Abstract

Web surveys often suffer from low response rates when invitations are sent via email. We conducted an experiment testing the effects of a $5 Starbucks gift card incentive on response rates and survey results from an email–web survey of Gulf of Mexico recreational anglers. Half the sample was randomly assigned to be offered the incentive for completion of the survey. Despite this, response rates were nearly identical between the incentivized (12 percent) and non-incentivized (13 percent) groups. Respondent demographics, fishing trip characteristics, and econometric estimates were highly consistent across groups. Statistical tests could not reject the null of no difference between the incentive treatments. Our results suggest foregoing small conditional non-monetary incentives can be cost-effective for this type of specialized recreation survey using an email protocol. However, generalizability to other populations, incentives, and protocols requires further research. The non-monetary incentive did not meaningfully impact response rates or estimates in this context.

1. Introduction

Incentives are often used to increase response rates and improve the quality of responses in surveys. There is considerable evidence suggesting that incentives work well when, for example, they are included in mail invitations to complete a survey on paper or on the internet as part of a mail-push strategy (Edwards et al. 2023). Less is known about the effectiveness of conditional incentives on response rates and quality in online-only surveys that make all contacts via email. Conditional incentives are popular because they are paid out after the completion of the survey task and are, therefore, less expensive than up-front unconditional incentive payments.1

We are focusing on a very specific, yet common, type of survey protocol that makes all contacts via email, including the initial invitation to complete the survey on the internet. This approach is a relatively fast and inexpensive way to collect data. However, the response rates tend to be low, especially when contacting people who are not expecting the email. A common way to incentivize participation is to offer a voucher or gift card upon completion of the survey.2 There is little published research examining the relative efficacy of this popular survey recruitment approach.

A recent review found evidence that monetary and non-monetary incentives increased response rates to online epidemiological surveys based on around twenty field experiment trials (Edwards et al. 2023).3 According to the review, however, it did not matter whether the incentive was delivered before (unconditional) or after (conditional) completing the survey. Looking more closely at the experiments included in Edwards et al. (2023), there is only one study that follows the email-only, conditional incentive strategy. Hathaway et al. (2021) found that cancer patients who received an email invitation promising a $10 gift card for completing an online survey were about twice as likely to respond than those who received an email invitation without the gift card promise.

There are a few field experiments not included in the above review that also followed a variant of the email invite, conditional-incentive protocol. Brown et al. (2016) found that a post-paid (conditional) incentive increased the response rate by about 14 percent in a sample of health care system clients.4 Note that the incentive was mailed and the respondent was given the option of a cash payment or gift card. Most respondents chose the cash. For the most part, the characteristics of study participants and the response to survey items were not statistically different between the treatment groups.5 In another field experiment, DeCamp and Manierre (2016) found that a low incentive ($2) did not change response rates, but that a higher incentive ($5) did increase response rates by around 40 percent in a sample of college students. The different incentive treatment groups were similarly representative of the population, consistent with administrative records at the college.

In contrast to the results of the field experiments, a recent meta-analysis model including more than 1,000 online education-related surveys found that, in general, incentives were not significantly correlated with response rates (Wu, Zhao, and Fils-Aime 2022). This result of no incentive effect on response rates was consistent with results reported in an earlier meta-analytical study of factors explaining response rate variation in online surveys (Cook, Heath, and Thompson 2000). Note, however, that the meta-analysis modeling approach cannot say anything regarding the causal effect of incentives on response rates.

We consider the implications of incentives in a valuation survey of recreational anglers, which is an important real-world setting because estimates of the value of recreational fishing are frequently used in policy analysis. For example, NOAA Fisheries analyzes the economic effects of every proposed change in saltwater fishing regulations and includes predictions of the change in economic value when the requisite data are available (National Marine Fisheries Service 2007). Studies to generate new estimates of economic value are costly and time consuming. It is important to find the most cost-effective survey (or other) approach to generate estimates of value that are relevant for policy analysis. Furthermore, we need to understand whether incentives change survey responses or, more crucially, the resulting estimates of sportfishing demand parameters and surplus measures.

Other studies have investigated the role of incentives in angler surveys, but none, to our knowledge, consider the effect of conditional incentives in email-only surveys. For example, NOAA's Fishing Effort Survey includes $2 along with the survey instrument in the invitation mailing because experiments found that the incentive increased the odds of responding by more than 90 percent (National Marine Fisheries Service Office of Science and Technology 2023, Andrews 2014). Similarly, Anderson et al. (2022) randomly assigned licensed anglers in the western United States to receive various cash incentives in a mail invitation to complete an online screener survey. They found that a $2 incentive increased response rates by more than 50 percent and a $5 incentive nearly doubled the response rate relative to no incentive. In an earlier analysis using the same survey form used in the present study, we found a similar doubling-of-response-rate result with a $2 mailed incentive in a mail-push strategy compared with an email-only survey with no incentive (Carter et al. 2024).5,6

We present the results of a random trial of the effect of conditional incentives in an email–web survey on response rates, sample characteristics, and angler demand estimates. Importantly, our trial considers a “cold” survey invitation with a conditional incentive, i.e. paid after the completion of the survey. Our results suggest that the surveys with and without incentives achieve similar response rates, and similar results for sample characteristics, demand model parameters, and measures of economic value. Therefore, an email–web survey that forgoes such incentives appears to be a more cost-effective solution.

2. Methods

2.1 Survey background

The fall 2023 version of the Florida Boating and Fishing Survey (FBFS) was conducted by the US National Atmospheric and Oceanic Administration (NOAA) to obtain information about Florida anglers’ fishing activity in the Gulf of Mexico (GOM).7 We administered the survey in November of 2023 to collect information about recreational fishing in the GOM during September and October of 2023. The target population for the FBFS was any person who might have used a private boat to fish offshore, specifically those who fished for Gag Grouper.8 We focused on Gag Grouper anglers because the policy-based contingent behavior (CB) questions in our survey (described below) concerned Gag Grouper. Around 6 percent of all trips by private boat anglers fishing from the west coast of Florida in 2022 targeted or caught Gag Grouper. In federal waters, the share of private boat angler trips fishing for Gag Grouper was even higher at around 21 percent.9

The recreational harvest of Gag Grouper in the GOM is managed with fixed seasons and bag limits. The bag limit has been two fish per angler since 2009, but the seasons varied considerably until 2016 when the season in federal waters was set to open in June and continue through the end of the year.10 In 2023, the Gag season closed early on October 19th. These regulations and related regulations in the commercial sector were implemented to protect the Gag Grouper stock, which was in decline during the early 2000s.

2.2 Survey questions

The FBFS was programmed in Qualtrics with questions designed to improve the prediction of changes in angler effort and economic value anticipated with changes in Gag Grouper bag limits and seasons. There were two main sections of the survey following a question confirming boat ownership and questions regarding the type of boat usage during September and October. For the respondents who used their boat for fishing, the first section asks a series of questions related to fishing activity during September and October. Specifically, respondents were asked to report the number of trips taken in September and October and the total cost paid by all anglers on a typical trip. We also asked for the duration of and the number of anglers on board a typical trip.

The second section of the survey contained two types of CB questions that asked respondents to report the number of trips they would have taken in September and October if fishing costs or Gag Grouper regulations were different. This is a type of reassessed contingent behavior trip question format that asks anglers to reassess how many trips they would have taken if hypothetical trip costs or Gag Grouper regulations had been in place (Simoes, Barata, and Cruz 2013). The full set of CB question scenarios is summarized in Table 1, where the first row represents actual conditions in September and October, the second two rows represent the cost (price) scenarios, and the last three rows represent the Gag Grouper bag limit scenarios. There are two sources of variation in the scenarios when collected for a set of anglers: (1) across anglers and (2) across scenarios within one angler.

Table 1.

Trip scenarios.

ScenarioPrice (p)Bag (r)Trips (d)
Base (actual)p02d0
Price changes   
 Double pricep1 = p0 × 2.02d1
 Half pricep2 = p0 × 0.52d2
Regulation changes   
 Bag threep03d3
 Bag onep01d4
 Bag zero (closed)p00d5
ScenarioPrice (p)Bag (r)Trips (d)
Base (actual)p02d0
Price changes   
 Double pricep1 = p0 × 2.02d1
 Half pricep2 = p0 × 0.52d2
Regulation changes   
 Bag threep03d3
 Bag onep01d4
 Bag zero (closed)p00d5
Table 1.

Trip scenarios.

ScenarioPrice (p)Bag (r)Trips (d)
Base (actual)p02d0
Price changes   
 Double pricep1 = p0 × 2.02d1
 Half pricep2 = p0 × 0.52d2
Regulation changes   
 Bag threep03d3
 Bag onep01d4
 Bag zero (closed)p00d5
ScenarioPrice (p)Bag (r)Trips (d)
Base (actual)p02d0
Price changes   
 Double pricep1 = p0 × 2.02d1
 Half pricep2 = p0 × 0.52d2
Regulation changes   
 Bag threep03d3
 Bag onep01d4
 Bag zero (closed)p00d5

The first CB question in the survey (row 2 of Table 1) asks for the number of trips that would have been taken if the cost had been double the cost of a typical trip and the second CB question (row 3) asks for the number of trips if the cost were half that of a typical trip. Note that we used piping on the internet survey to present respondents with trip cost alternatives that were double or half their actual reported costs.

The other three CB questions (rows 4 through 6) ask for the number of trips that would have been taken if the bag limit were three fish, one fish, or zero fish (closed season). These questions were only shown to those who reported fishing for Gag Grouper during September or October and stated that they might have taken a different number of trips if Gag Grouper regulations had been different. Note that the hypothetical regulation questions ask the angler to consider changes in the number of all of their trips, not just their trips that targeted Gag Grouper.11 For the analysis, we set the trips in the Gag Grouper regulation scenarios to the actual trips for those who stated that they would not have changed their trips under different Gag Grouper regulations.

2.3 Survey sampling and incentive experiment

The FBFS made all contacts (invitations, reminders, etc.) via email. There is no specific email list of Florida anglers fishing in the GOM for Gag Grouper. Therefore, we focused on anglers fishing from the west coast of Florida because nearly all of the recreational harvest of Gag Grouper originates from this area. We further narrowed our interest to boat-based anglers because Gag Grouper are primarily located around offshore reefs, which can only be reached by boat.

The State of Florida administers the State Reef Fish (FSRF) license, which is required to fish for reef fish, even for those who are over 65 and would not otherwise require a Florida saltwater fishing license. The FSRF license designation allowed us to more directly target the reef fish angling population of interest.

The State of Florida categorizes each record in the FSRF database based on county of residence and boat ownership. We narrowed the FSRF to boat owners with emails from the six strata likely to contain anglers fishing in the GOM.12 This subgroup comprises about 10 percent of the more than 800,000 FSFS licenses outstanding. A map of the sampling strata is shown in Fig. 1. We sampled 7,600 records, with the number of records for each stratum drawn in proportion to the relative share within the population subgroup. The 7,600 sample amount was selected given a target of 400 respondents who could fill out the Gag Grouper portion of the survey, an assumed response rate of 21 percent, and a Gag Grouper fishing prevalence rate of 25 percent based on previous work with the FSRF database and a similar sampling frame. Note that previous experience with the FSRF database actually achieved a response rate of around 16 percent. However, in planning for this survey we assumed that incentive (discussed below) would achieve an additional five percentage points in the overall response rate based on the literature reviewed in the introduction. Also, our target of 400 surveys completed (200 in each group) was based on a simple power analysis for a comparison of the incentive treatment group means using a t-test with a significance level of .05 to detect an effect size of 0.3 with a power of 0.8 (Champely 2020).

Counties in the sample frame.
Figure 1.

Counties in the sample frame.

We randomly assigned the 7,600 records in the FSRF sample to the incentive or no-incentive treatment groups (3,800 each).13 The text in the invitation email was identical between the two groups, with the exception of the second sentence, which read “(w)e will send you a $5 Starbucks gift card for carefully completing the 5 minute survey” for the incentive group and read “(t)he questions should take about 5 minutes” for the no incentive group.

Both groups received three reminder emails, approximately two days apart following the initial invitation. The text of the reminder emails was also identical except for the language about the gift card incentive.

2.4 Data analysis

2.4.1 Trip demand model and evaluation measures

Details regarding the derivation of the recreational fishing trip demand model can be found in Carter et al. (2022). For the purposes of this analysis, we assume that the trips follow a Poisson distribution and estimate the following fixed-effect trip demand model for the number of trips dijselected by angler i for scenario j:

(1)

where pijis the trip cost and associated parameter γ, rijis the bag limit with parameters δ and λ, and αiis an angler-specific fixed effect.14 We include an indicator, hij, for the hypothetical scenarios and interact the indicator with the trip cost variable.15 The parameters on the hypothetical indicator, θ and ϕ, are meant to capture the differences in the unmodeled factors that affect trips reported in the hypothetical scenarios (Englin and Cameron 1996; Haab, Sun, and Whitehead 2012). For example, the hypothetical indicator could measure errors on the part of the respondent. The internet survey reminded the respondent how many trips they took in the base case before each hypothetical scenario question. However, respondents could have made an error (e.g. recording or recall) such that the expected trips over the hypothetical scenarios at the baseline cost and bag limit do not equal the actual trips. The parameters associated with the dummy variable designating the hypothetical scenarios should capture this error.

With the Poisson fixed-effects estimator, the unobserved factors represented by the fixed effects can be correlated with p, r, or h without biasing the corresponding parameters. This is important because the angler response to changes in trip costs and bag limits is likely to be related to angler characteristics or fish stock conditions not included in the model.16

There are several other important measures that we calculate to compare between the two incentive treatments. The first type of measure is a semi-elasticity, which measures the percent change in trips expected with a unit change in trip cost or bag limit, all else equal. The average trip cost semi-elasticity is simply the parameter γ on this variable. The average semi-elasticity for the bag limit in scenario j is slightly more complicated because there is a squared term: ϵj= δ + 2λrj.

The other measures we compare between the incentive treatment groups are the value of a fishing trip and the change in value of fishing expected with a change in the Gag Grouper bag limit (Haab and McConnell 2002). The negative of the inverse of the trip cost parameter gives the expected value of a fishing trip, i.e. CS = 1.17 Similarly, the change in value per trip associated with a change in the bag limit is expressed as MWTPj= −ϵj, which measures the marginal willingness-to-pay (MWTP) for each bag limit increment.

2.4.2 Incentive treatment comparison

We consider several ways to formally compare the results between the two data collection treatments. First, we use χ2 tests to compare sample distribution (opened, started, finished, etc.) proportions and geographic stratification proportions between the treatment groups. Second, we use standard t-tests to compare the means of the key variables for both the sample overall and the Gag Grouper angler subset.18 Then, also on the Gag Grouper subset, we use a bootstrap-based approach to compare the trip demand model parameters (γ, δ, λ, ϕ), elasticities, ϵ, the value per trip (CS), and the MWTP for bag limit changes per trip estimates, MWTP.19

Specifically, we focus on the Gag Grouper angler subset and use a cluster bootstrap procedure (Cheng, Yu, and Huang 2013; Cameron and Miller 2015) in combination with the method of convolutions (Aizaki 2015; Poe, Giraud, and Loomis 2005) and an overlap index (Pastore 2018). First, we use the cluster bootstrap to obtain empirical distributions for the results of interest, denoted βt= (γt, δt, λt, ϕt, ϵt, CSt, MWTPt) for t = no − incentive, incentive, as follows:

  1. Sample anglers (respondents) with replacement Nttimes from the original sample of anglers.

  2. For the sampled Ntanglers, retain the observations for all six scenarios.

  3. Obtain estimates of βtwith the fixed-effects Poisson regression using the 6 × Ntobservations.

  4. Repeat steps 1, 2, and 3 B times to obtain B bootstrap estimates of βt.

Note that the resampling is done over anglers, rather than over scenarios. In this way, some anglers may not appear in bootstrap samples at all while other anglers will appear multiple times. The result of the bootstrap simulation gives vectors of length B for each element in βtfor each incentive treatment group t. We then use the method of convolutions to test the null hypothesis of estimate equality (Aizaki 2015; Poe, Giraud, and Loomis 2005). Specifically, we apply the method of convolutions to corresponding vectors in β for each treatment group. For example, to evaluate the null of equality of the value per trip estimates for the no incentive and incentive groups, we apply the method of convolutions on the vectors CSno−incentiveand CSincentive. Lastly, we evaluate the overlap of the two bootstrap distributions for each result of interest using plots and an overlap index (Pastore 2018). The overlap plots and indices offer another way to visualize and compare the distributions of the economic measures estimated using the two incentive treatment groups.

3. Results

3.1 Sampling results and sample characteristics

The final disposition of the samples is shown in Table 2. Of the 3,800 emails sent to each treatment group, the general return profile is very close between the two treatment groups. However, a test of equality for the status proportions in each group can be rejected at the .05 level using a χ2 test, which is unsurprising given the large sample size. It is notable that more than a third of emails were not even opened and that roughly half of those who opened the email did not start the survey. This was true whether or not the incentive was offered. Most people who started the survey finished. The response rates are consistent with other angler surveys employing similar sampling strategies (Wallen et al. 2016). Note, however, that we were not able to obtain a higher response rate using the incentive, with roughly 15 percent of delivered surveys at least started in both treatments. The distribution of the responses is shown by strata in Table 3 by treatment along with the disposition of the original sample, which was drawn to be representative of the population. Both treatment groups are similarly distributed among the strata and match the sample/population distribution relatively well.

Table 2.

Distribution summary by incentive treatment.

StatusNo incentiveIncentive
Didn't arrive78 (2.05%)67 (1.76%)
Not opened1,368 (36.0%)1,382 (36.4%)
Opened, not started1,782 (46.9%)1,834 (48.3%)
Survey finished489 (12.9%)469 (12.3%)
Survey started, not finished83 (2.18%)48 (1.26%)
StatusNo incentiveIncentive
Didn't arrive78 (2.05%)67 (1.76%)
Not opened1,368 (36.0%)1,382 (36.4%)
Opened, not started1,782 (46.9%)1,834 (48.3%)
Survey finished489 (12.9%)469 (12.3%)
Survey started, not finished83 (2.18%)48 (1.26%)

P value for test of equality of proportions: .022.

Table 2.

Distribution summary by incentive treatment.

StatusNo incentiveIncentive
Didn't arrive78 (2.05%)67 (1.76%)
Not opened1,368 (36.0%)1,382 (36.4%)
Opened, not started1,782 (46.9%)1,834 (48.3%)
Survey finished489 (12.9%)469 (12.3%)
Survey started, not finished83 (2.18%)48 (1.26%)
StatusNo incentiveIncentive
Didn't arrive78 (2.05%)67 (1.76%)
Not opened1,368 (36.0%)1,382 (36.4%)
Opened, not started1,782 (46.9%)1,834 (48.3%)
Survey finished489 (12.9%)469 (12.3%)
Survey started, not finished83 (2.18%)48 (1.26%)

P value for test of equality of proportions: .022.

Table 3.

Strata disposition by incentive treatment for the sample and completed surveys.

StrataIncentiveNo incentiveSample
Keys/Gulf26 (5.54%)27 (5.52%)342 (4.50%)
North/Gulf66 (14.1%)94 (19.2%)1,251 (16.5%)
North/Inland78 (16.6%)88 (18.0%)1,712 (22.5%)
Panhandle/Gulf88 (18.8%)83 (17.0%)1,286 (16.9%)
South/Gulf185 (39.4%)178 (36.4%)2,487 (32.7%)
South/Inland26 (5.54%)19 (3.89%)522 (6.87%)
StrataIncentiveNo incentiveSample
Keys/Gulf26 (5.54%)27 (5.52%)342 (4.50%)
North/Gulf66 (14.1%)94 (19.2%)1,251 (16.5%)
North/Inland78 (16.6%)88 (18.0%)1,712 (22.5%)
Panhandle/Gulf88 (18.8%)83 (17.0%)1,286 (16.9%)
South/Gulf185 (39.4%)178 (36.4%)2,487 (32.7%)
South/Inland26 (5.54%)19 (3.89%)522 (6.87%)

P values for test of equality of proportions:

Incentive versus no incentive, P = .263.

Incentive versus sample, P = .011.

No incentive versus sample, P = .013.

Table 3.

Strata disposition by incentive treatment for the sample and completed surveys.

StrataIncentiveNo incentiveSample
Keys/Gulf26 (5.54%)27 (5.52%)342 (4.50%)
North/Gulf66 (14.1%)94 (19.2%)1,251 (16.5%)
North/Inland78 (16.6%)88 (18.0%)1,712 (22.5%)
Panhandle/Gulf88 (18.8%)83 (17.0%)1,286 (16.9%)
South/Gulf185 (39.4%)178 (36.4%)2,487 (32.7%)
South/Inland26 (5.54%)19 (3.89%)522 (6.87%)
StrataIncentiveNo incentiveSample
Keys/Gulf26 (5.54%)27 (5.52%)342 (4.50%)
North/Gulf66 (14.1%)94 (19.2%)1,251 (16.5%)
North/Inland78 (16.6%)88 (18.0%)1,712 (22.5%)
Panhandle/Gulf88 (18.8%)83 (17.0%)1,286 (16.9%)
South/Gulf185 (39.4%)178 (36.4%)2,487 (32.7%)
South/Inland26 (5.54%)19 (3.89%)522 (6.87%)

P values for test of equality of proportions:

Incentive versus no incentive, P = .263.

Incentive versus sample, P = .011.

No incentive versus sample, P = .013.

Table 4 shows the means of respondent characteristics by treatment along with the P values for t-tests of mean differences.20 Nearly 60 percent of respondents used their boat during the study period and roughly half used their boat to fish in the GOM. Furthermore, around 20 percent of respondents stated that they “fished for Gag Grouper” in the GOM during the study period. Note, however, that we did not obtain the target number (400) of Gag Grouper anglers because incentives did not provide the five percentage-point increase in the response rate overall that we had assumed.21

Table 4.

Means of respondent characteristics by incentive treatment.

 No incentiveIncentiveP value
N489469 
Boater0.59 (0.49)0.57 (0.50).381
Fisher0.50 (0.50)0.47 (0.50).292
Gag fisher0.23 (0.42)0.21 (0.41).460
Age51.9 (12.6)51.6 (13.7).729
Income (0,000)15.7 (8.68)15.1 (8.51).271
Trips3.15 (6.00)2.49 (3.89).044
 No incentiveIncentiveP value
N489469 
Boater0.59 (0.49)0.57 (0.50).381
Fisher0.50 (0.50)0.47 (0.50).292
Gag fisher0.23 (0.42)0.21 (0.41).460
Age51.9 (12.6)51.6 (13.7).729
Income (0,000)15.7 (8.68)15.1 (8.51).271
Trips3.15 (6.00)2.49 (3.89).044

Standard errors in parentheses.

Table 4.

Means of respondent characteristics by incentive treatment.

 No incentiveIncentiveP value
N489469 
Boater0.59 (0.49)0.57 (0.50).381
Fisher0.50 (0.50)0.47 (0.50).292
Gag fisher0.23 (0.42)0.21 (0.41).460
Age51.9 (12.6)51.6 (13.7).729
Income (0,000)15.7 (8.68)15.1 (8.51).271
Trips3.15 (6.00)2.49 (3.89).044
 No incentiveIncentiveP value
N489469 
Boater0.59 (0.49)0.57 (0.50).381
Fisher0.50 (0.50)0.47 (0.50).292
Gag fisher0.23 (0.42)0.21 (0.41).460
Age51.9 (12.6)51.6 (13.7).729
Income (0,000)15.7 (8.68)15.1 (8.51).271
Trips3.15 (6.00)2.49 (3.89).044

Standard errors in parentheses.

The results in Table 4 are very similar between the two groups, with only the difference in the mean number of trips showing as statistically different from zero according to the P values. The difference in trips suggests that those who were not offered the incentive reported taking slightly more trips during the study period. However, the standard error of the mean estimated number of trips was considerably larger for those who were not offered the incentive. This result could also reflect the idea that relatively less avid anglers were induced to participate by the incentive.

Table 5 presents the means for respondents who said that they fished for Gag Grouper in the GOM during the open season. This is the population of interest for the analysis of the effect of changes in Gag Grouper regulations. With the exception of trip hours, all angler and trip characteristics are similar between the treatment groups with no statistically significant differences. Anglers who fished for Gag Grouper in the incentive group reported slightly shorter trips on average than anglers who fished for Gag Grouper in the group that did not receive the incentive.

Table 5.

Means of respondent and trip characteristics for Gag fishers by incentive treatment.

 No incentiveIncentiveP values
N11398 
Age52.6 (13.2)49.4 (12.0).060
Income (0,000)16.3 (8.42)16.4 (9.18).950
Trips6.46 (7.39)6.41 (5.03).952
Trip cost351 (410)311 (411).486
People3.40 (1.97)3.02 (1.22).091
Hours7.32 (2.11)6.73 (1.89).035
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost3.20 (5.88)3.30 (3.23).886
 Trips, half cost9.37 (9.61)9.19 (7.83).883
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags7.10 (7.92)7.17 (6.30).938
 Trips, one bag5.72 (7.33)5.65 (5.54).943
 Trips, zero bag4.99 (7.46)5.20 (5.44).811
 No incentiveIncentiveP values
N11398 
Age52.6 (13.2)49.4 (12.0).060
Income (0,000)16.3 (8.42)16.4 (9.18).950
Trips6.46 (7.39)6.41 (5.03).952
Trip cost351 (410)311 (411).486
People3.40 (1.97)3.02 (1.22).091
Hours7.32 (2.11)6.73 (1.89).035
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost3.20 (5.88)3.30 (3.23).886
 Trips, half cost9.37 (9.61)9.19 (7.83).883
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags7.10 (7.92)7.17 (6.30).938
 Trips, one bag5.72 (7.33)5.65 (5.54).943
 Trips, zero bag4.99 (7.46)5.20 (5.44).811

Standard errors in parentheses.

Table 5.

Means of respondent and trip characteristics for Gag fishers by incentive treatment.

 No incentiveIncentiveP values
N11398 
Age52.6 (13.2)49.4 (12.0).060
Income (0,000)16.3 (8.42)16.4 (9.18).950
Trips6.46 (7.39)6.41 (5.03).952
Trip cost351 (410)311 (411).486
People3.40 (1.97)3.02 (1.22).091
Hours7.32 (2.11)6.73 (1.89).035
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost3.20 (5.88)3.30 (3.23).886
 Trips, half cost9.37 (9.61)9.19 (7.83).883
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags7.10 (7.92)7.17 (6.30).938
 Trips, one bag5.72 (7.33)5.65 (5.54).943
 Trips, zero bag4.99 (7.46)5.20 (5.44).811
 No incentiveIncentiveP values
N11398 
Age52.6 (13.2)49.4 (12.0).060
Income (0,000)16.3 (8.42)16.4 (9.18).950
Trips6.46 (7.39)6.41 (5.03).952
Trip cost351 (410)311 (411).486
People3.40 (1.97)3.02 (1.22).091
Hours7.32 (2.11)6.73 (1.89).035
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost3.20 (5.88)3.30 (3.23).886
 Trips, half cost9.37 (9.61)9.19 (7.83).883
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags7.10 (7.92)7.17 (6.30).938
 Trips, one bag5.72 (7.33)5.65 (5.54).943
 Trips, zero bag4.99 (7.46)5.20 (5.44).811

Standard errors in parentheses.

Table 5 also shows the summary statistics for all of the hypothetical trip scenarios shown in Table 1. In general, the results are as expected with higher trips reported at lower costs, lower trips at higher costs, and trips increasing in the Gag Grouper bag limit offered. We cannot reject the null of equality of the hypothetical trips between the treatment groups for any scenario.22

In Fig. 2, we illustrate the similarity in trip demand between the incentive treatment groups by plotting the piecewise linear trip demand relationships based on the mean trips reported in the actual, cost doubling and cost halving scenarios for the Gag Grouper anglers. Consistent with the results in Table 5, the curves for the two treatment groups are relatively close together.

Piecewise linear trip demand based on the cost doubling and cost halving contingent behavior questions by conditional incentive treatment.
Figure 2.

Piecewise linear trip demand based on the cost doubling and cost halving contingent behavior questions by conditional incentive treatment.

3.2 Fishing trip demand and value

The estimated parameters of the trip demand regressions are shown in Table 6 for the sample of Gag Grouper anglers. Note that the number of observations is given by the number of Gag Grouper anglers reported in Table 5 times 6 for the number of scenarios shown in Table 1. We use cluster-robust standard errors to adjust for the fact that the multiple observations from the same individual are likely to be correlated. These adjusted standard errors account for both overdispersion and correlation over choices for a given angler (Bergé 2018).

Table 6.

Poisson fixed-effect trip demand regression.

 ParameterNo incentiveIncentiveAll
Trip demand model parameters
Trip cost per angler (1/10)
 γ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗
  (0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Bag limitθ0.1150.0820.100
  (0.059)(0.048)(0.039)
(Bag limit)2δ0.0000.0090.004
  (0.015)(0.013)(0.010)
Hypotheticalλ0.0330.0400.037
  (0.032)(0.030)(0.022)
Trip cost (1/10) × hypotheticalϕ0.001∗∗
(0.000)
0.001
(0.000)
0.001∗∗
(0.000)
     
CS per trip
CS per trip (actual)
1231.577∗∗∗267.769∗∗∗245.483∗∗∗
  (31.383)(72.311)(33.398)
 CS per trip (hypothetical)1/(γ + ϕ)206.902∗∗∗
(29.945)
233.744∗∗∗
(68.854)
217.152∗∗∗
(31.550)
     
Bag limit semi-elasticities    
Semi-elasticity: zero bagδ + 2λ00.115∗∗∗
(0.059)
0.082∗∗∗
(0.048)
0.100∗∗∗
(0.039)
Semi-elasticity: one bagδ + 2λ10.114∗∗∗
(0.035)
0.099∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.108∗∗∗
(0.023)
Semi-elasticity: two bagδ + 2λ20.114∗∗∗
(0.027)
0.117∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.115∗∗∗
(0.020)
     
Bag limit MWTP    
MWTP: zero bag(δ + 2λ0)26.601
(11.793)
21.913
(14.976)
24.630
(9.651)
MWTP: one bag(δ + 2λ1)26.475∗∗∗
(6.817)
26.617
(11.562)
26.441∗∗∗
(6.303)
MWTP: two bag(δ + 2λ2)26.349∗∗∗
(6.972)
31.321
(12.068)
28.252∗∗∗
(6.180)
Log likelihood 1,421.3541,262.4212,684.674
Number of observations 6785881,266
Bayesian information criterion 3,6123,1826,912
Akaike information criterion 3,0792,7315,801
 ParameterNo incentiveIncentiveAll
Trip demand model parameters
Trip cost per angler (1/10)
 γ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗
  (0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Bag limitθ0.1150.0820.100
  (0.059)(0.048)(0.039)
(Bag limit)2δ0.0000.0090.004
  (0.015)(0.013)(0.010)
Hypotheticalλ0.0330.0400.037
  (0.032)(0.030)(0.022)
Trip cost (1/10) × hypotheticalϕ0.001∗∗
(0.000)
0.001
(0.000)
0.001∗∗
(0.000)
     
CS per trip
CS per trip (actual)
1231.577∗∗∗267.769∗∗∗245.483∗∗∗
  (31.383)(72.311)(33.398)
 CS per trip (hypothetical)1/(γ + ϕ)206.902∗∗∗
(29.945)
233.744∗∗∗
(68.854)
217.152∗∗∗
(31.550)
     
Bag limit semi-elasticities    
Semi-elasticity: zero bagδ + 2λ00.115∗∗∗
(0.059)
0.082∗∗∗
(0.048)
0.100∗∗∗
(0.039)
Semi-elasticity: one bagδ + 2λ10.114∗∗∗
(0.035)
0.099∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.108∗∗∗
(0.023)
Semi-elasticity: two bagδ + 2λ20.114∗∗∗
(0.027)
0.117∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.115∗∗∗
(0.020)
     
Bag limit MWTP    
MWTP: zero bag(δ + 2λ0)26.601
(11.793)
21.913
(14.976)
24.630
(9.651)
MWTP: one bag(δ + 2λ1)26.475∗∗∗
(6.817)
26.617
(11.562)
26.441∗∗∗
(6.303)
MWTP: two bag(δ + 2λ2)26.349∗∗∗
(6.972)
31.321
(12.068)
28.252∗∗∗
(6.180)
Log likelihood 1,421.3541,262.4212,684.674
Number of observations 6785881,266
Bayesian information criterion 3,6123,1826,912
Akaike information criterion 3,0792,7315,801

P < .05; ∗∗P < .01; ∗∗∗P < .001. P values for the null that the estimate is equal to zero.

Table 6.

Poisson fixed-effect trip demand regression.

 ParameterNo incentiveIncentiveAll
Trip demand model parameters
Trip cost per angler (1/10)
 γ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗
  (0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Bag limitθ0.1150.0820.100
  (0.059)(0.048)(0.039)
(Bag limit)2δ0.0000.0090.004
  (0.015)(0.013)(0.010)
Hypotheticalλ0.0330.0400.037
  (0.032)(0.030)(0.022)
Trip cost (1/10) × hypotheticalϕ0.001∗∗
(0.000)
0.001
(0.000)
0.001∗∗
(0.000)
     
CS per trip
CS per trip (actual)
1231.577∗∗∗267.769∗∗∗245.483∗∗∗
  (31.383)(72.311)(33.398)
 CS per trip (hypothetical)1/(γ + ϕ)206.902∗∗∗
(29.945)
233.744∗∗∗
(68.854)
217.152∗∗∗
(31.550)
     
Bag limit semi-elasticities    
Semi-elasticity: zero bagδ + 2λ00.115∗∗∗
(0.059)
0.082∗∗∗
(0.048)
0.100∗∗∗
(0.039)
Semi-elasticity: one bagδ + 2λ10.114∗∗∗
(0.035)
0.099∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.108∗∗∗
(0.023)
Semi-elasticity: two bagδ + 2λ20.114∗∗∗
(0.027)
0.117∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.115∗∗∗
(0.020)
     
Bag limit MWTP    
MWTP: zero bag(δ + 2λ0)26.601
(11.793)
21.913
(14.976)
24.630
(9.651)
MWTP: one bag(δ + 2λ1)26.475∗∗∗
(6.817)
26.617
(11.562)
26.441∗∗∗
(6.303)
MWTP: two bag(δ + 2λ2)26.349∗∗∗
(6.972)
31.321
(12.068)
28.252∗∗∗
(6.180)
Log likelihood 1,421.3541,262.4212,684.674
Number of observations 6785881,266
Bayesian information criterion 3,6123,1826,912
Akaike information criterion 3,0792,7315,801
 ParameterNo incentiveIncentiveAll
Trip demand model parameters
Trip cost per angler (1/10)
 γ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗ 0.004∗∗∗
  (0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Bag limitθ0.1150.0820.100
  (0.059)(0.048)(0.039)
(Bag limit)2δ0.0000.0090.004
  (0.015)(0.013)(0.010)
Hypotheticalλ0.0330.0400.037
  (0.032)(0.030)(0.022)
Trip cost (1/10) × hypotheticalϕ0.001∗∗
(0.000)
0.001
(0.000)
0.001∗∗
(0.000)
     
CS per trip
CS per trip (actual)
1231.577∗∗∗267.769∗∗∗245.483∗∗∗
  (31.383)(72.311)(33.398)
 CS per trip (hypothetical)1/(γ + ϕ)206.902∗∗∗
(29.945)
233.744∗∗∗
(68.854)
217.152∗∗∗
(31.550)
     
Bag limit semi-elasticities    
Semi-elasticity: zero bagδ + 2λ00.115∗∗∗
(0.059)
0.082∗∗∗
(0.048)
0.100∗∗∗
(0.039)
Semi-elasticity: one bagδ + 2λ10.114∗∗∗
(0.035)
0.099∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.108∗∗∗
(0.023)
Semi-elasticity: two bagδ + 2λ20.114∗∗∗
(0.027)
0.117∗∗∗
(0.029)
0.115∗∗∗
(0.020)
     
Bag limit MWTP    
MWTP: zero bag(δ + 2λ0)26.601
(11.793)
21.913
(14.976)
24.630
(9.651)
MWTP: one bag(δ + 2λ1)26.475∗∗∗
(6.817)
26.617
(11.562)
26.441∗∗∗
(6.303)
MWTP: two bag(δ + 2λ2)26.349∗∗∗
(6.972)
31.321
(12.068)
28.252∗∗∗
(6.180)
Log likelihood 1,421.3541,262.4212,684.674
Number of observations 6785881,266
Bayesian information criterion 3,6123,1826,912
Akaike information criterion 3,0792,7315,801

P < .05; ∗∗P < .01; ∗∗∗P < .001. P values for the null that the estimate is equal to zero.

A detailed discussion of the regression model parameters and outputs shown in Table 6 is beyond the scope of this analysis. We focus here on the key model outputs that are important for policy analysis and how these estimates compare between the incentive and no incentive treatment groups. The trip cost parameters, γ, are identical up to three decimal points for the two treatment groups.23 These parameters represent the percent change in trips with a unit change in trip cost for the average angler who targeted Gag Grouper. The negative of the reciprocal of the travel cost parameter measures the CS or value per trip for the average angler (Haab and McConnell 2002), which is around $250 as shown in Table 6. The CS per trip estimates are relatively close between the treatment groups. We consider more formal comparisons below.

The trip response of anglers to bag limit changes is formally measured in Table 6 as bag limit semi-elasticities, i.e. the percent change in trips with a unit change in the bag limit. We use the semi-elasticity expressions for the bag limit changes presented earlier to calculate the bag limit semi-elasticity starting from zero, one, and two fish. Generally, the percent change in trips with a unit change in the bag limit increases at a decreasing rate with each bag limit increment for the group that received the incentive, but seems relatively stable overall and for the group that received the incentive.

The last set of measures shown in Table 6 is the estimates of the marginal MWTP or CSjfor a change in the bag limit. Similar to the semi-elasticities, the MWTP is relatively stable at around $26 over different bag limits overall and for the group that did not receive the incentive. The MWTP appears to be linearly increasing for the group that received the incentive.

3.3 Survey mode comparison analysis

The results of the bootstrap analysis are shown in Fig. 3. The plots show the bootstrapped distributions by incentive treatment for each parameter to visualize the extent of the overlap. The distributions for most of the parameters and measures overlap. However, the distribution of the trip cost parameter in the incentive group shows relatively more variance. This higher variance is also seen in the CS per trip and, to a lesser extent, the MWTP for bag limit estimates for the incentive group.

Overlap of parameter distributions of by incentive treatment.
Figure 3.

Overlap of parameter distributions of by incentive treatment.

The overlap for each parameter is numerically evaluated in Table 7 where we give a formal measure of the percentage of overlap (Pastore 2018) and the P values based on the method of convolutions for the null hypothesis that the means for each treatment group are equal. We also show the average of the ratio (mean ratio) for the estimates between the two modes. Consistent with the overlap plots, the trip cost parameter has a high level of overlap, which is also apparent in the CS per trip because CS is simply the negative of the reciprocal of the trip cost parameter. Furthermore, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the CS per trip is equal between modes at a .05 significance level.

Table 7.

Comparison of the means for the incentive treatments.

MeasureRatioOverlapP Value
Trip demand model parameters
 Trip cost per angler (1/10)1.210.62.669
 Hypothetical1.280.92.533
 Bag limit3.190.74.325
  (Bag limit)20.880.73.682
 Trip cost (1/10) × hypothetical1.130.73.523
CS per trip
 CS per trip (actual)0.910.62.669
 CS per trip (hypothetical)0.920.65.634
Bag limit semi-elasticities
 Semi-elasticity: zero bag3.190.74.325
 Semi-elasticity: one bag1.280.80.365
 Semi-elasticity: two bags1.040.96.525
Bag limit MWTP
 MWTP: zero bag3.630.78.411
 MWTP: one bag1.170.75.505
 MWTP: two bags0.950.74.638
MeasureRatioOverlapP Value
Trip demand model parameters
 Trip cost per angler (1/10)1.210.62.669
 Hypothetical1.280.92.533
 Bag limit3.190.74.325
  (Bag limit)20.880.73.682
 Trip cost (1/10) × hypothetical1.130.73.523
CS per trip
 CS per trip (actual)0.910.62.669
 CS per trip (hypothetical)0.920.65.634
Bag limit semi-elasticities
 Semi-elasticity: zero bag3.190.74.325
 Semi-elasticity: one bag1.280.80.365
 Semi-elasticity: two bags1.040.96.525
Bag limit MWTP
 MWTP: zero bag3.630.78.411
 MWTP: one bag1.170.75.505
 MWTP: two bags0.950.74.638

The ratio is defined as the no incentive estimate over the incentive estimate. The P value is for the null hypothesis that means are equal for the incentive treatments.

Table 7.

Comparison of the means for the incentive treatments.

MeasureRatioOverlapP Value
Trip demand model parameters
 Trip cost per angler (1/10)1.210.62.669
 Hypothetical1.280.92.533
 Bag limit3.190.74.325
  (Bag limit)20.880.73.682
 Trip cost (1/10) × hypothetical1.130.73.523
CS per trip
 CS per trip (actual)0.910.62.669
 CS per trip (hypothetical)0.920.65.634
Bag limit semi-elasticities
 Semi-elasticity: zero bag3.190.74.325
 Semi-elasticity: one bag1.280.80.365
 Semi-elasticity: two bags1.040.96.525
Bag limit MWTP
 MWTP: zero bag3.630.78.411
 MWTP: one bag1.170.75.505
 MWTP: two bags0.950.74.638
MeasureRatioOverlapP Value
Trip demand model parameters
 Trip cost per angler (1/10)1.210.62.669
 Hypothetical1.280.92.533
 Bag limit3.190.74.325
  (Bag limit)20.880.73.682
 Trip cost (1/10) × hypothetical1.130.73.523
CS per trip
 CS per trip (actual)0.910.62.669
 CS per trip (hypothetical)0.920.65.634
Bag limit semi-elasticities
 Semi-elasticity: zero bag3.190.74.325
 Semi-elasticity: one bag1.280.80.365
 Semi-elasticity: two bags1.040.96.525
Bag limit MWTP
 MWTP: zero bag3.630.78.411
 MWTP: one bag1.170.75.505
 MWTP: two bags0.950.74.638

The ratio is defined as the no incentive estimate over the incentive estimate. The P value is for the null hypothesis that means are equal for the incentive treatments.

There is also a relatively high level of agreement in the plots and overlap measures for the bag limit parameters and the bag limit semi-elasticities and MWTP measures. None of the parameters and measures of interest are statistically different between modes at the .05 significance level. All of the measures in the table demonstrate more than 60 percent overlap between treatment groups.

4. Discussion

We collected data on recreational fishing trip behavior from anglers via email invitations to a web survey. Half of the sample was randomly assigned to be offered a conditional, non-monetary incentive (gift card) for completing the survey.

There was little difference in the response rate between the incentive treatment groups, and summary statistics for more than ten different variables were very close between the treatment groups. The estimated parameters of the same recreational fishing trip demand model specification estimated using data from each treatment group were also very similar according to a bootstrap analysis that compared distribution plots, formal measures of overlap, and P values.

Both treatment groups directed respondents to complete the survey on the internet via email and the survey protocol was identical between the groups. Therefore, the costs of the web survey development and administration were the same for both survey strategies. The only differences in costs were the expense to administer the gift cards and the total face value of the cards. Based on our results, these additional costs, amounting to nearly $4,000 in our case, do not appear warranted.

More research is necessary to determine the extent to which our findings can be generalized. For example, there may be other domains where conditional incentives to complete web surveys offered via email work to increase response rates and the quality of survey data. Our results could also depend on the type and amount of incentives offered, such as the $5 Starbucks gift card used in our study.24 Research with other modes (e.g. mail) has found that unconditional cash incentives perform better than “non-monetary” offers and that higher incentives tend to generate higher response rates (Edwards et al. 2023). Conditional cash payments may work better than conditional non-monetary incentives. Unconditional gift cards could be explored as well. We had success in improving response rates with an unconditional cash incentive as part of a mail-push strategy, albeit with little difference in response quality (Carter et al. 2024). Others have found similar results with a mail-push-incentive strategy (Anderson et al. 2022). However, unconditional incentives for email-to-web surveys could be expensive and even wasteful if the improvements in response rates and survey quality are not significant.

Acknowledgments

We would like to acknowledge the help from the Florida State Reef Fish Survey Program in securing the sample for this study and thank the anglers who responded to the survey.

Conflict of interest

None declared.

Funding

None declared.

Data availability

The data underlying this article will be shared on reasonable request to the corresponding author.

Footnotes

1

We do not consider the work related to the use of incentives in other survey modes (e.g. Mercer et al. 2015) or the use of unconditional incentives in email-only web surveys. The latter can be very expensive and potentially wasteful given the relatively low response rates typically encountered in email-contact surveys. We also do not cover the work related to online panels.

2

Lotteries have also been used to encourage participation, but this approach is not available for surveys administered by US Government agencies that have to obtain Office of Management and Budget (OMB) approval.

3

A separate meta-analysis of field experiments found that incentives increased response rates (Abdelazeem et al. 2023). However, this analysis combined all survey modes (mail, web, etc.) and did not examine web-based/electronic surveys separately. Furthermore, all but three of the eleven web-based surveys included in the forty-six-study meta-analysis were also included in Edwards et al. (2023). The three studies excluded from Edwards et al. (2023) were of very specialized populations (e.g. senior dementia patients, applicants to a service organization, and first-year college students living on campus).

4

The protocol included a mailed paper survey if there was no response after three reminder emails. We calculated the response rate based on surveys completed via the web instrument using the information in fig. 1 of Brown et al. (2016). Including the follow-up mail survey results, the relative increase in the response rate remained at around 14 percent.

5

These results refer to the combined web and mail responses because the authors did not separate out the comparison of characteristics and survey items by survey response mode.

6

The Carter et al. (2024) study included an incentive, but the focus of the analysis was a comparison of a state-of-the-art mail-push-incentive survey strategy with a simple email-only contact strategy. The effect of the incentive could not be separated from the effect of the other components of the mail-push strategy.

7

The purpose of the FBFS was specifically to measure changes in recreational fishing effort, not to generate estimates of the absolute level of recreational fishing effort. In this way, the FBFS is distinct from and not affiliated with other angler surveys in the Gulf of Mexico such as the Fishing Effort Survey of the Marine Recreational Information Program (MRIP) and the Florida State Reef Fish Survey (FSRFS). The results of our survey are not strictly comparable to the MRIP or FSRFS results because our study used a narrower sampling frame, invited anglers via email (vs mail), had respondents complete the survey on the internet (vs paper), and asked effort-related questions in different ways.

8

This study does not include anglers fishing from for-hire or rental boats.

9

On the west coast of Florida, federal waters begin at 9 nautical miles from the shore. These estimates are based on the MRIP estimates for 2022.

10

The minimum size limit was also set in 2016 to 24 inches. The minimum size limit was set to 20 inches in 1990 and 22 inches in 2000. In addition, there is a combined bag limit for a set of shallow-water grouper species, including Gag, that is currently five fish.

11

Gag Grouper is part of a bottom fish complex that includes many substitute species. We assume that the respondent considers these alternative targets when reporting the number of trips that they would take under the hypothetical Gag Grouper regulation scenarios.

12

Nearly 95 percent of records from the six selected strata in the FSRF database had an email.

13

We used the sample function in R to assign each observation in the sample a zero or one, indicating the no incentive and incentive group, respectively.

14

Factors, such as income, fishing skill, and fish stock, that do not vary by scenario cannot be identified separate from the fixed effect. In the appendix of Carter, Liese, and Lovell (2022), we use an alternative procedure to estimate the income parameter for this model with the 2021 survey data and show that it is relatively small so that there is very little difference between the results with and without income effects.

15

We cannot interact the hypothetical indicator with the bag limit variables because the bag limit is fixed at two for all anglers in the base case.

16

The fixed effect Poisson estimator has been frequently used in contingent behavior studies (e.g. Englin and Cameron 1996; Whitehead et al. 2011) because it is fully robust even if trips do not follow a Poisson distribution or trips reported by the same angler are correlated (Wooldridge 2010). An alternative assumption would be a random-effects specification whereby αiis unobserved, but assumed to be uncorrelated with trip costs and the bag limit (e.g. Rosenberger and Loomis 1999; Whitehead, Haab, and Huang 2000; Alberini, Zanatta, and Rosato 2007).

17

The value per trip, including the effects of the hypothetical scenarios, would include the parameter on the interaction of the hypothetical indicator and trip cost, i.e. CS = 1/(γ +ϕ). We focus on the CS estimate without the effects of the hypothetical scenarios.

18

We also conduct Brunner–Munzell (BM) permutation tests in the Appendix to compare the distributions of the key variables. The BM tests are robust and powerful for small sample sizes, under a variety of assumptions.

19

Note that we collect the bag limit semi-elasticity and MWTP estimates for the different bag limit starting values into boldfaced vectors denoted ϵ = (ϵ0, ϵ1, ϵ2) and MWTP = (MWTP0, MWTP1, MWTP2).

20

The BM test results shown in the Appendix confirm the results in 4.

21

Multiplying the (un-rounded) Gag Grouper angler share times the observations in each group gives 211 respondents who said that they fished for Gag Grouper.

22

The Gag Grouper samples are relatively small. Therefore, we confirm the results of the t-tests in the Appendix with a more robust test of independent samples.

23

There are two trip cost parameters in each model: one on the trip cost and another on the interaction of trip cost with the hypothetical scenario indicator. Note that we divided the typical cost by the typical number of people to get cost on a per person basis. This does not scale the regression results because any factor that does not vary by scenario (e.g. typical cost and people per trip) is not separately identified in the fixed-effects estimator. The trip cost parameter alone, γ, indicates the general response to changes in trip costs. Adding the parameter on the interaction variable gives the response to trip costs including the effects inherent in the hypothetical scenarios. The parameter on the hypothetical scenario indicator, λ, is not significantly different from zero at the .05 significance level, but the hypothetical, trip cost interaction parameter, ϕ, is significant in the no incentive and all models.

24

We did receive a few “protest” email replies from people hostile to Starbucks.

Appendix A. Sample frame counties

Table A1.

Counties in the survey sample frame.

AlachuaHamiltonMarion
BayHardeeMonroe
BradfordHendryOkaloosa
CalhounHernandoPasco
CharlotteHighlandsPinellas
CitrusHillsboroughPolk
CollierJacksonSanta rosa
ColumbiaJeffersonSarasota
DesotoLafayetteSumter
DixieLakeSuwannee
EscambiaLeeTaylor
FranklinLeonUnion
GadsdenLevyWakulla
GilchristMadisonWalton
GulfManateeWashington
AlachuaHamiltonMarion
BayHardeeMonroe
BradfordHendryOkaloosa
CalhounHernandoPasco
CharlotteHighlandsPinellas
CitrusHillsboroughPolk
CollierJacksonSanta rosa
ColumbiaJeffersonSarasota
DesotoLafayetteSumter
DixieLakeSuwannee
EscambiaLeeTaylor
FranklinLeonUnion
GadsdenLevyWakulla
GilchristMadisonWalton
GulfManateeWashington
Table A1.

Counties in the survey sample frame.

AlachuaHamiltonMarion
BayHardeeMonroe
BradfordHendryOkaloosa
CalhounHernandoPasco
CharlotteHighlandsPinellas
CitrusHillsboroughPolk
CollierJacksonSanta rosa
ColumbiaJeffersonSarasota
DesotoLafayetteSumter
DixieLakeSuwannee
EscambiaLeeTaylor
FranklinLeonUnion
GadsdenLevyWakulla
GilchristMadisonWalton
GulfManateeWashington
AlachuaHamiltonMarion
BayHardeeMonroe
BradfordHendryOkaloosa
CalhounHernandoPasco
CharlotteHighlandsPinellas
CitrusHillsboroughPolk
CollierJacksonSanta rosa
ColumbiaJeffersonSarasota
DesotoLafayetteSumter
DixieLakeSuwannee
EscambiaLeeTaylor
FranklinLeonUnion
GadsdenLevyWakulla
GilchristMadisonWalton
GulfManateeWashington

Appendix B. Brunner–Munzell permutation tests

Results from the permutation version of the Brunner–Munzel (BM) test are reported in Table B1 as another way to compare the distributions of the key variables between the incentive and no incentive treatments for the respondents who fished for Gag Grouper. According to Noguchi et al. (2021), the permutation version of the BM test is robust and powerful for small sample sizes, under a variety of assumptions. In our case, the BM test evaluates the null hypothesis that the probability of observing a given variable level is the same regardless of the survey mode. Specifically, the null hypothesis is based on the relative effect: π = P(X < Y)+ |${\textstyle{1 \over 2}}P( {X = Y} )$|⁠, where X and Y represent observations from two independent groups. If π = 0.5, then the two groups are considered stochastically comparable, which is the null hypothesis of the BM test. Rejecting the null with π > 0.5, for example, suggests that a randomly drawn individual from the Y group will have a higher value for the variable of interest than a randomly drawn individual from the X group. We use the BM test to compare the following variables among the email-only, mail-push-incentive, and non-response groups: respondent age, respondent income, and the number of days fished (trips), trips with costs doubled and halved, and trips with a three-, one-, and zero-fish bag limit (relative to a two-fish bag limit). All BM tests are conducted with the rank.two.samples function in the rankFD R package (Konietschke et al. 2022). We use 10,000 permutations to calculate the relative effect along with its standard error and 0.95 confidence interval. Range-preserving confidence intervals are obtained using the logit transformation. The studentized permutation test is used to test the equality of the two distribution functions of the two groups with a two-sided alternative.

Table B1.

BM test results for Gag fisher characteristics: no incentive vs incentive.

VariableEstimatorSEtLowerUpperP value
Age0.440.04−1.60.360.51.11
Income0.490.04−0.130.420.57.88
Trips0.540.041.090.470.62.27
Trip cost0.450.04−1.140.380.53.26
People0.430.04−1.810.360.51.07
Hours0.420.04−2.170.340.49.03
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost 0.57 0.041.720.490.64.09
 Trips, half cost 0.53 0.040.820.450.61.4
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags0.550.041.270.470.62.19
 Trips, one bag0.520.040.540.440.60.59
 Trips, zero bag0.560.041.410.480.63.17
VariableEstimatorSEtLowerUpperP value
Age0.440.04−1.60.360.51.11
Income0.490.04−0.130.420.57.88
Trips0.540.041.090.470.62.27
Trip cost0.450.04−1.140.380.53.26
People0.430.04−1.810.360.51.07
Hours0.420.04−2.170.340.49.03
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost 0.57 0.041.720.490.64.09
 Trips, half cost 0.53 0.040.820.450.61.4
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags0.550.041.270.470.62.19
 Trips, one bag0.520.040.540.440.60.59
 Trips, zero bag0.560.041.410.480.63.17

The relative effect is shown in the estimator column. A relative effect greater than 0.5 suggests that the variable value for a randomly selected observation from the incentive group is likely to be greater than the variable value for a randomly selected observation from the no incentive group. The opposite relationship is suggested for relative effects less than 0.5.

Table B1.

BM test results for Gag fisher characteristics: no incentive vs incentive.

VariableEstimatorSEtLowerUpperP value
Age0.440.04−1.60.360.51.11
Income0.490.04−0.130.420.57.88
Trips0.540.041.090.470.62.27
Trip cost0.450.04−1.140.380.53.26
People0.430.04−1.810.360.51.07
Hours0.420.04−2.170.340.49.03
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost 0.57 0.041.720.490.64.09
 Trips, half cost 0.53 0.040.820.450.61.4
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags0.550.041.270.470.62.19
 Trips, one bag0.520.040.540.440.60.59
 Trips, zero bag0.560.041.410.480.63.17
VariableEstimatorSEtLowerUpperP value
Age0.440.04−1.60.360.51.11
Income0.490.04−0.130.420.57.88
Trips0.540.041.090.470.62.27
Trip cost0.450.04−1.140.380.53.26
People0.430.04−1.810.360.51.07
Hours0.420.04−2.170.340.49.03
Contingent behavior, costs (base actual cost)
 Trips, double cost 0.57 0.041.720.490.64.09
 Trips, half cost 0.53 0.040.820.450.61.4
Contingent behavior, bag limits (base two-fish bag)
 Trips, three bags0.550.041.270.470.62.19
 Trips, one bag0.520.040.540.440.60.59
 Trips, zero bag0.560.041.410.480.63.17

The relative effect is shown in the estimator column. A relative effect greater than 0.5 suggests that the variable value for a randomly selected observation from the incentive group is likely to be greater than the variable value for a randomly selected observation from the no incentive group. The opposite relationship is suggested for relative effects less than 0.5.

References

Abdelazeem
B.
et al. (
2023
) ‘
Does Usage of Monetary Incentive Impact the Involvement in Surveys? A Systematic Review and Meta-analysis of 46 Randomized Controlled Trials
’,
PLoS ONE
,
18
:
e0279128
.

Aizaki
H.
(
2015
)
mded: Measuring the Difference between Two Empirical Distributions
.
R package version 0.1-2.

Alberini
A.
,
Zanatta
V.
,
Rosato
P.
(
2007
) ‘
Combining Actual and Contingent Behavior to Estimate the Value of Sports Fishing in the Lagoon of Venice
’,
Ecological Economics
,
61
:
530
41
.

Anderson
L.
et al. (
2022
) ‘
Effects of Survey Response Mode, Purported Topic, and Incentives on Response Rates in human Dimensions of Fisheries and Wildlife Research
’,
Human Dimensions of Wildlife
,
27
:
201
19
.

Andrews
R.
,
Brick
J. M.
,
Mathiowetz
W. N. A.
(
2014
) ‘
Development and Testing of Recreational Fishing Effort Surveys
’.
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, National Marine Fisheries Service, Silver Spring
.

Bergé
L.
(
2018
) ‘
Efficient Estimation of Maximum Likelihood Models with Multiple Fixed-effects: The R Package FENmlm
’,
CREA Discussion Papers
.
Luxembourg
:
Department of Economics at the University of Luxembourg
.

Brown
J. A.
et al. (
2016
) ‘
Effect of a Post-paid Incentive on Response Rates to a Web-Based Survey
’,
Survey Practice
,
9
:
1
7
.

Cameron
A. C.
,
Miller
D. L.
(
2015
) ‘
A Practitioner's Guide to Cluster-Robust Inference
’,
Journal of Human Resources
,
50
:
317
72
.

Carter
D. W.
,
Liese
C.
,
Lovell
S. J.
(
2022
) ‘
The Option Price of Recreational Bag Limits and the Value of Harvest
’,
Marine Resource Economics
,
37
:
35
52
.

Carter
D. W.
et al. (
2022
) ‘
The Effect of Changes in Trip Costs and Gag Regulations on Recreational Fishing Demand in the Gulf of Mexico
’,
North American Journal of Fisheries Management
,
42
:
1465
76
.

Carter
D. W.
et al. (
2024
) ‘
A Comparison of Recreational Fishing Demand Estimates from a Mail-Push versus Email-Only Sampling Strategy: Evidence from a Survey of Gulf of Mexico Anglers
’,
North American Journal of Fisheries Management
.

Champely
S.
(
2020
)
pwr: Basic Functions for Power Analysis
.
R package version 1.3-0.

Cheng
G.
,
Yu
Z.
,
Huang
J. Z.
(
2013
) ‘
The Cluster Bootstrap Consistency in Generalized Estimating Equations
’,
Journal of Multivariate Analysis
,
115
:
33
47
.

Cook
C.
,
Heath
F.
,
Thompson
R. L.
(
2000
) ‘
A Meta-analysis of Response Rates in Web- or Internet-Based Surveys
’,
Educational and Psychological Measurement
,
60
:
821
36
.

DeCamp
W.
,
Manierre
M. J.
(
2016
) ‘
Money Will Solve the Problem”: Testing the Effectiveness of Conditional Incentives for Online Surveys
’,
Survey Practice
,
9
:
1
9
.

Edwards
P. J.
et al. (
2023
) ‘
Methods to Increase Response to Postal and Electronic Questionnaires
’,
Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews
,
11
:
MR000008
.

Englin
J.
,
Cameron
T. A.
(
1996
) ‘
Augmenting Travel Cost Models with Contingent Behavior Data
’,
Environmental and Resource Economics
,
7
:
133
47
.

Haab
T. C.
,
McConnell
K. E.
(
2002
)
Valuing Environmental and Natural Resources: The Econometrics of Non-market Valuation
. Northampton, Massachusetts:
Edward Elgar Publishing
.

Haab
T. C.
,
Sun
B.
,
Whitehead
J. C.
(
2012
) ‘
Combining Revealed and Stated Preferences to Identify Hypothetical Bias in Repeated Question Surveys: A Feedback Model of Seafood demand
’, in T. C. Haab, J. C. Whitehead and J.-C. Huang (eds)
Preference Data for Environmental Valuation
, pp.
174
85
. New York:
Routledge
.

Hathaway
C. A.
et al. (
2021
) ‘
Improving Electronic Survey Response Rates among Cancer Center Patients during the COVID-19 Pandemic: Mixed Methods Pilot Study
’,
JMIR Cancer
,
7
:
e30265
.

Konietschke
F.
et al. (
2022
)
rankFD: Rank-Based Tests for General Factorial Designs
.
R package version 0.1.1.

Mercer
A.
et al. (
2015
) ‘
How Much Gets You How Much? Monetary Incentives and Response Rates in Household Surveys
’,
Public Opinion Quarterly
,
79
:
105
29
.

National Marine Fisheries Service
(
2007
)
Guidelines for Economic Review of National Marine Fisheries Service Regulatory Actions
.
Silver Spring
:
National Marine Fisheries Service
.

National Marine Fisheries Service Office of Science and Technology
(
2023
)
Marine Recreational Information Program: Survey Design and Statistical Methods for Estimation of Recreational Fisheries Catch and Effort
.
Silver Spring
: National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration.

Noguchi
K.
et al. (
2021
) ‘
Permutation Tests Are Robust and Powerful at 0.5
’,
Behavior Research Methods
,
53
:
2712
24
.

Pastore
M.
(
2018
) ‘
Overlapping: A R Package for Estimating Overlapping in Empirical Distributions
’,
Journal of Open Source Software
,
3
:
1023
.

Poe
G. L.
,
Giraud
K. L.
,
Loomis
J. B.
(
2005
) ‘
Computational Methods for Measuring the Difference of Empirical Distributions
’,
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
,
87
:
353
65
.

Rosenberger
R. S.
,
Loomis
J. B.
(
1999
) ‘
The Value of Ranch Open Space to Tourists: Combining Observed and Contingent Behavior Data
’,
Growth and Change
,
30
:
366
83
.

Simoes
P.
,
Barata
E.
,
Cruz
L.
(
2013
) ‘
Joint Estimation Using Revealed and Stated Preference Data: An Application Using a National Forest
’,
Journal of Forest Economics
,
19
:
249
66
.

Wallen
K. E.
et al. (
2016
) ‘
Mode Effect and Response Rate Issues in Mixed-mode Survey Research: Implications for Recreational Fisheries Management
’,
North American Journal of Fisheries Management
,
36
:
852
63
.

Whitehead
J. C.
,
Haab
T. C.
,
Huang
J.
(
2000
) ‘
Measuring Recreation Benefits of Quality Improvements with Revealed and Stated Behavior Data
’,
Resource and Energy Economics
,
22
:
339
54
.

Whitehead
J. C.
et al. (
2011
) ‘
Valuing Bag Limits in the North Carolina Charter Boat Fishery with Combined Revealed and Stated Preference Data
’,
Marine Resource Economics
,
26
:
233
41
.

Wooldridge
J.M.
(
2010
)
Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data
. Cambridge, Massachusetts:
MIT Press
.

Wu
M.-J.
,
Zhao
K.
,
Fils-Aime
F.
(
2022
) ‘
Response Rates of Online Surveys in Published Research: a Meta-analysis
’,
Computers in Human Behavior Reports
,
7
:
100206
.

This work is written by (a) US Government employee(s) and is in the public domain in the US.