Abstract

This article empirically investigates the impact of trade barriers on the world wine trade focusing on trade costs impeding exports, including transport, tariffs, technical barriers and sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) standards. A gravity model is estimated using data from the main importing and exporting countries for the years 1997–2010. The Poison pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator accounts for heteroskedasticity and the presence of zero trade flows. Our results identify which regulations can adversely affect trade providing useful information to policy-makers involved in negotiations on trade frictions. While SPS measures do not seem to obstruct exports, technical barriers have a varying impact on trade. A decreasing trend for tariffs has largely been compensated by more stringent technical barriers. The overall result is that frictions in the world wine trade have not changed during the past 15 years.

1. Introduction

A decade has passed since Kym Anderson studied the effects of globalisation on the world wine market: ‘Globalisation is not new to the world's wine markets, but its influence over the past decade or so has increased significantly’ (Anderson and Golin, 2004: 14). Indeed, the wine sector is increasingly becoming an export-oriented industry. Nowadays, almost half of world production is concentrated in three countries (France, Italy and Spain), which account for less than a third of global consumption, while the declining consumption in their domestic markets is pushing the industry to export to distant markets. The rapid and dynamic growth of the world wine trade and the rise of new exporters and importers have largely contributed to rendering wine one of the most globally consumed drinks (Anderson and Nelgen, 2011).

In recent decades, growth in the world wine trade has been driven by a number of complementary factors,1 including technological improvements and policy interventions. The former have reduced transport costs, bringing distant countries ever closer, while the latter have aimed to reduce price mark-ups on imported goods. At the same time, new regulations have impacted trade flows. In general terms, sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures and technical barriers to trade (TBTs) have been introduced to overcome technical regulations and correct market failures for facilitating trade and to guarantee high safety and technical standards (Mahé, 1997). However, a vast majority of scholars have argued that non-tariff barriers have simply been put in place to protect domestic industries from import competition (Yue and Beghin, 2009), raising international political concern (Disdier, Fontagné and Mimouni, 2008). Wine is seldom perceived by consumers as an essential good, and it is regulated by governments accordingly, as a source of additional revenue. Although the objective of reducing negative externalities from consuming alcohol is undoubtedly noble, the real, less noble, motivation for taxing wine consumption is simply revenue seeking (Fogarty, 2010). As a result, the rate of taxation on wine is high (Freebairn, 2010). Indeed, as repeatedly argued (Foster and Spencer, 2002: 14–19), the world wine market has been overregulated, and the effective level of protectionism has probably not changed at all. Addressing this specific question is an open empirical issue which is particularly relevant to policy-makers and entrepreneurs: identification of the protectionist nature of specific TBTs set by governments may in fact facilitate changes in existing TBTs in some countries or foster the implementation of harmonised standards internationally in order to improve wine trading and marketing.

An extensive literature on the effects of trade regulations analysed the role of tariffs and non-tariff barriers and their impact in economic terms, reporting contrasting results on the role of non-tariff barriers (TBTs and SPS standards). Leamer (1990) showed how trade barriers greatly reduce trade. Heien and Sims (2000) found that the removal of tariffs and non-tariff barriers due to the establishment of the Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement (FTA) increased trade flows from Canada to the USA by 10 per cent for tariffs, and by 17 per cent for non-tariff barriers. Similarly, Otsuki, Wilson, and Sewadeh (2001) demonstrated that the European standards on aflatoxins are the main barrier to imports of African groundnuts. Similar results have been reported by Henson and Loader (2001) and Peterson and Orden (2005, 2008). Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini (2010) analysed trade frictions in world demand for US corn seeds and concluded that ‘tariffs matter most, followed by distance and SPS measures' while Henry de Fraham and Vancauteren (2006) stated that the removal of TBTs and the harmonisation of regulations in the food industry have greatly increased intra-EU trade. Finally, Henson, Brouder and Mitullah (2000) stressed that also measures such as food safety requirements can equally act as barriers to trade.

In contrast, several scholars have reconsidered the negative effects of non-tariff barriers on trade flows. Harrigan (1993) showed that trade between organisation for economic co-operation and development members is limited by tariffs and transport costs rather than by non-tariff barriers. Similarly, Fontagné, Mimouni and Pasteels (2005) stated that SPS and TBTs in fresh and processed foods are not very restrictive, Cioffi, Santeramo and Vitale (2011) and Santeramo and Cioffi (2012) found that a price ceiling is not as effective as tariffs for imported products in the EU and Henson and Jaffee (2008) examined the concept of ‘standards as catalysts' in the context of food safety standards in international trade, highlighting the need for careful analysis when considering the trade effects of TBTs.2

What is becoming clear in the extensive debate animating the literature is that the effects of non-tariff measures on trade are likely to be sector- and country-specific depending on several aspects. For instance, Disdier, Fontagné and Mimouni (2008), in a study considering 30 disaggregated industries at the HS-23 aggregation level, found that TBTs and SPS had positive effects for 8 industries, insignificant effects for 12 and negative effects for 10 industries. Similarly, Swinnen and Vandemoortele (2011) investigated the role of food standards on trade and showed that standards may be ‘barriers’ to trade but also ‘catalysts’ to trade. These results are also confirmed by Chevassus-Lozza et al. (2008).

All told, the net effects of TBTs and SPS standards are still unclear and merit further research. Indeed, what makes the picture even harder to fathom is the empirical difficulty in measuring and comparing the actual impact of tariffs and non-tariff barriers on trade. Yue, Beghin and Jensen (2006) propose two alternative methods, the price-wedge approach and the gravity-equation approach in order to assess the tariff equivalency of TBTs. By applying the latter approach, this study seeks to tackle the above challenge. In particular, we assess the equivalence of technical barriers and SPS measures with respect to tariffs by means of an econometric analysis. The novelty of this article arises from the detail with which the trade regulations are dissected and assessed for analysing their impact on global trade flows of wine. This type of analysis is especially useful for identifying what regulations (most) efficiently achieve protectionist goals. The study is conducted on the main exporters and importers in the world wine trade, analysing data on bilateral trade flows from 1997 to 2010.

The global nature of the wine sector, the complex set of existing tariff and non-tariff barriers and the increasing trade volumes are the key motivations for justifying a specific study of trade barriers in the world wine trade, representing an ideal framework to compare tariffs and non-tariff measures. These are the elements we focus on. The remainder of the article is organised as follows: the next section details the current situation of country-specific tariffs and non-tariff regulations; the third and fourth sections describe the methodology; and the fifth section describes the empirical results. We conclude by summing up the results and discussing empirical and policy implications.

2. Trade frictions in the wine market

In recent decades the global wine trade has experienced major changes. First, since the 1980s the traditional producers (France, Italy and Spain) have witnessed a conspicuous fall in domestic consumption that has driven exports. Second, the countries in the NewWorld have increased their production potential to satisfy the new demand in foreign markets (Cembalo, Caracciolo and Pomarici, 2014). These changes have been accompanied by a geographical redistribution of wine consumption (Aizenman and Brooks, 2008), especially an increase in wine consumption in North America and Asia.

During the last 15 years, the New World countries have quadrupled their exported quantities, now accounting for 33 per cent of the world's 11 major wine producers exports.4 Despite the relative increase in market shares, in absolute terms the export gap that separates the main European producers from countries in the New World has increased from 68 to 107 million hectolitres. Overall the volumes of wine exported have doubled in the last 15 years, topping ten million litres in 2012. Nowadays almost half of the global wine is consumed outside the country of production (Figure 1). However, this rarely comes without an extra cost. The sections below provide a cursory review of these regulations.

Trend in world wine exports (000s hl), consumption (000s hl) and exports/consumption (per cent).
Fig. 1.

Trend in world wine exports (000s hl), consumption (000s hl) and exports/consumption (per cent).

Sources: OIV, Global Trade Atlas.

2.1. Tariffs

In this study, tariff barriers for bottled wines were calculated by taking into account most favoured nation (MFN) tariffs, chosen as reference for national tariff levels, then corrected according to FTAs, if any. If the importer applied specific tariffs, these were converted into ad valorem equivalent (AVE), utilising the average import price as reference. AVE calculations were performed to aggregate the different HS codes5 in the same country and to compare tariffs across different countries.6 For importers implementing several duty lines, the median of the duties is considered here. This approach allows a central value to be obtained at the level of HS codes with eight digits and over, minimising the influence of tariff peaks (Anderson and Neary, 2003; Bouët et al., 2008; Cipollina and Salvatici, 2008).

Table 1 presents a rough picture of trade openness of the principal actors for the global trade in bottled wine in 1999 and 2010.7 The second and third columns show the ranking of importers and exporters of bottled wine (in value). The fourth column reports the MFN tariffs of selected countries. The fifth column shows the number of FTAs signed by country. The sixth column (referred to as the ‘effective barrier’) describes the real duty considering the reduction in the MFN tariff due to FTAs.8

Table 1.

Structure of world wine trade concessions to main partner countries (1999–2010)

Importer rankExporter rankMFN tariff (%)FTAEffective barriera (%)
1999
 European Unionb114.5704.57
 United Statesb241.5911.59
 Canadab4110.9030.89
 Japanb31723.37023.37
 China221365.00065.00
 Australia1425.0005.00
 Argentina19623.00023.00
 Chile25310.00110.00
2010
 European Unionb115.1115.04
 United Statesb241.4421.29
 Canadab3140.3630.34
 Japanb52022.09120.77
 China71314.00113.60
 Australia1025.002c4.77
 Argentina47620.00115.55
 Chile5036.0070.64
Importer rankExporter rankMFN tariff (%)FTAEffective barriera (%)
1999
 European Unionb114.5704.57
 United Statesb241.5911.59
 Canadab4110.9030.89
 Japanb31723.37023.37
 China221365.00065.00
 Australia1425.0005.00
 Argentina19623.00023.00
 Chile25310.00110.00
2010
 European Unionb115.1115.04
 United Statesb241.4421.29
 Canadab3140.3630.34
 Japanb52022.09120.77
 China71314.00113.60
 Australia1025.002c4.77
 Argentina47620.00115.55
 Chile5036.0070.64

Sources: World Trade Organization, WITS, GTA, CBSA, Trade Statistics of Japan, EU TARIC, Easy Comext, USITC.

Note: It is worth pointing out that the exporter ranked fifth in 1999 was South Africa, followed by Argentina and New Zealand. In 2010 New Zealand was fifth, followed by Argentina and South Africa. We considered Argentina because it was consistently ranked sixth. Moreover, Argentine production is rapidly growing and is increasingly export-oriented, further reasons that make it an interesting case study.

aEffective protection, including FTA, for the main partner countries.

bMFN tariffs include AVE tariffs.

cExcluding the FTA with USA, because it did not entail any reduction in MFN tariff.

Table 1.

Structure of world wine trade concessions to main partner countries (1999–2010)

Importer rankExporter rankMFN tariff (%)FTAEffective barriera (%)
1999
 European Unionb114.5704.57
 United Statesb241.5911.59
 Canadab4110.9030.89
 Japanb31723.37023.37
 China221365.00065.00
 Australia1425.0005.00
 Argentina19623.00023.00
 Chile25310.00110.00
2010
 European Unionb115.1115.04
 United Statesb241.4421.29
 Canadab3140.3630.34
 Japanb52022.09120.77
 China71314.00113.60
 Australia1025.002c4.77
 Argentina47620.00115.55
 Chile5036.0070.64
Importer rankExporter rankMFN tariff (%)FTAEffective barriera (%)
1999
 European Unionb114.5704.57
 United Statesb241.5911.59
 Canadab4110.9030.89
 Japanb31723.37023.37
 China221365.00065.00
 Australia1425.0005.00
 Argentina19623.00023.00
 Chile25310.00110.00
2010
 European Unionb115.1115.04
 United Statesb241.4421.29
 Canadab3140.3630.34
 Japanb52022.09120.77
 China71314.00113.60
 Australia1025.002c4.77
 Argentina47620.00115.55
 Chile5036.0070.64

Sources: World Trade Organization, WITS, GTA, CBSA, Trade Statistics of Japan, EU TARIC, Easy Comext, USITC.

Note: It is worth pointing out that the exporter ranked fifth in 1999 was South Africa, followed by Argentina and New Zealand. In 2010 New Zealand was fifth, followed by Argentina and South Africa. We considered Argentina because it was consistently ranked sixth. Moreover, Argentine production is rapidly growing and is increasingly export-oriented, further reasons that make it an interesting case study.

aEffective protection, including FTA, for the main partner countries.

bMFN tariffs include AVE tariffs.

cExcluding the FTA with USA, because it did not entail any reduction in MFN tariff.

As regards the MFN tariffs, a clear differentiation may be noted on the basis of geographical area: the countries of North America have the lowest protection of the domestic market through tariffs, while Latin American and Asian countries set very high import duties. Thanks to the world trade organization (WTO) policies aimed at encouraging free trade, the countries in question have reduced MFN tariffs applied to imported bottled wine. Nevertheless, in the particular case of the European Union, the calculated AVE indicates the contrary; this apparent contradiction is due to the fact that the EU applies specific tariffs, such that their reduction has been followed by a more than proportional reduction in the unit value of imported wine.9 Consequently, the percentage of the duty calculated on the basis of the unit value of the imported product has increased.

For the selected countries the (export-weighted) average decrease in the MFN tariff from 1999 to 2010 was 22.7 per cent, driven by China and Canada which experienced a more than fourfold decrease, and by Chile that reduced its MFN tariff by 40 per cent. China applied the main reduction of the tariff in both absolute and relative terms. This reduction was undoubtedly after its accession to the WTO in 2001 falling from 65 per cent to 14 per cent in only 3 years. In contrast, Canada and Chile reduced their tariffs in order to open up to the international market: indeed, Chile and Canada have stipulated a large number of FTAs. Further considerations can be made by analysing the effective protection (last column of Table 1). While in 1999 there was almost no difference between MFN tariffs and the ‘effective barrier’, in 2010 all the nations considered10 show differences between the MFN tariff and the tariff then actually applied. An emblematic case is Chile: it has stipulated numerous FTAs such that in 2010 the average tariff applied on imported wines was 90 per cent lower than the MFN tariff.

As shown in Table 2, bilateral tariffs and MFN tariffs have been largely revised during the last 15 years. Moreover, while some countries have established high MFN tariffs (above 14 per cent), others have adopted lower tariffs (below 6 per cent). The former group of countries (namely Japan, Argentina and China) have established only one FTA in favour of Chile, while, more generally, countries with low MFN tariffs tend to set a higher number of FTAs. All these give sufficient reasons for analysing these dynamics in order to quantify to what extent tariffs may slacken trade flows.

Table 2.

Structure of world wine trade tariffs to the main preferential countries (1997–2010)

19971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010
EU
 ChileNANAMFN5.42.31.10.00.00.00.0
 MFNNANA4.64.43.94.25.05.05.05.04.95.15.55.1
CAN
 Australia0.80.80.70.70.60.60.60.50.50.50.50.50.40.3
 Chile0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 USA0.00.00.00.00.00,00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN1.00.90.90.80.80.80.80.70.70.70.70.70.50.4
JAP
 ChileMFN13.814.011.511.5
 MFN20.528.323.420.919.818.717.417.016.114.713.614.620.022.1
USA
 ChileMFN2.31.81.51.51.61.6
 Canada0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN2.31.91.61.71.51.51.41.41.41.31.31.21.41.5
AUS
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.0
 ChileMFN0.00.0
 MFN5.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.0
CHINA
 ChileMFN11.29.88.47.0
 MFN65.065.065.065.065.034.424.214.014.014.014.014.014.014.0
ARG
 ChileMFN15.414.40.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN20.023.023.023.022.520.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.0
CHILE
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 EUMFN5.04.03.02.01.00.00.00.0
 ChinaMFN0.00.00.00.00.0
 AustraliaMFN0.00.0
 JapanMFN5.55.14.6
 ArgentinaMFN5.04.03.02.01.0
 MFN11.011.010.09.08.07.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.0
19971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010
EU
 ChileNANAMFN5.42.31.10.00.00.00.0
 MFNNANA4.64.43.94.25.05.05.05.04.95.15.55.1
CAN
 Australia0.80.80.70.70.60.60.60.50.50.50.50.50.40.3
 Chile0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 USA0.00.00.00.00.00,00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN1.00.90.90.80.80.80.80.70.70.70.70.70.50.4
JAP
 ChileMFN13.814.011.511.5
 MFN20.528.323.420.919.818.717.417.016.114.713.614.620.022.1
USA
 ChileMFN2.31.81.51.51.61.6
 Canada0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN2.31.91.61.71.51.51.41.41.41.31.31.21.41.5
AUS
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.0
 ChileMFN0.00.0
 MFN5.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.0
CHINA
 ChileMFN11.29.88.47.0
 MFN65.065.065.065.065.034.424.214.014.014.014.014.014.014.0
ARG
 ChileMFN15.414.40.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN20.023.023.023.022.520.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.0
CHILE
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 EUMFN5.04.03.02.01.00.00.00.0
 ChinaMFN0.00.00.00.00.0
 AustraliaMFN0.00.0
 JapanMFN5.55.14.6
 ArgentinaMFN5.04.03.02.01.0
 MFN11.011.010.09.08.07.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.0

Sources: WTO, WITS, CBSA, Trade Statistics of Japan, Easy Comext, USITC, SICE.

Table 2.

Structure of world wine trade tariffs to the main preferential countries (1997–2010)

19971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010
EU
 ChileNANAMFN5.42.31.10.00.00.00.0
 MFNNANA4.64.43.94.25.05.05.05.04.95.15.55.1
CAN
 Australia0.80.80.70.70.60.60.60.50.50.50.50.50.40.3
 Chile0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 USA0.00.00.00.00.00,00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN1.00.90.90.80.80.80.80.70.70.70.70.70.50.4
JAP
 ChileMFN13.814.011.511.5
 MFN20.528.323.420.919.818.717.417.016.114.713.614.620.022.1
USA
 ChileMFN2.31.81.51.51.61.6
 Canada0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN2.31.91.61.71.51.51.41.41.41.31.31.21.41.5
AUS
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.0
 ChileMFN0.00.0
 MFN5.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.0
CHINA
 ChileMFN11.29.88.47.0
 MFN65.065.065.065.065.034.424.214.014.014.014.014.014.014.0
ARG
 ChileMFN15.414.40.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN20.023.023.023.022.520.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.0
CHILE
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 EUMFN5.04.03.02.01.00.00.00.0
 ChinaMFN0.00.00.00.00.0
 AustraliaMFN0.00.0
 JapanMFN5.55.14.6
 ArgentinaMFN5.04.03.02.01.0
 MFN11.011.010.09.08.07.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.0
19971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010
EU
 ChileNANAMFN5.42.31.10.00.00.00.0
 MFNNANA4.64.43.94.25.05.05.05.04.95.15.55.1
CAN
 Australia0.80.80.70.70.60.60.60.50.50.50.50.50.40.3
 Chile0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 USA0.00.00.00.00.00,00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN1.00.90.90.80.80.80.80.70.70.70.70.70.50.4
JAP
 ChileMFN13.814.011.511.5
 MFN20.528.323.420.919.818.717.417.016.114.713.614.620.022.1
USA
 ChileMFN2.31.81.51.51.61.6
 Canada0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN2.31.91.61.71.51.51.41.41.41.31.31.21.41.5
AUS
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.0
 ChileMFN0.00.0
 MFN5.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.05.0
CHINA
 ChileMFN11.29.88.47.0
 MFN65.065.065.065.065.034.424.214.014.014.014.014.014.014.0
ARG
 ChileMFN15.414.40.00.00.00.00.0
 MFN20.023.023.023.022.520.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.020.0
CHILE
 USAMFN0.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
 EUMFN5.04.03.02.01.00.00.00.0
 ChinaMFN0.00.00.00.00.0
 AustraliaMFN0.00.0
 JapanMFN5.55.14.6
 ArgentinaMFN5.04.03.02.01.0
 MFN11.011.010.09.08.07.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.06.0

Sources: WTO, WITS, CBSA, Trade Statistics of Japan, Easy Comext, USITC, SICE.

2.2. Non-tariff barriers

As tariffs have been lowered, demands for protectionism have led to new technical barriers. Among these, SPS standards and TBTs are of increasing importance (Moenius, 2004; Disdier, Fontagné and Mimouni, 2008). Several definitions exist in the literature for non-tariff barriers: Hillman (1991: 52) described TBTs as ‘any governmental device or practice other than a tariff which directly impedes the entry of imports into a country and which discriminates against imports, but does not apply with equal force on domestic production or distribution’. More recently, Beghin (2008) and Li and Beghin (2011) defined TBTs as the wide and heterogeneous set of intervention measures, other than custom duties, that influence and distort the commerce of goods, services and production factors. Attention is currently focused on the distinction between measures that have the primary aim of protecting national products and others that do not. Following this approach, the definition of a TBT is linked to its legitimacy: the term ‘barrier’ should not be used if the measure has a collateral effect on trade, but its primary aim is to correct some market inefficiency. However, establishing impartially whether a standard has a legitimate basis is no simple task (Fisher and Serra, 2000; Maskus, Wilson and Otsuki, 2000).

In the wine sector there has been a growing use of TBTs by governments in order to protect domestic markets (Anderson and Golin, 2004). As shown in Table 3, the level of intervention is very heterogeneous across countries. Indeed, the number of TBTs set by each country at the end of 2010 varied from 169 for Australia to 811 for the USA. Three cases worth further note. First, Argentina, one of the last countries to implement TBTs, issued a total of 24 TBTs just in few years.11 Second, the USA and the EU have set, respectively, 19 and 10 TBTs during the last few decades. After joining the WTO in 2002, China was forced to lower its import duties, balancing the loss in level of protectionism through TBTs. In particular, China has produced new notifications at regular intervals. The other countries have made less use of these instruments: Australia has produced six TBTs, Chile four, Japan three and Canada only two. Some nations stand out for the specificity with which they have regulated the wine sector: for example the EU have issued 8 out of the 10 TBTs for products belonging to code HS2204 (wine from fresh grapes); for Argentina 15 out of 24 TBTs are specific to wine and for USA 8 out of 19. The other importing countries have not shown such zeal in meticulously regulating the sector, and wine is generally included in notifications that regulate a wider range of food products or beverages.

Table 3.

Non-tariff barriers – 2010

Total documentsTBTsWine TBTs
Wine-specific TBTs
Food standardsLabellingConformity assessmentPackagingFood containersHuman health
EU715544378
USA1,262811116118
Canada69546320
Japan622488211
Chile249225220
Argentina472315814215
Australia177169241
China8957741510
Total documentsTBTsWine TBTs
Wine-specific TBTs
Food standardsLabellingConformity assessmentPackagingFood containersHuman health
EU715544378
USA1,262811116118
Canada69546320
Japan622488211
Chile249225220
Argentina472315814215
Australia177169241
China8957741510

Source: WTO documents.

Table 3.

Non-tariff barriers – 2010

Total documentsTBTsWine TBTs
Wine-specific TBTs
Food standardsLabellingConformity assessmentPackagingFood containersHuman health
EU715544378
USA1,262811116118
Canada69546320
Japan622488211
Chile249225220
Argentina472315814215
Australia177169241
China8957741510
Total documentsTBTsWine TBTs
Wine-specific TBTs
Food standardsLabellingConformity assessmentPackagingFood containersHuman health
EU715544378
USA1,262811116118
Canada69546320
Japan622488211
Chile249225220
Argentina472315814215
Australia177169241
China8957741510

Source: WTO documents.

Currently, the WTO comprises the TBTs pertinent to wine in six categories on the basis of what they regulate: food standards, labelling, conformity assessment, packaging, food containers and human health. According to this classification, labelling is the only category used at least once by all the countries concerned. Labelling regulations refer to the requirements imposed to attest the presence of substances that might cause allergic reactions,12 to protect specific names,13 to regulate the wording regarding the country or designation of origin14 and to ensure and regulate the presence of obligatory information such as brand, alcohol content and vintage.15 Some TBTs have also been inserted to discourage the consumption of alcoholic beverages, including wine, covering the impossibility of mentioning any health benefits from wine, the obligation for warnings about possible repercussions on human health and sometimes to regulate sales to young people.16 ‘Food standards’, the second most frequent category, set technical requisites of the product, regulating oenological practices in general, and the maximum contents of particular substances.17 Some TBTs that regulate sectors are generally not strict regulations in the case of wine: this particularly holds for regulations belonging to the classes packaging,18 food containers,19 conformity assessment20 and human health.21 Such TBTs are rarely adopted and are often very country-specific.

SPS measures generally concern the fresh product trade and there is almost no recourse to such measures for the wine sector. Notably, only Argentina, Australia, China, the USA and the EU have produced SPS notifications (Table 4). Argentina adopted SPS measures to set the maximum limit of lead, arsenic and zinc in wine.22 China, by means of SPS/N/CHN/P/133 of April 2002 which regulates all alcoholic beverages, has formalised the requisites, supervision and inspection procedures of alcoholic beverages at ports and on the domestic market. The USA adopted the sanitary barrier G/SPS/N/USA/196 in November 1999, which regulates the labelling of alcoholic beverages by prohibiting, on labels or in advertising, any claim regarding the health benefits deriving from the consumption of any alcoholic beverage, unless the statement is qualified, objective, sufficiently detailed and specific. Lastly, the EU issued G/SPS/N/EEC/247 in 2004 which sets the maximum limit for ochratoxin A in different foods, including wine. Our empirical analysis will explore the restrictiveness of these regulations, calculating the tariff equivalency as a measure of their impact. The methodology adopted to achieve these goals is described in the next section.

Table 4.

SPS barriers – 2010

CountryTotal SPSsWine-sector specific SPSs
Argentina1631
Australia3060
Canada8430
Chile3870
China5251
European Union6981
Japan2780
United States3,0451
CountryTotal SPSsWine-sector specific SPSs
Argentina1631
Australia3060
Canada8430
Chile3870
China5251
European Union6981
Japan2780
United States3,0451

Source: WTO.

Table 4.

SPS barriers – 2010

CountryTotal SPSsWine-sector specific SPSs
Argentina1631
Australia3060
Canada8430
Chile3870
China5251
European Union6981
Japan2780
United States3,0451
CountryTotal SPSsWine-sector specific SPSs
Argentina1631
Australia3060
Canada8430
Chile3870
China5251
European Union6981
Japan2780
United States3,0451

Source: WTO.

3. Empirical framework

In order to quantify the impact of trade barriers on the world wine trade we augmented the standard gravity equation (Tinbergen, 1962: 262–293) linking trade flows to economic masses and distances with tariffs, technical barriers and SPS regulations. Scholars have reached a consensus on the proxies for economic masses, namely the countries' Gross domestic product (GDP), and distances, proxied by physical distances (Head and Mayer, 2013). In our model, we refined the proxy for the exporter's economic mass Y by replacing GDP in country i with wine supply in country i in year t. A standard constant elasticity of substitution specification was adopted
(1)
where Y1it represents the exporter's supply (namely the production of wine for country i) at time t, Y2jt stands for importer's GDP at time t, Dij proxies geographical distance and Xijt stands for wine trade flows from country i to country j at time t. After log-linearisation the gravity model becomes
(2)
where the additive error, εij, is assumed to be identically and independently distributed, and μ* = lnμ.
In analogy with previous studies (Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini, 2010), we modelled trade resistance induced by trade regulations by augmenting the ‘geographical’ distance with the ‘economic distance’ including tariffs and non-tariff barriers
(3)
where Dij proxies the ‘economic’ distance, including physical distance and trade regulations. Dij represents the pair-wise geographical distance between i and j; tj stands for the j-specific tariff; Bmjt stands for the m-th classes of TBTs (label, food standards, conformity assessments, food containers, human health and packaging) and SPS measures of country j in year t. In other words, Bmjt represents the m-th non-tariff barrier classes as count variables. Furthermore, a constant (set to 1) is added to avoid the possibility of taking the logarithm of zero. Following Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini (2010), non-tariff barriers are treated as costs that are assumed to be proxied by their frequency. A negative and statistically significant effect ((Xij/Dij)<0) is expected for the ‘economic distance’.
Equation (2) becomes as follows
(4)
where δ1, δ2 and δ3m replace the parameter δ of Equation (1).
In order to control for home bias effects23 (Anderson and Van Wincoop, 2003), we introduced the total wine supply in country j at time t, Productionjt, as an explanatory covariate. Evidence of trade resistance due to home bias would be supported by a negative and statistically significant coefficient (γ) of the variable Production for country j. Moreover, we controlled for another covariate that has been widely adopted in analyses of trade flows: a common language dummy variable, assuming a value of one if country i and country j share the same official language. Finally, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and Feenstra (2004) suggest that the standard gravity equation is incorrectly specified as it does not include the multilateral resistance terms. One of the suggested solutions to solve this problem is to include fixed effects in order to account for the multilateral resistance terms (Baier and Bergstrand, 2007; Subramanian and Wei, 2007) which are able to eliminate problems arising from incorrect deflation of trade (Baldwin and Taglioni, 2006). Taking this into account, the resulting specification includes 13 covariates and the exporter country shifter(μi)24
(5)
From an empirical point of view, several econometric issues need to be considered for correct estimation of the gravity equation. It has become widely recognised in recent years that the presence of zero flows and heteroskedasticity in the error term affects gravity-type estimations (Silva and Tenreyro, 2006). In particular, least squares estimates tend to be biased by the presence of zero trade flows. Two naïve approaches consist in replacing zero trade flows with small numbers or dropping observations with zero flows. The former neglects the intrinsic information conveyed by zero trade flows; the latter discards an even larger proportion of information contained in the dataset. An alternative solution would be to estimate a Tobit model. There is a consensus on the need to model the presence of zero trade flows (Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini, 2010; Xiong and Beghin, 2012) to correct for bias: the larger the percentage zeros, the larger the bias is likely to be. Heckman's (1979) specification can handle sample selection induced by zero flows. In our setting the limited proportion of zero flows and the heteroskedasticity disfavour the adoption of the Heckman estimation procedure. We followed the approach proposed by Silva and Tenreyro (2006) and widely supported in recent studies (Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini, 2010; Raimondi and Olper, 2011; Xiong and Beghin, 2012, among others). It consists in assuming an additive error in specification (1) and in estimating the model by a Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator (PPML), with the following set of first-order conditions:
(6)
where Xk represents trade flows, Zk is the full vector of explanatory covariates and exp(Zkαˆ) is the expected value of Xk conditional on covariates (i.e. E[Xk|Zk]). Wooldridge (2002: 676) argues that PPML Zk is consistent if the conditional mean is correctly specified, that is if E[Xk|Zk]=exp(Zkαˆ) holds. The property applies regardless of the count data adopted.

In terms of data sources, it was deemed appropriate to include both the largest world wine producers and the main importing nations. The set of countries chosen covers more than two-thirds of the world imports and almost 90 per cent of the global trade in bottled wine for the period 1997–2010. More specifically, we considered trade among Argentina, Australia, Canada, Chile, China, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Spain, the UK and the USA. Data were collected from the Global Trade Atlas (GTA) database25 for export values, the CEPII database26 for distance, WTO, WITS27 and from national customs offices for tariffs and non-tariff barriers as described in the previous section. Supply data were collected from StatOIV Extracts. Data on tariffs were obtained from the WTO official database which reports the MFN tariffs applied by importers. See Section 4 on how we computed the AVE tariffs. For non-tariff barriers the most widely adopted trade regulations are considered (Maskus, Wilson and Otsuki, 2000). Information to model count variables on the six classes of TBTs and on SPS standards was extracted from the ‘Technical Barriers to Trade Information Management System’ database and the ‘SPS Information Management System’ database, respectively.28

To obtain the maximum level of detail, all the documents issued from 1995 (i.e. from the creation of the WTO) to the end of 2010 were examined in order to identify those regarding wine and that are likely to originate extra costs. Table 5 shows the definition and the descriptive statistics of data on which the estimates are based.

Table 5.

Definition of variables and descriptive statistics

Variable nameVariable descriptionMeanStd. dev.
ExportijtThe quantity wine traded from country i to country j in year t, expressed in millions of dollars59.02153.5
Y1it and ProductionjtThe total supply (in millions of hectolitres) of wine in country i (or j) in year t18.3417.6
Y2jtThe GDP (in billions of dollars) of country j in year t2.483.1
DijThe distance between country i and country j in thousands of kilometres8.885.0
LanguageijThe common language dummy variable for country i and country j0.150.4
tjtWine-specific tariff protection (in percentage terms) of country j in year t8.5312.7
B1jtNumber of restrictive regulations on labelling for country j in year t2.513.1
B2jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food standards for country j in year t1.172.1
B3jtNumber of restrictive regulations on conformity assessments for country j in year t0.170.6
B4jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food containers for country j in year t0.010.1
B5jtNumber of restrictive regulations on human health for country j in year t0.050.2
B6jtNumber of restrictive regulations on packaging for country j in year t0.070.2
B7jtNumber of restrictive SPS measures for country j in year t0.330.5
Variable nameVariable descriptionMeanStd. dev.
ExportijtThe quantity wine traded from country i to country j in year t, expressed in millions of dollars59.02153.5
Y1it and ProductionjtThe total supply (in millions of hectolitres) of wine in country i (or j) in year t18.3417.6
Y2jtThe GDP (in billions of dollars) of country j in year t2.483.1
DijThe distance between country i and country j in thousands of kilometres8.885.0
LanguageijThe common language dummy variable for country i and country j0.150.4
tjtWine-specific tariff protection (in percentage terms) of country j in year t8.5312.7
B1jtNumber of restrictive regulations on labelling for country j in year t2.513.1
B2jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food standards for country j in year t1.172.1
B3jtNumber of restrictive regulations on conformity assessments for country j in year t0.170.6
B4jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food containers for country j in year t0.010.1
B5jtNumber of restrictive regulations on human health for country j in year t0.050.2
B6jtNumber of restrictive regulations on packaging for country j in year t0.070.2
B7jtNumber of restrictive SPS measures for country j in year t0.330.5

The statistics are computed from a pooled sample of 12 countries and 14 years.

Table 5.

Definition of variables and descriptive statistics

Variable nameVariable descriptionMeanStd. dev.
ExportijtThe quantity wine traded from country i to country j in year t, expressed in millions of dollars59.02153.5
Y1it and ProductionjtThe total supply (in millions of hectolitres) of wine in country i (or j) in year t18.3417.6
Y2jtThe GDP (in billions of dollars) of country j in year t2.483.1
DijThe distance between country i and country j in thousands of kilometres8.885.0
LanguageijThe common language dummy variable for country i and country j0.150.4
tjtWine-specific tariff protection (in percentage terms) of country j in year t8.5312.7
B1jtNumber of restrictive regulations on labelling for country j in year t2.513.1
B2jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food standards for country j in year t1.172.1
B3jtNumber of restrictive regulations on conformity assessments for country j in year t0.170.6
B4jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food containers for country j in year t0.010.1
B5jtNumber of restrictive regulations on human health for country j in year t0.050.2
B6jtNumber of restrictive regulations on packaging for country j in year t0.070.2
B7jtNumber of restrictive SPS measures for country j in year t0.330.5
Variable nameVariable descriptionMeanStd. dev.
ExportijtThe quantity wine traded from country i to country j in year t, expressed in millions of dollars59.02153.5
Y1it and ProductionjtThe total supply (in millions of hectolitres) of wine in country i (or j) in year t18.3417.6
Y2jtThe GDP (in billions of dollars) of country j in year t2.483.1
DijThe distance between country i and country j in thousands of kilometres8.885.0
LanguageijThe common language dummy variable for country i and country j0.150.4
tjtWine-specific tariff protection (in percentage terms) of country j in year t8.5312.7
B1jtNumber of restrictive regulations on labelling for country j in year t2.513.1
B2jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food standards for country j in year t1.172.1
B3jtNumber of restrictive regulations on conformity assessments for country j in year t0.170.6
B4jtNumber of restrictive regulations on food containers for country j in year t0.010.1
B5jtNumber of restrictive regulations on human health for country j in year t0.050.2
B6jtNumber of restrictive regulations on packaging for country j in year t0.070.2
B7jtNumber of restrictive SPS measures for country j in year t0.330.5

The statistics are computed from a pooled sample of 12 countries and 14 years.

4. Methodology for calculating tariff barriers

For the analysis of tariff barriers related to the exporting of products subject to code HS 220421, reference was made to the official WTO database, considering the MFN29 tariff of the various importing countries for the period 1995–2010. The accuracy of the data was supported by a crosscheck with the duties reported in the WITS database, and with those of the respective national customs authorities, where possible. This procedure compensated for the initial lack of data on Chinese tariffs for 1998, 1999, 2000, 2009 and 2010 and made a clearer distinction on the basis of the six-digit HS code for the European Union. No data interpolation was therefore necessary nor the use of ‘extreme’ values to complete the dataset.

The MFN tariff was taken as the base value indicative of the duty imposed by each importing country on all the other WTO members, but the various preferential agreements (FTAs) already in force were also considered, as well as those instituted during the period considered. When there was a tariff deriving from an FTA for a given year and towards a given exporting country, this was substituted for the MFN. For the calculation of the tariffs deriving from preferential agreements reliance was initially placed on the WITS and WTO databases. Yet, following a more thorough revision, it emerged that they were partially inaccurate due to the lack of various preferential agreements, errors in the duties indicated and sometimes in the year they came into force. For this reason, the Sistema de Información Sobre Comercio Exterior (SICE) portal30 was used for the analysis of all the official documents of the FTAs signed between the various countries, thus improving the information inserted in the dataset.

The tariffs were inserted in the dataset as AVE data, representative of the average import duty imposed on products subject to the code HS 220421. This operation overcame two methodological problems: on the one hand, the tariff profiles had to be aggregated where the code HS6 included tariffs (HS8 or lower) with different duties. On the other, when the tariffs did not directly affect the value of the imported good, but were instead expressed as specific tariffs, a transformation into AVE data became necessary by dividing the duty by the value of the imported good.

The first step was therefore the transformation of all the specific tariffs into AVE data, at the level of codes HS6 or HS8 when present. The choice of the reference unit value of the imported good was tackled in different ways in the past. The value of specific imports of the State in question is usually utilised for this operation, which has been shown to be entirely valid. It allows a qualitative distinction to be made of the imported goods, but suffers from estimation errors and is often not significant where trade is limited. To overcome these problems Gibson (2001) proposed the use of the import world as reference. This provides more robust data but does not permit any qualitative distinction to be made of the imports. Bouët et al. (2008) further developed this methodology by proposing the use of the average importation value of a group of reference countries, i.e. a set of countries with similar characteristics. This approach is classified midway between the two previously described and has been shown to be robust and able to partly take into account the qualitative differences. However, given that wine is a widely differentiated product, and that to minimise the estimation errors the dataset was constructed by inserting the major exporters and importers, in this study we preferred to use the value of specific imports of the State as reference.

The specific tariffs were therefore transformed into AVE using the following methodology: In response to the second methodological problem, i.e. aggregation of the different tariffs in code HS6, the different methods indicated include the simple average, weighted average and median. The simple average has been criticised because the tariffs have an irregular distribution (Cipollina and Salvatici, 2008), and it has no theoretical basis (Anderson and Neary, 2003; Bouët et al., 2008). The weighted average is instead valid but tends to underestimate the effect of high tariffs (Bouët et al., 2008), as high duties generally lead to a reduction in the quantities imported. Because the median is generally indicated as more robust and reliable, it was used for the aggregation of the tariffs in this article.

  1. where the tariff was expressed on the basis of alcohol content (e.g. EUR 10/per cent vol/hl), an alcohol content of 12 per cent on volume was adopted, which can be considered the average for wine produced on a global basis, as suggested by the WHO;

  2. where the tariff was a fixed sum on the volume imported (e.g. EUR 1/L), the average importing price from each exporter country in the respective year was used as reference for the conversion;

  3. where the tariff included a fixed sum on the volume to which a variable quota was added based on alcohol content (e.g. EUR 1/L + EUR 1/per cent vol/hl), the average price of specific imports per exporting country in the respective year was used as reference for the fixed sum, to which the variable quota was added, calculated on the basis of an alcohol content of 12 per cent;

  4. where the tariff included a percentage on the value plus a quota based on volume/alcohol content (e.g. 15 per cent on the value + EUR 1/L, or 15 per cent on the value + EUR 1/per cent vol/hl), this quota was transformed as indicated in points 1 and 2, and then added to the ad valorem tariff;

  5. where the tariff included the lowest or highest level among the different possible options (e.g. 15 per cent on the value or 125 yen/L), the two options were calculated with the methodology of the preceding points, and then choosing the one indicated by the regulation in force;

  6. where the importing country imposed a maximum and/or minimum limit to the tariff, the average tariff calculated by each exporter and each year was maintained if within the set limits. Otherwise the set minimum/maximum limit was adopted as duty.

The calculation method was used for each importing nation towards all the exporters and all years, to obtain as clear and detailed a picture as possible on the evolution of customs duty during the considered period. In order to obtain the maximum accuracy of the data the official values were used, expressed in the local currency of the various customs authorities, hence without any conversion into US dollars.

5. Model results and discussion

The results for different estimation methods are reported in Table 6. We considered four alternative estimation methods. The first column reports OLS estimates in log form. By adding a constant to the dependent variable we were also able to estimate the model for observations with zero bilateral trade. The second column presents Tobit estimates, based on the Eaton and Tamura (1995) approach. The third and fourth columns report Heckman and PPML estimates, respectively. Exporters' fixed effects are included to account for unobserved heterogeneity (Cardamome, 2011).

Table 6.

Trade barriers in world wine trade

VariableOLSTobitHeckmanPPML
Y1i (Productioni)0.431**0.3500.3330.475**
Productionj−0.313***−0.307***−0.317***−0.198***
Y2j (GDP)1.305***1.455***1.544***1.384***
Dij−0.374***−0.429***−0.436***−0.107*
Languageij0.756***0.906***0.988***1.204***
tj−0.224***−0.219***−0.233***−0.472***
B1j (Label)−0.1000.0260.038−0.214*
B2j (Food standards)−0.068−0.161−0.1710.224
B3j (Conformity assessment)−0.250*−0.638***−0.655**−1.344***
B4j (Food containers)−0.044−0.128−0.158−0.105
B5j (Human health)−0.121−0.164−0.123−0.737**
B6j (Packaging)0.497−0.047−0.128−0.458*
B7j (SPS)−0.214*−0.275**−0.286−0.185
VariableOLSTobitHeckmanPPML
Y1i (Productioni)0.431**0.3500.3330.475**
Productionj−0.313***−0.307***−0.317***−0.198***
Y2j (GDP)1.305***1.455***1.544***1.384***
Dij−0.374***−0.429***−0.436***−0.107*
Languageij0.756***0.906***0.988***1.204***
tj−0.224***−0.219***−0.233***−0.472***
B1j (Label)−0.1000.0260.038−0.214*
B2j (Food standards)−0.068−0.161−0.1710.224
B3j (Conformity assessment)−0.250*−0.638***−0.655**−1.344***
B4j (Food containers)−0.044−0.128−0.158−0.105
B5j (Human health)−0.121−0.164−0.123−0.737**
B6j (Packaging)0.497−0.047−0.128−0.458*
B7j (SPS)−0.214*−0.275**−0.286−0.185

Note: Specifications are in logarithmic form. For OLS and Tobit dependent variables we add an arbitrary small constant.

*, **and ***denote 10, 5 and 1 per cent significance level, respectively.

Table 6.

Trade barriers in world wine trade

VariableOLSTobitHeckmanPPML
Y1i (Productioni)0.431**0.3500.3330.475**
Productionj−0.313***−0.307***−0.317***−0.198***
Y2j (GDP)1.305***1.455***1.544***1.384***
Dij−0.374***−0.429***−0.436***−0.107*
Languageij0.756***0.906***0.988***1.204***
tj−0.224***−0.219***−0.233***−0.472***
B1j (Label)−0.1000.0260.038−0.214*
B2j (Food standards)−0.068−0.161−0.1710.224
B3j (Conformity assessment)−0.250*−0.638***−0.655**−1.344***
B4j (Food containers)−0.044−0.128−0.158−0.105
B5j (Human health)−0.121−0.164−0.123−0.737**
B6j (Packaging)0.497−0.047−0.128−0.458*
B7j (SPS)−0.214*−0.275**−0.286−0.185
VariableOLSTobitHeckmanPPML
Y1i (Productioni)0.431**0.3500.3330.475**
Productionj−0.313***−0.307***−0.317***−0.198***
Y2j (GDP)1.305***1.455***1.544***1.384***
Dij−0.374***−0.429***−0.436***−0.107*
Languageij0.756***0.906***0.988***1.204***
tj−0.224***−0.219***−0.233***−0.472***
B1j (Label)−0.1000.0260.038−0.214*
B2j (Food standards)−0.068−0.161−0.1710.224
B3j (Conformity assessment)−0.250*−0.638***−0.655**−1.344***
B4j (Food containers)−0.044−0.128−0.158−0.105
B5j (Human health)−0.121−0.164−0.123−0.737**
B6j (Packaging)0.497−0.047−0.128−0.458*
B7j (SPS)−0.214*−0.275**−0.286−0.185

Note: Specifications are in logarithmic form. For OLS and Tobit dependent variables we add an arbitrary small constant.

*, **and ***denote 10, 5 and 1 per cent significance level, respectively.

While the estimated coefficients from the OLS, Tobit and Heckman models are quite similar, most coefficients obtained from the PPML model differ significantly from those obtained with other models (except for the parameter estimates of GDP and Language). This suggests that heteroskedasticity (rather than truncation) is responsible for the differences between PPML and the other models (Silva and Tenreyro, 2006).

P-values from the heteroskedasticity-robust RESET test (Ramsey, 1969) on OLS, Tobit and Heckman models suggest that the null-hypothesis of misspecification should not be rejected, unlike the PPML model. We conclude that the PPML model is to be preferred.31 A further advantage of the PPML model is that it allows us to deal with sample selection bias that may result from excluding zero observations. Although selection bias rarely affects the sign of the variable, it often influences the magnitude, statistical significance and economic interpretation of the marginal effects (Haq, Meilke and Cranfield, 2013). In the rest of this section, unless specified otherwise, we refer to the estimates from the PPML model.

Parameter estimates of GDP and distance are statistically significant and have the expected signs: positive and negative, respectively. The estimated elasticity for GDP is close to 1.4 in all specifications. This result is supported by Silva and Tenreyro (2006): they argue that the coefficients on importer's and exporter's GDPs tend to be higher than one. The role of geographical distance is significantly larger when using OLS and Heckman estimators. The estimated elasticity is negative and close to 0.4, whereas the PPML estimate is much lower (−0.11). Compared with the literature on the gravity model (Disdier and Head, 2008), the physical distance has a limited impact on the global wine trade. This result is hardly surprising because exported wine is highly priced and has relatively long storability. In addition, as underlined by Silva and Tenreyro (2006), OLS estimation exaggerates the role of geographical proximity. We conclude that transport costs have a limited role in determining trade patterns. Our explanation for this result is that product differentiation plays an important role in the bottled wine trade because imported wines are imperfect substitutes, distant importers do not replace imports from distant markets with wines sold by closer partners.

The results concerning wine supply also deserve particular attention. Wine production in country i (Y1i) is statistically significant (at the 5 per cent level) and positive and this captures the stimulus of domestic supply on exports. In contrast, the production in country j (importer) is negative and significant at the 1 per cent level: we conclude that home bias induces trade resistance. The elasticity of the former variable (0.475) is more than twice that of the latter (−0.198). ‘Language’ is statistically significant: its impact is large and positive (1.204). These results are in agreement with previous studies (Disdier, Fontagné and Mimouni, 2008; Seccia, Carlucci and Santeramo, 2009; Grant and Boys, 2012; Kandilov and Grennes, 2012).

The estimated coefficients of ‘tariffs’ (tj) are negative in all specifications. The PPML estimate indicates an elasticity of trade to tariffs of −0.472: a 1 per cent increase in tariffs would reduce trade by 0.47 per cent ceteris paribus. Frictions from restrictive technical barriers are effective: this result is in line with those of several authors (Heien and Sims, 2000; Olper and Raimondi, 2008; Liu and Yue, 2009). In particular, we found that SPS measures do not inhibit trade, while technical barriers are considerable frictions to exports. The estimated coefficients of country-specific technical barriers, if statistically significant, are negative. The estimated coefficients of ‘food containers' are statistically not significant. We argue that such a barrier is non-prohibitive. ‘Human health’ and ‘conformity assessment’ are statistically significant at 5 and 1 per cent, respectively. ‘Labelling’ is also statistically significant (at 10 per cent) and negative. Barriers due to ‘food standards’, despite being widely adopted, do not seem to be prohibitive: in all specifications the estimated coefficients are statistically not significant. Our interpretation for this result is that, while food standards on wine are motivated by food safety arguments to protect consumers, modern techniques and innovations in the wine industry allow international standards to be easily satisfied.

The results on equivalent tariffs for technical barriers (AVE-TBTs) are reported in Table 7. The estimates represent the change in tariff that would be equivalent to the imposition of TBTs. Moreover, we evaluated the actual impact of both tariffs and non-tariff barriers on the world wine trade by computing the marginal effect of trade frictions and the aggregate impact on exports.32

Table 7.

Marginal effects (in millions of dollars) and equivalent tariff of TBTs (based on PPML estimates)

Marginal effectAVE-TBTsa
Y1i (Productioni)1.36n/a
Productionj−0.56n/a
Y2j (GDP)3.95n/a
Dij−0.35n/a
Languageij5.54bn/a
tj−1.35n/a
B1j (Label)−0.610.45
B2j (Food standards)n/acn/ac
B3j (Conformity assessment)−3.842.84
B4j (Food containers)n/acn/ac
B5j (Human health)−2.992.21
B6j (Packaging)−1.310.97
B7j (SPS)n/acn/ac
Marginal effectAVE-TBTsa
Y1i (Productioni)1.36n/a
Productionj−0.56n/a
Y2j (GDP)3.95n/a
Dij−0.35n/a
Languageij5.54bn/a
tj−1.35n/a
B1j (Label)−0.610.45
B2j (Food standards)n/acn/ac
B3j (Conformity assessment)−3.842.84
B4j (Food containers)n/acn/ac
B5j (Human health)−2.992.21
B6j (Packaging)−1.310.97
B7j (SPS)n/acn/ac

aEquivalent tariff for the m-th TBT (AVE-TBT) is as follows: AVE - TBTm=(X/Bm)/(X/t). It represents the change in tariff that would be equivalent to the imposition of the TBT.

bDiscrete effect.

cEstimates for food standard TBTs, food container TBTs and SPS measures are statistically not different from zero.

Table 7.

Marginal effects (in millions of dollars) and equivalent tariff of TBTs (based on PPML estimates)

Marginal effectAVE-TBTsa
Y1i (Productioni)1.36n/a
Productionj−0.56n/a
Y2j (GDP)3.95n/a
Dij−0.35n/a
Languageij5.54bn/a
tj−1.35n/a
B1j (Label)−0.610.45
B2j (Food standards)n/acn/ac
B3j (Conformity assessment)−3.842.84
B4j (Food containers)n/acn/ac
B5j (Human health)−2.992.21
B6j (Packaging)−1.310.97
B7j (SPS)n/acn/ac
Marginal effectAVE-TBTsa
Y1i (Productioni)1.36n/a
Productionj−0.56n/a
Y2j (GDP)3.95n/a
Dij−0.35n/a
Languageij5.54bn/a
tj−1.35n/a
B1j (Label)−0.610.45
B2j (Food standards)n/acn/ac
B3j (Conformity assessment)−3.842.84
B4j (Food containers)n/acn/ac
B5j (Human health)−2.992.21
B6j (Packaging)−1.310.97
B7j (SPS)n/acn/ac

aEquivalent tariff for the m-th TBT (AVE-TBT) is as follows: AVE - TBTm=(X/Bm)/(X/t). It represents the change in tariff that would be equivalent to the imposition of the TBT.

bDiscrete effect.

cEstimates for food standard TBTs, food container TBTs and SPS measures are statistically not different from zero.

‘Conformity assessment’ and ‘human health’ are equivalent to 2.84 and 2.21 tariffs, respectively. Thus we can argue that the barriers are prohibitive given that the weighted average tariffs in 2010 were close to 5.04.33 Being country-specific, these technical barriers tend to be very prohibitive as they raise the average transaction costs incurred by exporters.

The tariff equivalent for ‘packaging’, adopted only by the USA, is assessed as being close to unity. Several considerations have to be made on this country. First, the USA system of protectionism is complex and includes a variety of technical barriers such that the marginal contribution of each measure is relatively low. Moreover, the USA being the main world market can exert market power in order to protect its growing domestic market (e.g. Californian supply). Figure 2 shows the dynamics of the total trade frictions per year, as composed by the two components, equivalent AVE for technical barriers (AVE-TBTs) and AVE of tariffs. It is worth noting that while AVE tariffs show a declining trend over the years, and AVE-TBTs an increasing trend, the total frictions pattern is quite steady and does not change significantly during the period 1997–2010 (weighting the measures according to actual trade flows). The result provides statistical and quantitative evidence of the real immutability of overall friction in the world wine trade. Moreover, Figure 3 breaks the total impact of the TBTs down into the different and prohibitive components, providing a measure of the frictions in terms of real export values. While ‘conformity assessment’ and ‘human health’ TBTs showed the greatest marginal impact on trade, they only have a potential and not a real impact on trade given their low diffusion to date. In contrast, notifications on ‘labelling’ have globally been the main non-tariff friction in world wine trade, matching in 2010 the impact of tariff barriers, although the AVE-TBT per notification (0.45) is the lowest among the restrictive TBTs.

TBT tariff equivalents (simply and export weighted average values).
Fig. 2.

TBT tariff equivalents (simply and export weighted average values).

Evolution of relative impacts of tariffs and TBT on trade in thousands of US dollars.
Fig. 3.

Evolution of relative impacts of tariffs and TBT on trade in thousands of US dollars.

6. Conclusions

The expansion of the wine trade over the last decade is due to many factors which include the Uruguay Round/WTO agreements that have led to a progressive lowering of the import duties on agricultural products. As reported by Anderson and Golin (2004), several countries have attempted to maintain some level of protection of their domestic market by stipulating technical requisites that the imported products must satisfy. These new instruments have spread rapidly, as testified by the WTO notifications issued, and have animated academic debates that are not just confined to the literature of agricultural economics, but have a much wider audience (see Henson and Jaffe, 2008; Kee, Nicita and Olarreaga, 2009; Jacks, Meissner and Novy, 2011, among others). Our analysis shows how the principal wine-importing countries are behaving, and in particular how tariffs and non-tariff regulations have impacted trade flows over the period 1997–2010. An extended version of the gravity model was applied to a panel dataset which includes data on 90 per cent of global trade of bottled wine, and detailed information on technical barriers and SPS measures. In order to focus on the economic aspects and avoid cumbersome notation, the econometric formulation was admittedly simple, while the estimates were carried out through the PPML estimator.

The study involved two innovations. First, this is one of the few works where the impact of non-tariff measures on a specific sector has been carefully evaluated and compared type by type to ad valorem tariffs. Second, assessing the impact of non-tariff barriers by using count data is a rather novel way to quantify the impacts of regulations. The main limitation in adopting count data relies on the excessive costs incurred in gathering country- and line-specific regulations. By focusing on a single-specific product we were able to overcome this limitation.

All in all, the econometric estimation of the gravity equation shows that tariff and non-tariff barriers do matter considerably in the world wine trade. Our findings are in line with previous studies on trade costs (Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini, 2010) and the wine trade (Raimondi and Olper, 2011). Jayasinghe, Beghin and Moschini (2010) found that world demand for corn seeds is mainly inhibited by tariffs and distance, and only in a limited way by SPS measures. We found similar evidence for the world wine trade. Our results are also in line with those provided by Kee, Nicita and Olarreaga (2009) who estimate, for agricultural regulations, an average AVE-TBTs of 20 per cent, which for our estimates would represent a top boundary.

However, not all non-tariff barriers are equal: our in-depth analysis shows that, in some cases, TBTs are neither binding nor catalysts for trade. In particular, some trade regulations were assessed to be as stringent as 3 per cent of ad valorem tariffs, while others including SPS measures are totally negligible. This is an important result as it may justify the removal of inefficient technical standards on imported wine, whilst suggesting a target to aim at when seeking to liberalise the international wine trade. Furthermore, for policy-makers who are often interested in the impact of standards and regulations on international trade and competitiveness, the current analysis provides tariff equivalencies that may help them gain insights and negotiate trade agreements to enhance wine trade flows. Finally, we show that the decreasing trend for tariffs has for the most part been compensated by more stringent technical barriers. The overall result, foreseen by Anderson and Golin (2004) 10 years ago, is that frictions in the world wine trade have not changed during the past 15 years.

Our analysis is not exempt from potential improvements. First, our dataset includes only trade observed among 12 countries during the period 1997–2010. Although we capture more than 90 per cent of world wine exports and two-thirds of global import flows, our results cannot explain trade patterns among small traders. Second, our comparative analysis of tariffs and non-tariff barriers, challenged by the complex regulations in force, might not be entirely satisfactory and could invite further research. Indeed, empirical work on technical regulations in world trade represents a promising area of research.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank Alessandro Olper and two anonymous referees whose comments have greatly improved this article, and Mark Walters for editing the manuscript.

References

Aizenman
J.
Brooks
E.
(
2008
).
Globalization and taste convergence: the cases of wine and beer
.
Review of International Economics
16
(2)
:
217
233
.

Anderson
J. E.
Neary
P. J.
(
2003
).
The mercantilist index of trade policy
.
International Economic Review
44
(2)
:
627
649
.

Anderson
J. E.
van Wincoop
E.
(
2003
).
Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle
.
The American Economic Review
93
(1)
:
170
192
.

Anderson
K.
Golin
G.
(eds) (
2004
).
The World's Wine Markets: Globalization at Work
.
Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA, USA
.

Anderson
K.
Nelgen
S.
(eds) (
2011
).
Global Wine Markets, 1961 to 2009: A Statistical Compendium
.
Adelaide
:
University of Adelaide Press
.

Baier
S. L.
Bergstrand
J. H.
(
2007
).
Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade?
Journal of International Economics
71
(1)
:
72
95
.

Baldwin
R.
Taglioni
D.
(
2006
).
Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity equations
.
NBER Working Paper No. 12516
.

Beghin
J. C.
(
2008
).
Nontariff barriers. Center for Agricultural and Rural Development
.
Working Paper 06-WP 438
.

Bouët
A.
Decreux
Y.
Fontagné
L.
Jean
S.
Laborde
D.
(
2008
).
Assessing applied protection across the world
.
Review of International Economics
16
(5)
:
850
863
.

Cardamome
P.
(
2011
).
The effect of preferential trade agreements on monthly fruit exports to the European Union
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
38
(4)
:
553
586
.

Cembalo
L.
Caracciolo
F.
Pomarici
E.
(
2014
).
Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy
.
Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
58
(3)
:
374
391
.

Chevassus-Lozza
E.
Latouche
K.
Majkovic
D.
Unguru
M.
(
2008
).
The importance of EU-15 borders for CEECs agri-food exports: the role of tariffs and non-tariff measures in the pre-accession period
.
Food Policy
33
(6)
:
595
606
.

Cioffi
A.
Santeramo
F. G.
Vitale
C. D.
(
2011
).
The price stabilization effects of the EU entry price scheme for fruits and vegetables
.
Agricultural Economics
42
(3)
:
405
418
.

Cipollina
M.
Salvatici
L.
(
2008
).
Measuring protection: mission impossible?
Journal of Economic Surveys
22
(3)
:
577
616
.

Disdier
A. C.
Fontagné
L.
Mimouni
M.
(
2008
).
The impact of regulation on agricultural trade: evidence from SPS and TBT agreements
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
90
(2)
:
336
350
.

Disdier
A. C.
Head
K.
(
2008
).
The puzzling persistence of the distance effect on bilateral trade
.
The Review of Economics and Statistics
90
(1)
:
37
48
.

Eaton
J.
Tamura
A.
(
1995
).
Bilateralism and regionalism in Japanese and US trade and direct foreign investment patterns (No. w4758). NBER Working Paper
.

Feenstra
R. C.
(ed.) (
2004
).
Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence
.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
.

Fisher
R.
Serra
P.
(
2000
).
Standards and protection
.
Journal of International Economics
52
(2)
:
377
400
.

Fogarty
J.
(
2010
).
The demand for beer, wine and spirits: a survey of the literature
.
Journal of Economic Surveys
24
(3)
:
428
478
.

Fontagné
L.
Mimouni
M.
Pasteels
J. M.
(
2005
).
Estimating the impact of environmental SPS and TBT on international trade
.
Integration and Trade Journal
22
(3)
:
7
37
.

Foster
M.
Spencer
D.
(eds) (
2002
).
World wine market: barriers to increasing trade. ABARE Research Report 02.6
,
Canberra
.

Freebairn
J.
(
2010
).
Special taxation of alcoholic beverages to correct market failures
.
Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy
29
(2)
:
200
214
.

Gibson
P. R.
Wainio
J.
Whitley
D. B.
Bohman
M.
(
2001
).
Profiles of tariffs in global agricultural markets (No. 34055)
.
United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC: Economic Research Service
.

Grant
J. H.
Boys
K. A.
(
2012
).
Agricultural trade and the GATT/WTO: does membership make a difference?
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
94
(1)
:
1
24
.

Haq
Z. U.
Meilke
K.
Cranfield
J.
(
2013
).
Selection bias in a gravity model of agrifood trade
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
40
(2)
:
331
360
.

Harrigan
J.
(
1993
).
OECD imports and trade barriers in 1983
.
Journal of International Economics
35
(1–2)
:
91
111
.

Head
K.
Mayer
T.
(
2013
).
Gravity Equations: Workhorse, Toolkit, and Cookbook
.
London: Centre for Economic Policy Research
.

Heckman
J. J.
(
1979
).
Sample selection bias and a specification error
.
Econometrica
47
(1)
:
153
161
.

Heien
D.
Sims
E.
(
2000
).
The impact of the Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement on U.S. Wine Export
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
82
(1)
:
173
182
.

Henry de Frahan
B.
Vancauteren
M.
(
2006
).
Harmonization of food regulation and trade in the single market: evidence from disaggregated data
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
33
(3)
:
337
360
.

Henson
S.
Brouder
A. M.
Mitullah
W.
(
2000
).
Food safety requirements and food exports from developing countries: the case of fish exports from Kenya to the European Union
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
82
(5)
:
1159
1169
.

Henson
S.
Jaffee
S.
(
2008
).
Understanding developing country strategic responses to the enhancement of food safety standards
.
The World Economy
31
(4)
:
548
568
.

Henson
S.
Loader
R.
(
2001
).
Barriers to agricultural exports from developing countries: the role of sanitary and phytosanitary requirements
.
World Development
29
(1)
:
85
102
.

Hillman
J. S.
(
1991
).
Technical Barriers to Agricultural Trade
.
Boulder, CO
:
Westview Press
.

Jacks
D. S.
Meissner
C. M.
Novy
D.
(
2011
).
Trade booms, trade busts, and trade costs
.
Journal of International Economics
83
(2)
:
185
201
.

Jayasinghe
S.
Beghin
J. C.
Moschini
G.
(
2010
).
Determinants of world demand for U.S. corn seeds: the role of trade costs
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
92
(4)
:
999
1010
.

Kandilov
I. T.
Grennes
T.
(
2012
).
The determinants of service offshoring: Does distance matter?
Japan and the World Economy
24
(1)
:
36
43
.

Kee
L. H.
Nicita
A.
Olarreaga
M.
(
2009
).
Estimating trade restrictiveness indices
.
The Economic Journal
119
(1)
:
172
199
.

Leamer
E. E.
(
1974
).
Nominal tariff averages with estimated weights
.
Southern Economic Journal
41
(1)
:
34
46
.

Leamer
E. E.
(
1990
).
Latin America as a target of trade barriers erected by the major developed countries in 1983
.
Journal of Development Economics
32
(2)
:
337
368
.

Li
Y.
Beghin
J. C.
(
2011
).
A meta-analysis of estimates of the impact of technical barriers to trade
.
Journal of Policy Modelling
34
(3)
:
497
511
.

Liu
L.
Yue
C.
(
2009
).
Non-tariff barriers to trade caused by SPS measures and customs procedures with product quality changes
.
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
34
(1)
:
196
212
.

Mahé
L. P.
(
1997
).
Environment and quality standards in the WTO: new protectionism in agricultural trade? A European perspective
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
24
(3–4)
:
480
503
.

Martin
W.
Pham
C.
(
2008
)
Estimating the gravity equation when zero trade flows are frequent. MPRA Paper No. 9453
.

Maskus
K. E.
Wilson
J. S.
Otsuki
T.
(
2000
).
Quantifying the Impact of Technical Barriers to Trade: A Framework for Analysis (No. 2512)
.
Washington, DC: The World Bank
.

Moenius
J.
(
2004
).
The good, the bad, and the ambiguous: standards and trade in agricultural products. In: International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium Summer Symposium, Bonn, Germany, May 28–30
.

Olper
A.
Raimondi
V.
(
2008
).
Explaining national border effects in the QUAD food trade
.
Journal of Agricultural Economics
59
(3)
:
436
462
.

Orden
D.
Roberts
D.
(
2007
).
Food regulation and trade under the WTO: ten years in perspective
.
Agricultural Economics
37
(s1)
:
103
118
.

Otsuki
T.
Wilson
J. S.
Sewadeh
M.
(
2001
).
What price precaution? European Harmonisation of Aflatoxin Regulations and African Groundnut Exports
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
28
(3)
:
263
283
.

Peterson
E. B.
Orden
D.
(
2005
).
Effects of tariffs and sanitary barriers on high and low value poultry trade
.
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
30
(1)
:
109
127
.

Peterson
E. B.
Orden
D.
(
2008
).
Avocado pests and avocado trade
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
90
(2)
:
321
335
.

Raimondi
V.
Olper
A.
(
2011
).
Trade elasticity, gravity and trade liberalisation: evidence from the food industry
.
Journal of Agricultural Economics
62
(3)
:
525
550
.

Ramsey
J. B.
(
1969
).
Tests for specification errors in classical linear least squares regression analysis
.
Journal of Royal Statistical Society
31
(2)
:
350
371
.

Santeramo
F. G.
Cioffi
A.
(
2012
).
The entry price threshold in EU agriculture: deterrent or barrier?
Journal of Policy Modeling
34
(5)
:
691
704
.

Seccia
A.
Carlucci
D.
Santeramo
F. G.
(
2009
).
Exports of Italian high quality wine: new empirical evidence from a gravity-type model
. In:
Canavari
M.
(ed.),
International Marketing and Trade of Quality Food Products
.
Wageningen: Wageningen Academic Publishers
,
15
29
.

Silva
S.
Tenreyro
S.
(
2006
).
The log of gravity
.
The Review of Economics and Statistics
88
(4)
:
641
658
.

Subramanian
A.
Wei
S. J.
(
2007
).
The WTO promotes trade strongly but unevenly
.
Journal of International Economics
72
(1)
:
151
175
.

Swinnen
J. F. M.
Vandemoortele
T.
(
2011
).
Trade and the political economy of food standards
.
Journal of Agricultural Economics
62
(2)
:
259
280
.

Tinbergen
J.
(ed.) (
1962
).
Shaping the World Economy: Suggestion for an International Economy Policy
.
New York
:
The Twentieth Century Fund
.

Wooldridge
J.
(
2002
).
Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data
.
Cambridge, MA
:
MIT Press
.

Xiong
B.
Beghin
J. C.
(
2012
).
Does European aflatoxin regulation hurt groundnut exporters from Africa?
European Review of Agricultural Economics
39
(4)
:
589
609
.

Yue
C.
Beghin
J. C.
(
2009
).
Tariff equivalent and forgone trade effects of prohibitive technical barriers to trade
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
91
(4)
:
930
941
.

Yue
C.
Beghin
J. C.
Jensen
H. H.
(
2006
).
Tariff equivalent of technical barriers to trade with imperfect substitution and trade costs
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
88
(4)
:
947
960
.

1

Aizenman and Brooks (2008) suggest that this could be the result of larger phenomena: the increase in migration and tourism flows, as well as a cultural revolution which, via globalisation, is generating a new cultural collective identity.

2

The cursory review we have presented is not exhaustive as it is far beyond the scope of the article to summarise the debate on trade regulation. The interested reader may refer to Orden and Roberts (2007) for an excellent review of the effects of trade regulations.

3

The HS2 refer to the first chapter (2 digit level) of the Harmonised Commodity Description and Coding System (HS) of tariff nomenclature. Being an internationally standardised system for classifying traded products, it allows participating countries to classify traded goods on a common basis for customs purposes.

4

Global Trade Atlas: consulted on 16 August 2014.

5

Bottled wine is universally associated to the HS code 220421, corresponding to ‘wine of fresh grapes (other than sparkling wine) and grape must with fermentation prevented, etc. by adding alcohol, containers of not over 2 l’. In fact below this HS six-digit code, there are generally several HS codes with eight or more digits, that are country-specific, and with different tariff levels.

6

The most common methodology to aggregate the tariffs is the use of their weighted average, using as weight the respective quota of imports valued at the frontier. This type of aggregation is criticised for its endogeneity, since the higher the tariff, the greater its effect will be on restricting trade, as a function of the price elasticity of the demand (Anderson and Neary, 2003; Bouët et al., 2008). Leamer (1974) therefore proposes the use of the world import as a weighting measure, while Bouët et al. (2008) utilise the imports of a group of countries of reference for the weighting. Unfortunately, this approach cannot be used with an HS8 (or higher) level of detail because, varying from country to country, it is not possible to use common weights.

7

Our analysis includes trade among selected large main importers and exporters: France, Italy, Spain, Germany, UK, USA, Canada, Argentina, Chile, Australia, China and Japan

8

Computed as the MFN tariff net of the established FTAs and weighted by the value of imports.

9

Changes in duty introduced by Regulations R1734/96, R2086/97, R2261/98, R2204/99 and RO 948/09.

10

Considering the States of the European Union jointly.

11

By summing the TBTs reported in columns 3–5.

12

TBT/N/EEC/11, TBT/N/USA/205, TBT/N/CAN/248, TBT/N/ARG/252, TBT/N/CHL/95 and TBT/N/JPN/123.

13

TBT/N/EEC/15, TBT/N/EEC/57, TBT/N/USA/158, TBT/N/USA/593, TBT/N/ARG/18, TBT/N/ARG/107. TBT/N/CHN/72, TBT/N/CHN/197 and TBT/N/CHN/733.

14

TBT/N/EEC/191, TBT/N/EEC/254, TBT/N/EEC/264, TBT/N/EEC/305, TBT/Notif.95/348, TBT/N/CHL/33 and TBT/NOTIF.95/155.

15

TBT/N/USA/110, TBT/N/USA/126, TBT/N/USA/290, TBT/N/CAN/8, TBT/N/ARG/64, TBT/N/ARG/65, TBT/N/ARG/130, TBT/N/ARG/164, TBT/NOTIF.99/235, TBT/NOTIF.98/272 and TBT/N/CHN/33.

16

TBT/Notif.99/541, TBT/N/USA/6 and TBT/NOTIF.96/221.

17

TBT/N/EEC/19, TBT/N/EEC/158, TBT/Notif.00/423, TBT/N/ARG/93 and TBT/NOTIF.97/317.

18

G/TBT/Notif.99/89.

19

TBT/N/USA/509.

20

G/TBT/Notif.99.255 and G/TBT/Notif.99.375.

21

TBT/N/CHN/2.

22

G/SPS/N/ARG/140.

23

We considered ‘home bias’ in the context of the wine trade as the resistance to importing foreign products due to the supply of national products.

24

We tested for significance of time-varying fixed effects. Results were not affected, while time-varying fixed effects were statistically not significant.

25

The GTA database is based on official customs data collected from reporting countries. Products are classified at eight digit level according to the Harmonised System (HS) codes. Data have been available for most countries since 1997.

26

In the CEPII database the calculation is based on bilateral distance between cities, weighted by the share of the city in the overall population in the country.

27

World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) is a database provided by the World Bank. It provides the AVE tariffs for each country, starting from 1996.

28

‘Technical Barriers to Trade Information Management System’ (TBT IMS) is a public database created with the aim of guaranteeing transparency on technical regulations and evaluation procedures of the conformity and standards introduced by each country. The database provides access to the various notifications introduced at county level (including subsequent revisions, appendices, corrections and supplements), to the bilateral and multilateral agreements between countries relating to the TBT measures, and to the documents issued by the standardisation authorities in relation to the ‘Code of Good Practice’. The ‘SPS Information Management System’ (SPS IMS) contains information on the agreements signed within the SPS Agreement.

29

Most favoured nation.

31

Zero-inflated PPML does not lead to different results. A limitation of PPML, pointed by Martin and Pham (2008), is that it tends to underestimate coefficients relative to other estimators when they work with few zero-trade flows, while it overestimates them the number of zero-trade flows is substantial. In our analysis, the limited number of zero-trade flows implies that estimates might be slightly biased downwards.

32

Aggregate impact on exports in time t was calculated as j((X/Bm)Bmjt).

33

For computation we excluded intra-EU trade.

Author notes

Review coordinated by Giannis Karagiannis