunity to test the local effects of FDI, there are some drawbacks. According to Brazys and Kotsadam (2020), there is a slight over-representation of capital investments in comparison with the World Bank data. Another limitation is the missing coverage of mergers and acquisitions, which might be especially important in the context of developing markets (Jung, Owen, and Shim 2021). The data also covers announcements of estimated capital expenditure only, which might deviate from actual capital invested. To mitigate these problems, we focus on several measures of MNC activity. For each unique project location, the “fdimarkets” database allows us to code the year of the first MNC activity as a binary indicator. This measure should not only be less prone to measurement error but also reduce the available information to a sizable degree. We thus also take more fine-grained measures of MNC activity into account, in which we sum up (over time) either the estimated capital expenditure or the number of jobs created.

In our main specification, we match the FDI data with nightlight data in a radius of 10 km around each unique project location, an area that approaches a reasonable commuting distance (see Figure A1 in the Appendix for an illustration of this approach).7 Our final dataset consists of 4,386 buffer zones around FDI project locations in 143 non-OECD countries, for which we have information on local growth and interregional inequality before and after projects were implemented. Light emissions and MNC activity thus vary within each buffer zone over a time period of 16 years. To investigate whether the local consequences of FDI vary as a function of distance to each project, we also use varying buffer zones ranging from 5 km to 100 km. All buffer zones are clipped at the borders of their respective country to account for the fact that national borders still constitute substantial barriers for economic activity as well as to avoid bias for FDI projects that are built at sea borders.

Analysis of Global Grid Cells

While the approach using buffer zones as the units of analysis has been applied in previous scholarly works (e.g., see Brazys and Kotsadam 2020), there are potential problems. Focusing on concentric buffer zones around projects helps us to deal with selection bias as we only compare locations that are at some point in time attractive for multinational enterprises. Yet, due to the design of only choosing locations that already have or will receive FDI projects, the number of treated observations will equal the number of all units in the last year, i.e., 2018. Furthermore, buffer zones around unique project locations might overlap the more we increase the radius of the respective buffers.8 Areas or parts of them that end up twice in the pool of observations might induce a systematic bias. In sum, we cannot conclusively rule out that we might overestimate the effect of FDI using the buffer approach.

Hence, we complement the buffer zone approach with an alternative empirical strategy: instead of drawing buffers around FDI projects, we partition the globe into 10 × 10 km grids, which results in 942,592 cells in 156 non-OECD countries as the units of analysis. Compared to the buffer approach, the grid approach uses information on economic activity in grid cells that will at some point in time receive FDI as well as other grid cells that do not (and, for most of them, probably never will) host FDI projects. We clip grid cells at country borders and then match both nightlight emissions9 and geo-located information on FDI projects. Of the 942,592 total grid cells, only 4,064 are treated between 2003 and 2018. Therefore, we test the robustness of this approach by limiting the available grid cells to the treated as well as the first neighbors of treated cells (see Figure A2 in the Appendix for an illustration).10

Estimation Strategy and Regime Types On the Country-Level

To uncover whether FDI has conducive economic effects in host localities, we use a difference-in-differences approach (Christensen 2019).11 We estimate OLS regression models that contain project fixed effects (for buffers as the unit of analysis) or grid fixed effects (for grids as the unit of analysis), which control for time-invariant factors, such as mountainous terrain, deserts, etc., as well as year fixed effects, which control for common shocks in investors’ investment decisions, such as the 2008/9 financial crisis (for similar approaches to estimation strategies on the local level, see Bluhm et al. (2025) and Christensen (2019)). We cluster the standard errors on the buffer or grid level, respectively. Even though we can effectively rule out a lot of sources for potential bias using the difference-in-differences estimator on two different units of analysis, we are still left with one concern: light emissions in areas that receive investment might change not because of the presence of foreign multinationals, but because investors anticipate booming areas. For this reason, we additionally control for lagged nightlight intensity and population size in both the buffer and the grid approach.12

In addition, we investigate the mediating effect of the regime type on the country level using split regression models. We divide our sample using three dichotomous indicators: First, we differentiate between different types of political regimes using a dichotomous measure. Based on raw data from the V-Dem project (Coppedge et al. 2020; Pemstein et al. 2020), Lührmann, Tannenberg, and Lindberg (2018) group countries in four regime categories13 that we collapse into a simple autocracy-democracy dichotomy. The other two measures focus more closely on the key components of liberal democracy. On the one hand, we use the extent to which citizens have the power to hold their government accountable using formal political participation in the form of free and fair elections (vertical accountability). On the other hand, we capture differences in legal institutions, i.e., to what extent citizens enjoy equal and secure access to the judicial system (access to judiciary). Both measures are continuous, ranging from 0 to 1. We dichotomize by using a cut-off at 0.75, which corresponds with the coding instructions for V-Dem expert coders.

Empirical Evidence

How does FDI affect growth and inequality in developing countries? We expect that FDI directly and indirectly induces growth, but that this effect is geographically concentrated. We further expect that FDI increases inequality, especially when taking into consideration that the growth-inducing effect of FDI is spatially confined. On top of that, the local economic consequences of FDI should be more pronounced in autocratic compared to democratic regimes.

FDI and Local Economic Activity

Figure 1 reports the first set of our findings focusing on the effect of FDI on economic growth using both buffers (on the left-hand side) and grids (on the right-hand side) as the unit of analysis. Economic development is operationalized by average nightlight intensity in a 10 km radius around each FDI project or within a 10 × 10 km grid cell, respectively. The unconditional effect of MNC activity is positive and statistically significant in both approaches. This means that compared to an area that will only be exposed to international investment in the future, areas where multinational companies have already invested in a given year experience increasing light emissions at night. The growth effect is also substantial in size. A one standard deviation increase in FDI leads to a growth rate of light emission of about 11 percent for the first year after a new project was built (for the grid analysis). In line with Hypothesis 1, we thus conclude that FDI is conducive to economic growth on the local level.

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity. Note: OLS regression models based on model specifications in Table A1 and Table A2, including 95 percent and 83 percent confidence intervals.
Figure 1.

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity. Note: OLS regression models based on model specifications in Table A1 and Table A2, including 95 percent and 83 percent confidence intervals.

The results in figure 1 are based on Table A1 and Table A2 in the Appendix, which further show that the statistically significant effect of FDI on economic development is robust to different operationalizations of MNC activity. Models 1 and 2 use a simple treatment variable of the very first FDI project in each buffer or grid. This variable is 0 if, in a given year, investment in that area has not yet been made; in addition, it is also 0 for all grid cells that are never treated. The variable increases to 1 in the first year any MNC has invested in that locality.14 In models 3 and 4, we switch to a more fine-grained operationalization using the cumulative sum of capital invested; logged because capital expenditures are highly skewed. This variable thus offers more variation in terms of the actual extent of MNC activity between buffers or grids as well as changes in investment behavior over time. Models 5 and 6 mirror these models, but use the estimated number of jobs created in a project site or grid cell, respectively. The effect of FDI on growth is positive and statistically significant across all model specifications. The growth enhancing effect of FDI is also robust to controlling for lagged nightlight intensity, which is a proxy for how well-off an area already is before (the initial or more) investment takes place, and population size, which proxies for the size of the local market. Lastly, the results from the grid approach also hold when we restrict the number of grid cells used in the regression models to treated grid cells as well as direct neighbors of treated grids (see Table A3).

We additionally expect that the political regime type mediates the effect of FDI on economic growth. Figure 1 thus also focuses on the scope of the growth effect of FDI across autocracies and democracies. We use model 4 from Table A1 and Table A2 as the preferred specification and interact exposure to FDI with a binary indicator for the type of political regime. In line with Hypothesis 4, we find that the growth-inducing effect of FDI is—albeit positive in every political regime—far greater in autocratic regimes and statistically significantly different from democracies.15 We come to the same conclusion when focusing on two core components of liberal democracy. FDI induces higher growth rates on the local level when citizens are able to hold their government to account via free and fair elections (vertical accountability) and when citizens have equal access to the court system (access to justice). Note, however, that these are differences for local growth rates, which do not necessarily imply that FDI similarly leads to higher aggregate economic growth in authoritarian regimes overall. These results are also robust to excluding China from the analysis16 and to excluding highly populated areas, such as national and regional capitals.17

Lastly, we leverage a key advantage of the buffer approach to explore the spatial concentration of the growth-inducing effect of FDI. Using the specification from model 4 in Table A1, we vary the size of the buffer zone around each FDI project. As shown in figure 2, the growth-enhancing effect of FDI is strongest in the immediate vicinity of multinational companies (within 5–10 km). While FDI continues to induce growth in more distant areas, the effect size steadily declines and is not statistically significantly different from zero anymore beyond 40 km.18 This supports Hypothesis 2, suggesting the positive effect of FDI on economic growth—both directly and through indirect spillovers—is spatially concentrated around the site of investment.

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity, depending on distance. Note: OLS regression models based on model specification in Table A1, including 95 percent confidence intervals.
Figure 2.

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity, depending on distance. Note: OLS regression models based on model specification in Table A1, including 95 percent confidence intervals.

FDI and Regional Economic Inequality

We now turn to investigating the effect of FDI on economic inequality. For the buffer approach, we operationalize regional inequality using the difference between average light intensity in a 10 km buffer zone and the average light intensity in a ring including the area of 10–25 km around each FDI project. As for the grid approach, we calculate the difference in light intensity between each cell and the average light intensity of its neighboring cells that lie within the same country. Figure 3 reports the results from a two-way fixed effects model. Irrespective of whether we use buffers (on the left-hand side) or grids (on the right-hand side), the unconditional effect of FDI is positive and statistically significant. This implies that the presence of MNCs leads to a divergence of economic activity between areas in the immediate vicinity of FDI projects and the areas farther away, which supports Hypothesis 3. Although we cannot rule out that some of the increase in economic activity may be attributed to complementary domestic investments, such as infrastructure development, our estimates specifically isolate the direct and indirect effects of FDI projects in the areas where MNCs choose to invest. In substantial terms, our results imply that the nightlights growth rate in treated grids is about double the growth rate in neighboring grids that are not exposed to FDI.19

Effect of FDI projects on spatial nightlight inequality. Note: OLS regression models based on model specifications in Table A4 and Table A5, including 95 percent and 83 percent confidence intervals.
Figure 3.

Effect of FDI projects on spatial nightlight inequality. Note: OLS regression models based on model specifications in Table A4 and Table A5, including 95 percent and 83 percent confidence intervals.

Furthermore, figure 3 showcases that there are again substantial differences between autocracies and democracies. The inequality-inducing effect of FDI is substantially larger in autocracies and statistically significantly different from democracies in the buffer as well as the grid approach. FDI also bolsters inequality in regimes where citizens have less say in politics via free and fair elections and when citizens do not have access to an impartial justice system. Our findings thus indicate that FDI fosters a more unequal distribution of economic resources in more authoritarian countries, which is again in line with Hypothesis 4.

Summing up, these findings provide strong evidence in favor of our argument. Through both direct and indirect linkages, FDI induce more economic activity, most notably in the area that is very close to multinational investment sites. At the same time, FDI amplifies regional economic inequality. Lastly, more authoritarian countries, in terms of their political as well as their legal institutions, fare better when it comes to the local growth potential of FDI, but worse when it comes to FDI-induced reallocation of economic resources.

Figure 4 portrays these patterns graphically. This graph shows that prospective investment locations (in black) have generally higher light emissions compared to neighboring, but untreated grid cells (in gray). Importantly, we clearly see a sharp increase in light intensity after investment by foreign multinationals, whereas we do not see any effect in neighboring untreated grid cells. Additionally, we do observe a small anticipation effect of FDI in treated grids in the year before the first FDI project, which is likely due to public investment or accompanying infrastructure development. In contrast, what we do not detect is an overall decline in economic activity in unaffected areas, which implies that regional inequality does not emerge from crowding-out effects, but from large differences in asymmetric growth.

Development of economic activity in treated and neighbor cells. Note: Average nightlight intensity of treated and untreated grids before and after investment by MNCs.
Figure 4.

Development of economic activity in treated and neighbor cells. Note: Average nightlight intensity of treated and untreated grids before and after investment by MNCs.

Treatment Matching as a Robustness Check

One assumption of the difference-in-differences design is that treated and untreated grids show roughly equal light emissions trends before MNCs enter an area. Figure 4 shows that this assumption is slightly violated. Consequently, we find it important to employ an estimator that only compares similar units. Establishing a reliable effect thus requires matching and weighting treated with untreated cells based on previous light developments and the treatment history.20 To do so, we apply the estimation strategy by Imai, Kim, and Wang (2023), who established an identification strategy for cross-sectional time-series data that specifically takes the treatment history of previous years into account.

In terms of estimation, we rely on the R-package “PanelMatch” (Kim et al. 2021), which contains three steps: First, we create a set of matched treated and control units for the 10 × 10 km grid raster. Second, we apply the propensity score distance matching to refine the matched set based on country, the mean of light development as well as population size in the last two years. The five most similar control units will be used to estimate the average treatment effect on treated units (ATT) for the first 2 years after the FDI project has been announced. To calculate confidence intervals for the point estimates, we calculate bootstrap standard errors with 1000 iterations. Figure 5 shows the effect of FDI on local economic activity, based on average nightlight emission within 10 × 10 km grid cells. The average treatment effects are positive and statistically significant, thus corroborating the findings from previous analyses. As expected by the long-term nature of FDI, the growth effect of FDI also becomes bigger over time.21 FDI again leads to higher local growth rates in autocratic countries compared to democracies (see Figure A3 in the Appendix).

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity—treatment matching. Note: ATT for 0–2 years after the first FDI project in 10 × 10 km grid cells.
Figure 5.

Effect of FDI projects on nightlight intensity—treatment matching. Note: ATT for 0–2 years after the first FDI project in 10 × 10 km grid cells.

We run the same estimator for our second dependent variable: spatial economic inequality.22  Figure 6 shows that FDI projects asymmetrically benefit the lights development of the inner versus the surrounding grid cells. The positive and statistically significantly positive effect implies a growing divergence in terms of economic activity between grids treated by FDI and untreated neighbor grids. We also find statistically significant differences between democratic and autocratic countries, whereas FDI increases regional inequality more in more authoritarian settings (see Figure A4 in the Appendix).

Effect of FDI projects on spatial nightlight inequality—treatment matching. Note: ATT for 0–2 years after the first FDI project in 25 × 25 km grid cells.
Figure 6.

Effect of FDI projects on spatial nightlight inequality—treatment matching. Note: ATT for 0–2 years after the first FDI project in 25 × 25 km grid cells.

Conclusion

Foreign direct investments in many non-OECD countries are a growing source of capital, and governments are eager to attract multinational enterprises in the hope of creating better economic conditions. However, the debate as to where and how foreign multinationals really contribute to economic prosperity and an equal distribution of economic resources in society is still open. In this article, we argue that the consequences of MNC activity should be heterogeneous within countries and between different political regimes. While FDI induces growth around the site of investment, it contributes to rising inter-regional inequality as growth trajectories of investment areas and places farther away diverge. The growth- and inequality-inducing effects of FDI on the local level are more pronounced in autocracies compared to democracies. We contend that the local growth effect of FDI results from a combination of increased capital stocks from the multinational enterprise, accompanying public investment and infrastructure development, as well as spillover effects to domestic businesses and the working-age population that occur closely around the sites of investment. At the same time, disproportionate economic growth from FDI in close proximity to project locations increase disparities with those regions that are not attractive for foreign investors.

We find evidence in favor of these hypotheses using geo-located data on FDI, which we match with data on light emissions at night. Doing so allows us to investigate the economic consequences of FDI on a very fine-grained, sub-national level. This approach also enables us to differentiate between the local economic consequences of FDI in autocracies and democracies. By employing a dynamic buffer zone approach, we are able to test the effect of FDI at varying distances from the project location. In addition, we complement our analysis with a difference-in-differences design based on global grid cells. Both approaches support our argument: There is a sizable, positive growth effect in the vicinity of multinationals’ sites of investment that decreases in distance to the project location. Because of this spatially concentrated effect on economic development, FDI also heightens inter-regional inequality. Local economic inequality increases especially in authoritarian regimes.

Our article thus speaks to the question of whether a country's regime type makes a difference for multinational investors. We show that more authoritarian countries, both in terms of their political and legal institutions, fare better when it comes to the local growth potential of FDI, but fare worse regarding the FDI-induced polarization of economic activity. Democratic countries, on the other hand, seem to be more successful in generating a more equitable distribution of the benefits of FDI. Our article further speaks to the general necessity of moving away from national cross-country analyses and calls for more work that focuses on what consequences any form of economic integration has for the local level—on the empirical as well as theoretical level (Bunte et al. 2018; Benshaul-Tolonen et al. 2019; Bluhm et al. 2025). Recent advances in trade theory (Melitz 2003; Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple 2004; Walter 2010) have already outlined that economic globalization exhibits consequences that are more heterogeneous than previously assumed. We add to that literature by additionally highlighting the geographical heterogeneity of international economic integration. One important avenue for future research lies in further disaggregating the type of FDI project. We might expect that export-oriented (or vertical) FDI produces economic growth, but market-seeking (or horizontal) FDI leads to economic inequality. Unfortunately, our design cannot differentiate between these dynamics. And a rigorous empirical evaluation of this hypothesis goes well beyond the scope of this article.23

Taken together, our analysis makes clear that taking into account both the geographical dispersion and political institutions is crucial to understand the heterogeneous impact of foreign direct investment on domestic economies in developing countries. Hence, we conclude that the increasing inter-regional polarization from FDI equally warrants a more fine-grained, local response to the distributive effects of globalization. If so desired, policy makers in developing countries need to ensure adequate and targeted compensation for places that cannot benefit from the locally restricted gains of international integration. Place-based compensation policies might be a potential solution for addressing increasing inter-regional inequality that might destabilize these countries. Otherwise, the revenge of left-behind places in developing and emerging markets (Rodríguez-Pose 2018) could potentially lead to social conflict and subsequently endanger the economic catch-up process of many of these countries.

Funder Information

Tobias Rommel and Tabea Palmtag gratefully acknowledge funding from the Department of Political Science at the University of Zurich.

Author Biography

Tobias Rommel is a Senior Research Fellow and Lecturer at the Hochschule für Politik München at the Technical University of Munich.

Tabea Palmtag is a Senior Research Fellow and Lecturer at the Department for Political Science at the University of Zurich.

Luca Messerschmidt is a Research Associate at the Chair for International Relations at the Technical University of Munich.

Notes

Author's Note: We would like to thank Sarah Bauerle Danzman, Celeste Beesley, Tim Büthe, Frederick Chen, Cindy Cheng, Timur Ergen, Lisa Garbe, In Song Kim, Erica Owen, Amy Pond, Adam Rauh, Paul Schaudt, Marcel Schliebs, Stefanie Walter, and three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions. We are grateful to the Department of Political Science at the University of Zurich, which generously offered funding to purchase data used in this study, the Chair for International Relations at the Hochschule für Politik München for providing a highly supportive research environment, and the Leibniz Supercomputing Centre at the Technical University of Munich for access to their infrastructure. Authors in reverse alphabetical order.

The data underlying this article are available on the ISQ Dataverse, at: https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/isq.

Footnotes

1

Of course, most studies go further than assuming a growth effect of FDI and leveraging it in their argumentation, but also include FDI's distributional consequences. Nevertheless, the fact that FDI allegedly promotes growth plays a sufficiently large role in these theoretical arguments to warrant a closer inspection.

2

Even if individual projects are not immediately profitable, their spillover effects often persist and drive indirect positive impacts on local growth.

3

Domestic companies that operate in the same sector, irrespective of whether they are located near or far from foreign investors, face heightened competition from market-seeking FDI (Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple 2004; Melitz 2003). However, any potentially negative effect of FDI from competition can be offset by positive spillovers and growth effects in the vicinity of FDI projects (Gerschewski 2013b).

4

We focus foremost on national-level political institutions because regulations the for entry of MNCs are usually set at the federal level. Research has increasingly illustrated that political institutions also vary on the local level. For example, Bill Chavez (2004) shows that access to justice can vary substantially within countries, and Gibson (2024) presents evidence on sub-national authoritarianism in otherwise democratic countries. Tapping into such within-country variation in political institutions might be a fruitful avenue for further research. One recent attempt to explicitly include differences with regard to local electoral politics is by Palmtag, Paula, and Rommel (2025).

5

This is one of the main reasons why democracies should in principle attract more international investment (e.g., Büthe and Milner 2008; Jensen 2003, 2006; Li and Resnick 2003), even though it is empirically unclear whether democracies are indeed more attractive for foreign multinationals (Li, Owen and Mitchell 2018).

6

While nightlights are a reliable proxy for economic activity, they can suffer from saturation (lack of differentiation in very bright areas), overglow (geospatial displacement regarding the exact origin of light), and blooming (undetected isolated light spots in dark areas); see Mellander et al. (2015); Henderson, Storeygard, and Weil (2011); and Chen and Nordhaus (2011).

7

We use the difference in light intensity between the immediate surroundings of a project location (a small buffer zone of 10 km) and the larger region (a 25 km radius around the project location, without the inner 10 km buffer zone) as our baseline measure for regional inequality.

8

In the 10 km buffer zone dataset, 8,890 out of 13,594 buffer zones overlap to some extent with another buffer.

9

To measure the regional inequality in nightlight emission, we calculate the difference between the nightlight intensity in each grid cell and the average nightlight intensity in the maximum eight surrounding grids that also lie in the same country.

10

In another robustness check, we use grid cells of the size 25 × 25 km. Here, 3,552 out of a total of 159,651 grids have received at least one FDI project at some point in time.

11

We substantiate the validity of this approach using treatment matching estimators as robustness checks.

12

Population data is taken from the HYDE database (Klein Goldewijk et al. 2017), which provides a spatial estimate of population size and density based on harmonizing a variety of different sources and interpolation methods. We do not account for other geographical features within both buffers and grids, because bodies of water and mountainous terrain should be constant over time. Additionally, we clip buffers and grids at the land borders of each country and, thus, do not include geographical units that are fully covered by water.

13

Liberal democracies, electoral democracies, electoral autocracies, and closed autocracies.

14

This variable simplifies a lot of information regarding the prevalence of FDI in specific areas. Given that each unique FDI location is on average exposed to only two FDI projects between 2003 and 2018, we think this variable still is a good indicator to capture overall exposure to international investment of subnational units.

15

Whereas we use 95 percent confidence intervals to compare an effect to the null hypothesis, here we focus on 83 percent confidence intervals. If 83 percent confidence intervals do not overlap, effects are statistically significantly different from each other approximately on the 5 percent level.

16

Simply because of its size and importance in investment relationships, China might be driving the results on differences between regime types. We re-run both the buffer and grid analysis on economic activity and exclude China from the sample. The differences between democracy and autocracy, between low and high accountability, and between bad and good access to justice remain statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

17

We suspect urban-rural differences in FDI location decisions, especially in non-OECD countries. Yet, this must not mean that we should expect differences in the growth effect of FDI between highly populated and more remote areas. To test this explicitly, we identify the 10 percent most highly populated grid cells in each country. Hence, we focus on actual country-standardized population numbers and not the status of a city as a national or regional capital. The effect of FDI on local economic activity is slightly smaller in size, but remains positive and statistically significant. Additionally, the differences in the growth effect of FDI remain statistically significant between democracies and autocracies as well as between countries with good and bad access to the judicial system.

18

Larger buffer sizes might at some point clash with the size of very small countries. This is to say that simply by design, the size of a country could mediate the effect of FDI on economic activity in this analysis; a buffer cannot become larger than the country itself. Hence, already large buffers cannot expand further if the buffer zone already covers the entire country. We re-run the buffer analysis and exclude the 20 percent (or 31) smallest countries from the analysis. Our findings are robust to this change.

19

Table A4 and Table A5 further highlight that the inequality-increasing effect of MNC activity is robust to different operationalizations of FDI exposure.

20

The grid cell design also does not take into account that investors invest several times in the same location. Around 2,291 out of 4,064 treated cells in the 10x10km raster have been treated multiple times.

21

Some FDI projects are indeed just announcements and it might take some time for them to be fully built and running. The increasing effect of FDI on economic activity over time takes this into account and corresponds nicely with the nature of FDI as a long-term investment.

22

Unfortunately, given that the refinement procedure is very memory-intensive, we need to rely on 25 × 25 km grid cells for this analysis.

23

We are very grateful to an anonymous reviewer for making this suggestion.

References

Adams
 
Samuel
.
2009
. “
Foreign Direct Investment, Domestic Investment, and Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa
.”
Journal of Policy Modeling
.
31
(
6
):
939
49
.

Aitken
 
Brian
,
Harrison
 
Ann
.
1999
. “
Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence from Venezuela
.”
American Economic Review
.
89
(
3
):
605
18
.

Alfaro
 
Laura
,
Chanda
 
Areendam
,
Kalemli-Ozcan
 
Sebnem
,
Sayek
 
Selin
.
2004
. “
FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets
.”
Journal of International Economics
.
64
(
1
):
89
112
.

Azman-Saini
 
W.
,
Baharumshah
 
Ahmad
,
Law
 
Siong
.
2010
. “
Foreign Direct Investment, Economic Freedom and Economic Growth: International Evidence
.”
Economic Modelling
.
27
(
5
):
1079
89
.

Bak
 
Daehee
,
Moon
 
Chungshik
.
2016
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Authoritarian Stability
.”
Comparative Political Studies
.
49
(
14
):
1998
2037
.

Balasubramanyam
 
V.
,
Salisu
 
M.
,
Sapsford
 
David
.
1996
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP and IS Countries
.”
The Economic Journal
.
106
(
1
):
92
105
.

Bengoa
 
Marta
,
Sanchez-Robles
 
Blanca
.
2003
. “
Foreign Direct Investment, Economic Freedom and Growth: New Evidence from Latin America
.”
European Journal of Political Economy
.
19
(
3
):
529
45
.

Benshaul-Tolonen
 
Anja
,
Chuhan-Pole
 
Punam
,
Dabalen
 
Andrew
,
Kotsadam
 
Andreas
,
Sanoh
 
Aly
.
2019
. “
The Local Socioeconomic Effects of Gold Mining: Evidence from Ghana
.”
The Extractive Industries and Society
.
6
(
4
):
1234
55
.

Bergougui
 
Brahim
,
Murshed
 
Syed
.
2023
. “
Spillover Effects of FDI Inflows on Output Growth: an Analysis of Aggregate and Disaggregated FDI Inflows of 13 MENA Economies
.”
Australian Economic Papers
.
62
(
4
):
668
92
.

Bill Chavez
 
Rebecca
.
2004
.
The Rule of Law in Nascent Democracies: Judicial Politics in Argentina
.
Stanford
:
Stanford University Press
.

Blanton
 
Robert
,
Blanton
 
Shannon
.
2012
. “
Labor Rights and Foreign Direct Investment: Is There a Race to the Bottom?
International Interactions
.
38
(
3
):
267
94
.

Blomström
 
Magnus
,
Lipsey
 
Robert
,
Zejan
 
Mario
.
1994
. “
What Explains the Growth of Developing Countries?
” In
Convergence of Productivity: Cross-National Studies and Historical Evidence
,
edited by
 
Baumol
 
William
,
Nelson
 
Richard
,
Wolff
 
Edward
,
243
59
.
New York
:
Oxford University Press
.

Blonigan
 
Bruce
,
Wang
 
Miao
.
2005
. “
Inappropriate Pooling of Wealthy and Poor Countries in Empirical FDI Studies
.” In
Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development?
,
edited by
 
Moran
 
Theodore
,
Graham
 
Edward
,
Blomström
 
Magnus
,
221
44
.
Washington
:
Peterson Institute for International Economics
.

Bluhm
 
Richard
,
Dreher
 
Axel
,
Fuchs
 
Andreas
,
Parks
 
Bradley
,
Strange
 
Austin
,
Tierney
 
Michael
.
2025
. “
Connective Financing: Chinese Infrastructure Projects and the Diffusion of Economic Activity in Developing Countries
.”
Journal of Urban Economics
.
145
.

Borensztein
 
Eduardo
,
De Gregorio
 
Jose
,
Lee
 
Jong-Wha
.
1998
. “
How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?
Journal of International Economics
.
45
(
1
):
115
35
.

Brazys
 
Samuel
,
Kotsadam
 
Andreas
.
2020
. “
Sunshine or Curse? Foreign Direct Investment, the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention, and Individual Corruption Experiences in Africa
.”
International Studies Quarterly
.
64
(
4
):
956
67
.

Bunte
 
Jonas
,
Desai
 
Harsh
,
Gbala
 
Kanio
,
Parks
 
Bradley
,
Runfola
 
Daniel Miller
.
2018
. “
Natural Resource Sector FDI, Government Policy, and Economic Growth: Quasi-Experimental Evidence from Liberia
.”
World Development
.
107
:
151
62
.

Büthe
 
Tim
,
Milner
 
Helen
.
2008
. “
The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?
American Journal of Political Science
.
52
(
4
):
741
62
.

Carkovic
 
Maria
,
Levine
 
Ross
.
2005
. “
Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Growth?
” In
Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development?
,
edited by
 
Moran
 
Theodore
,
Graham
 
Edward
,
Blomström
 
Magnus
,
195
220
.
Washington
:
Peterson Institute for International Economics
.

Caselli
 
Francesco
,
Michaels
 
Guy
.
2013
. “
Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards? Evidence from Brazil
.”
American Economic Journal: Applied Economics
.
5
(
1
):
208
38
.

Cederman
 
Lars-Erik
,
Weidmann
 
Nils
,
Bormann
 
Nils-Christian
.
2015
. “
Triangulating Horizontal Inequality: Toward Improved Conflict Analysis
.”
Journal of Peace Research
.
52
(
6
):
806
21
.

Chandra
 
Siddharth
,
Rudra
 
Nita
.
2015
. “
Reassessing the Links between Regime Type and Economic Performance: Why some Authoritarian Regimes Show Stable Growth and Others Do Not
.”
British Journal of Political Science
.
45
(
2
):
253
85
.

Chen
 
Xi
,
Nordhaus
 
William
.
2011
. “
Using Luminosity Data as a Proxy for Economic Statistics
.”
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
.
108
(
21
):
8589
94
.

Christensen
 
Darin
.
2019
. “
Concession Stands: How Mining Investments Incite Protest in Africa
.”
International Organization
.
73
(
1
):
65
101
.

Coppedge
 
Michael
,
Gerring
 
John
,
Knutsen
 
Carl
,
Lindberg
 
Staffan
,
Teorell
 
Jan
,
Altman
 
David
,
Bernhard
 
Michael
 et al.  
2020
. “
V-Dem Dataset v10
.”
Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project
.

De Mello
 
Luiz
.
1999
. “
Foreign Direct Investment-led Growth: Evidence from Time Series and Panel Data
.”
Oxford Economic Papers
.
51
(
1
):
133
51
.

Dunning
 
John
.
1993
.
Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy
.
Reading
:
Addison-Wesley
.

Dunning
 
John
.
2001
. “
The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm of International Production: Past, Present and Future
.”
International Journal of the Economics of Business
.
8
(
2
):
173
90
.

Dutt
 
Amitava
.
1997
. “
The Pattern of Direct Foreign Investment and Economic Growth
.”
World Development
.
25
(
11
):
1925
36
.

Elkins
 
Zachary
,
Guzman
 
Andrew
,
Simmons
 
Beth
.
2006
. “
Competing for Capital: The Diffusion of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1960-2000
.”
International Organization
.
60
(
4
):
811
46
.

Elvidge
 
Christopher
,
Baugh
 
Kimberly
,
Hobson
 
Vinita Ruth
,
Kihn
 
Eric
,
Kroehl
 
Herbert
,
Davis
 
Ethan
,
Cocero
 
David
.
1997
. “
Satellite Inventory of Human Settlements Using Nocturnal Radiation Emissions: a Contribution for the Global Toolchest
.”
Global Change Biology
.
3
(
5
):
387
95
.

Emako
 
Ezo
,
Nuru
 
Seid
,
Menza
 
Mesfin
.
2022
. “
The Effect of Foreign Direct Investment on Structural Transformation in Developing Countries
.”
Cogent Economics & Finance
.
10
(
1
).

Escribà-Folch
 
Abel
.
2017
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and the Risk of Regime Transition in Autocracies
.”
Democratization
.
24
(
1
):
61
80
.

Forte
 
Rosa
,
Moura
 
Rui
.
2013
. “
The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on the Host Country's Economic Growth: Theory and Empirical Evidence
.”
The Singapore Economic Review
.
58
(
3
):
1
28
.

Gerschewski
 
Johannes
.
2013a
. “
The Three Pillars of Stability: Legitimation, Repression, and Co-optation in Autocratic Regimes
.”
Democratization
.
20
(
1
):
13
38
.

Gerschewski
 
Stephan
.
2013b
. “
Do Local Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment? An Analysis of Spillover Effects in Developing Countries
.”
Asian Social Science
.
9
(
4
):
67
76
.

Gibson
 
Edward
.
2024
. “
Subnational Authoritarianism in Comparative Politics
.” In
The Oxford Handbook of Authoritarian Politics
, edited by
Wolf
 
Anne
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.

Godart
 
Oliver
,
Görg
 
Holger
.
2013
. “
Suppliers of Multinationals and the Forced Linkage Effect: Evidence from Firm Level Data
.”
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
.
94
:
393
404
.

Görg
 
Holger
,
Greenaway
 
David
.
2004
. “
Much Ado about Nothing? Do Domestic Firms Really Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?
World Bank Research Observer
.
19
(
2
):
171
98
.

Görg
 
Holger
,
Strobl
 
Eric
.
2002
. “
Multinational Companies and Indigenous Development: an Empirical Analysis
.”
European Economic Review
.
46
(
7
):
1305
22
.

Helpman
 
Elhanan
,
Melitz
 
Marc
,
Yeaple
 
Stephen
.
2004
. “
Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms
.”
American Economic Review
.
94
(
1
):
300
16
.

Henderson
 
J. Vernon
,
Storeygard
 
Adam
,
Weil
 
David
.
2011
. “
A Bright Idea for Measuring Economic Growth
.”
American Economic Review
.
101
(
3
):
194
9
.

Hermes
 
Niels
,
Lensink
 
Robert
.
2003
. “
Foreign Direct Investment, Financial Development and Economic Growth
.”
Journal of Development Studies
.
40
(
1
):
142
63
.

Hodler
 
Roland
,
Raschky
 
Paul
.
2014
. “
Regional Favoritism
.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
.
129
(
2
):
995
1033
.

Iamsiraroj
 
Sasi
.
2016
. “
The Foreign Direct Investment–Economic Growth Nexus
.”
International Review of Economics & Finance
.
42
:
116
33
.

Iamsiraroj
 
Sasi
,
Ulubaşoğlu
 
Mehmet Ali
.
2015
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: a Real Relationship or Wishful Thinking?
Economic Modelling
.
51
:
200
13
.

Imai
 
Kosuke
,
Kim
 
In Song
,
Wang
 
Erik
.
2023
. “
Matching Methods for Causal Inference with Time-Series Cross-Sectional Data
.”
American Journal of Political Science
.
67
(
3
):
587
605
.

Jensen
 
Nathan
.
2003
. “
Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment
.”
International Organization
.
57
(
3
):
587
616
.

Jensen
 
Nathan
.
2006
.
Nation-States and the Multinational Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment
.
Princeton
:
Princeton University Press
.

Jerven
 
Morten
.
2013
.
Poor Numbers: How We Are Misled by African Development Statistics and What to Do about It
.
Ithaca and London
:
Cornell University Press
.

Jung
 
Yoo Sun
,
Owen
 
Erica
,
Shim
 
Gyu Sang
.
2021
. “
Heterogeneity in How Investors Respond to Disputes: Greenfield FDI and Co-Industrial Disputes
.”
Journal of Politics
.
83
(
4
):
1260
74
.

Katitas
 
Aycan
,
Pandya
 
Sonal
.
2024
. “
Investment Incentives Attract Foreign Direct Investment: Evidence from the Great Recession
.”
Public Choice
.
200
(
1
):
323
45
.

Keola
 
Souknilanh
,
Andersson
 
Magnus
,
Hall
 
Ola
.
2015
. “
Monitoring Economic Development from Space: Using Nighttime Light and Land Cover Data to Measure Economic Growth
.”
World Development
.
66
:
322
34
.

Khadaroo
 
Jameel
,
Seetanah
 
Boopen
.
2009
. “
The Role of Transport Infrastructure in FDI: Evidence from Africa Using GMM Estimates
.”
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy
.
43
(
3
):
365
84
.

Kim
 
In Song
,
Rauh
 
Adam
,
Wang
 
Erik
,
Imai
 
Kosuke
.
2021
.
PanelMatch: Matching Methods for Causal Inference with Time-Series Cross-Sectional Data
.
R package version 2.0.0
.

Klein Goldewijk
 
Kees
,
Beusen
 
Arthur
,
Doelman
 
Jonathan
,
Stehfest
 
Elke
.
2017
. “
Anthropogenic Land Use Estimates for the Holocene—HYDE 3.2
.”
Earth System Science Data
.
9
(
2
):
927
53
.

Knutsen
 
Carl-Henrik
.
2021
. “
A Business Case for Democracy: Regime Type, Growth, and Growth Volatility
.”
Democratization
.
28
(
8
):
1505
24
.

Krugman
 
Paul
.
1991
. “
Increasing Returns and Economic Geography
.”
Journal of Political Economy
.
99
(
3
):
483
99
.

Kuhn
 
Patrick
,
Weidmann
 
Nils
.
2015
. “
Unequal We Fight: Between- and within-Group Inequality and Ethnic Civil War
.”
Political Science Research and Methods
.
3
(
3
):
543
68
.

Lessmann
 
Christian
.
2013
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Inequality: a Panel Data Analysis
.”
China Economic Review
.
24
(
1
):
129
49
.

Lessmann
 
Christian
,
Seidel
 
André
.
2017
. “
Regional Inequality, Convergence, and Its Determinants—a View from Outer Space
.”
European Economic Review
.
92
:
110
32
.

Li
 
Quan
.
2006
. “
Democracy, Autocracy, and Tax Incentives to Foreign Direct Investors: a Cross-National Analysis
.”
Journal of Politics
.
68
(
1
):
62
74
.

Li
 
Quan
,
Resnick
 
Adam
.
2003
. “
Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to Developing Countries
.”
International Organization
.
57
(
1
):
175
211
.

Li
 
Quan
,
Owen
 
Erica
,
Mitchell
 
Austin
.
2018
. “
Do Democracies Attract More Foreign Direct Investment? A Meta-Regression Analysis
.”
International Studies Quarterly
.
62
(
3
):
494
504
.

Li
 
Xiaoying
,
Liu
 
Xiaming
.
2005
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: an Increasingly Endogenous Relationship
.”
World Development
.
33
(
3
):
393
407
.

Li
 
Xuecao
,
Zhou
 
Yuyu
,
Zhao
 
Min
,
Zhao
 
Xia
.
2020
. “
A Harmonized Global Nighttime Light Dataset 1992–2018
Scientific Data
.
7
(
1
):
1
9
.

Lührmann
 
Anna
,
Tannenberg
 
Marcus
,
Lindberg
 
Staffan
.
2018
. “
Regimes of the World (RoW): Opening New Avenues for the Comparative Study of Political Regimes
.”
Politics and Governance
.
6
(
1
):
60
77
.

Marchetti
 
Cesare
.
1994
. “
Anthropological Invariants in Travel Behavior
.”
Technological Forecasting and Social Change
.
47
:
75
88
.

Markusen
 
James
,
Venables
 
Anthony
.
1999
. “
Foreign Direct Investment as a Catalyst for Industrial Development
.”
European Economic Review
.
43
(
2
):
335
56
.

Melitz
 
Marc
.
2003
. “
The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity
.”
Econometrica
.
71
(
6
):
1695
725
.

Mellander
 
Charlotta
,
Lobo
 
José
,
Stolarick
 
Kevin
,
Matheson
 
Zara
.
2015
. “
Night-Time Light Data: A Good Proxy Measure for Economic Activity?
PLoS ONE
.
10
(
10)
.

Merlevede
 
Bruno
,
Purice
 
Victoria
.
2016
. “
Distance, Time Since Foreign Entry, and Productivity Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment*
Papers in Regional Science
.
95
(
4
):
775
801
.

Messerschmidt
 
Luca
,
Janz
 
Nicole
.
2023
. “
Unravelling the ‘Race to the Bottom’ Argument: Foreign Direct Investment and Different Types of Labour Rights
.”
World Development
.
161
.

National Geophysical Data Center (NOAA)
.
2018a
. “
DMSP-OLS Nighttime Lights Time Series
.”
Accessed December 15, 2020. https://www.ngdc.noaa.gov/eog/dmsp.html

National Geophysical Data Center (NOAA)
.
2018b
. “
Nighttime VIIRS Day/Night Band Composites
.” .

Nielsen
 
Bo Bernhard
,
Asmussen
 
Christian Geisler
,
Weatherall
 
Cecilie Dohlmann
.
2017
. “
The Location Choice of Foreign Direct Investments: Empirical Evidence and Methodological Challenges
.”
Journal of World Business
.
52
(
1
):
62
82
.

Nunnenkamp
 
Peter
,
Spatz
 
Julius
.
2004
. “
FDI and Economic Growth in Developing Economices: How Relevant Are Host-economy and Industry Characteristics?
Transnational Corporations
.
13
(
3
):
53
83
.

OECD
.
2018
.
Geographical Distribution of Financial Flows to Developing Countries 2018. Disbursements, Commitments, Country Indicators
.
Paris
:
OECD Publishing
.

Owen
 
Erica
.
2019
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Elections: the Impact of Greenfield FDI on Incumbent Party Reelection in Brazil
.”
Comparative Political Studies
.
52
(
4
):
613
45
.

Paczynska
 
Agnieszka
.
2016
. “
Liberia Rising? Foreign Direct Investment, Persistent Inequalities and Political Tensions
.”
Peacebuilding
.
4
(
3
):
297
316
.

Palmtag
 
Tabea
,
Paula
 
Katrin
,
Rommel
 
Tobias
.
2025
. “
Beyond Economic Development? Foreign Direct Investment and Pre-Election Violence
.”
Journal of Peace Research
.
62
(
2
):
246
61
.

Palmtag
 
Tabea
,
Rommel
 
Tobias
,
Walter
 
Stefanie
.
2020
. “
International Trade and Public Protest: Evidence from Russian Regions
.”
International Studies Quarterly
.
64
(
4
):
939
55
.

Pandya
 
Sonal
.
2014
. “
Democratization and FDI Liberalization, 1970-2000
.”
International Studies Quarterly
.
58
(
3
):
475
88
.

Pandya
 
Sonal
.
2016
. “
Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment: Globalized Production in the Twenty-First Century
.”
Annual Review of Political Science
.
19
:
455
75
.

Pemstein
 
Daniel
,
Marquardt
 
Kyle
,
Tzelgov
 
Eitan
,
Wang
 
Yi-ting
,
Medzihorsky
 
Juraj
,
Krusell
 
Joshua
,
Miri
 
Farhad
,
von Römer
 
Johannes
.
2020
. “
The V-Dem Measurement Model: Latent Variable Analysis for Cross-National and Cross-Temporal Expert-Coded Data
.”
Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project
.

Perez-Sindin
 
Xaquin
,
Chen
 
Tzu-Hsin
,
Prishchepov
 
Alexander
.
2021
. “
Are Night-Time Lights a Good Proxy of Economic Activity in Rural Areas in Middle and Low-Income Countries? Examining the Empirical Evidence from Colombia
Remote Sensing Applications: Society and Environment
.
24
.

Proville
 
Jeremy
,
Zavala-Araiza
 
Daniel
,
Wagner
 
Gernot
.
2017
. “
Night-Time Lights: a Global, Long Term Look at Links to Socio-Economic Trends
.”
PLoS ONE
.
12
(
3
):
1
12
.

Ram
 
Rati
,
Zhang
 
Honglin
.
2002
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: Evidence from Cross-country Data for the 1990s
.”
Economic Development and Cultural Change
.
51
(
1
):
205
15
.

Rodríguez-Pose
 
Andrés
.
2018
. “
The Revenge of the Places that Don't Matter (and What to Do about It)
.”
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society
.
11
(
1
):
189
209
.

Romer
 
David
.
1986
. “
A Simple General Equilibrium Version of the Baumol-Tobin Model
.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
.
101
(
4
):
663
86
.

Rommel
 
Tobias
.
2018
.
Foreign Direct Investment and the Politics of Autocratic Survival
.
PhD Diss.
,
Zurich, Switzerland
:
University of Zurich
.

Rommel
 
Tobias
.
2024
. “
Foreign Direct Investment and Political Preferences in Non-Democratic Regimes
.”
Comparative Political Studies
.
57
(
8
):
1276
309
.

Shi
 
Min
,
Svensson
 
Jakob
.
2006
. “
Political Budget Cycles: Do They Differ across Countries and Why?
Journal of Public Economics
.
90
(
8-9
):
1367
89
.

Shmuel
 
Assaf
.
2020
. “
The Political Budget Cycle across Varying Degrees of Democracy
.”
Journal of Public Economics
.
68
.

Speakman
 
John
,
Koivisto
 
Marjo
.
2013
. “
Growth Poles: Raising Competitiveness and Deepening Regional Integration
.” In
The Africa Competitiveness Report 2013
,
edited by
 
The World Bank
,
93
106
.
Washington
:
The World Bank
.

Sutton
 
Paul
,
Elvidge
 
Christopher
,
Ghosh
 
Tilottama
.
2007
. “
Estimation of Gross Domestic Product at Sub-National Scales Using Nighttime Satellite Imagery
.”
International Journal of Ecological Economics & Statistics
.
8
(
S07
):
5
21
.

Tang
 
Sumei
,
Selvanathan
 
E.
,
Selvanathan
 
S.
.
2008
. “
Foreign Direct Investment, Domestic Investment and Economic Growth in China: a Time Series Analysis
.”
The World Economy
.
31
(
10
):
1292
309
.

The Financial Times Ltd
.
2018
. “
fDi Markets: the in-depth Crossborder Investment Monitor

Treisman
 
Daniel
.
2011
. “
Presidential Popularity in a Hybrid Regime: Russia under Yeltsin and Putin
.”
American Journal of Political Science
.
55
(
3
):
590
609
.

Walter
 
Stefanie
.
2010
. “
Globalization and the Welfare State: Testing the Microfoundations of the Compensation Hypothesis
.”
International Studies Quarterly
.
54
(
2
):
403
26
.

Weidmann
 
Nils
,
Schutte
 
Sebastian
.
2017
. “
Using Night Light Emissions for the Prediction of Local Wealth
.”
Journal of Peace Research
.
54
(
2
):
125
40
.

Wintrobe
 
Ronald
.
1998
.
The Political Economy of Dictatorship
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.

This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial reproduction and distribution of the work, in any medium, provided the original work is not altered or transformed in any way, and that the work is properly cited. For commercial re-use, please contact [email protected]

Supplementary data